Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Political Behavior 3/2014

Open Access 01-09-2014 | Original Paper

Fear and Anger in Great Britain: Blame Assignment and Emotional Reactions to the Financial Crisis

Author: Markus Wagner

Published in: Political Behavior | Issue 3/2014

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

While we know that emotional reactions are important influences on political behavior, we know far less about the sources of these emotions. This paper studies the causes of fear and anger in reaction to a negative stimulus: the financial crisis. Anger should have been experienced among individuals who believed a specific actor was to blame for the crisis. Moreover, individuals should have been particularly angry if they blamed an actor who should be accountable to them, for example the national government. I test these expectations using a panel survey run in Britain between 2005 and 2010. This data shows that British citizens experienced anger if they held an actor responsible for the crisis. Moreover, they felt particularly angry if they held the Labour government (and to a lesser extent the European Union) responsible. These findings underline the importance of studying the causes of emotional reactions and show how these may be linked to common institutional distinctions between political systems.
Notes

Electronic supplementary material

The online version of this article (doi:10.​1007/​s11109-013-9241-5) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

Introduction

The emotions we experience have important consequences for our political behavior. Recent psychological and neuroscientific research has thus shown that our emotional reactions can shape how we take decisions (Eagly and Chaiken 1993; Damasio 1994; Lerner and Keltner 2000, 2001). Political psychologists have found that emotions can affect how willing we are to re-evaluate our political beliefs and become actively engaged in politics (Marcus and MacKuen 1993; Marcus et al. 2000; Rudolph et al. 2000; Brader 2005, 2006; Valentino et al. 2008, 2009; Huddy et al. 2007; Groenendyk 2011).
Some of this research has investigated the impact on political behavior of discrete emotions such as enthusiasm, anger, fear and sadness.1 For example, there is evidence that how we react to negative stimuli and threatening situations depends in part on whether they make us feel fear or anger (Huddy et al. 2005, 2007; Valentino et al. 2008; MacKuen et al. 2010). The reasons for this may lie in the different mental systems these emotions operate in (Marcus and MacKuen 1993; Cacioppo et al. 1999; MacKuen et al. 2010; Weber 2012). While fear makes us more risk-averse and vigilant (avoidance/surveillance systems), anger increases our readiness to address the threat directly while relying on previously learned routines (approach/disposition systems). For instance, some research has shown that it is anger rather than fear that leads citizens to engage in protest behavior by taking part in demonstrations or in other forms of political mobilization (van Zomeren et al. 2004; Leach et al. 2006; Smith et al. 2008).
Yet, we know far less about the causes of these discrete emotions (Brader et al. 2010). What is it about the threatening situation or the negative stimulus that leads some people to experience fear and others anger? Since these emotional reactions may be central to determining our further behavior, it is important to understand why these emotions arise in the first place. So far, political scientists and political psychologists have however not paid much attention to exploring the sources of discrete emotional reactions (though see Smith et al. 2008; Brader et al. 2010; and Petersen et al. 2012).
In this paper, I develop two hypotheses that build on cognitive appraisal theories of emotions, which suggest that the emotions we experience depend on our assessment of the situation (Smith and Ellsworth 1985; Lazarus 1991; Smith et al. 2008). First, it is likely that our perception of whether someone is responsible for a threat is a key determinant of whether we react to that threat with fear or anger. Specifically, anger is the more likely emotional reaction if the threat has an identifiable external cause.
Yet, blaming an actor on its own may not be enough to explain why someone reacts with anger instead of fear: instead, it may matter what kind of actor is blamed. My second hypothesis is therefore that anger is more likely than fear among individuals who believe that the actor responsible should be under their control and should care about their welfare. This means that reacting with anger should be more likely if there is an accountability relationship between the individual and the actor blamed (e.g. Smith and Ellsworth 1985; Lerner and Keltner 2000, 2001; Smith et al. 2008; Sell et al. 2009).
I test these hypotheses using emotional reactions to the financial crisis in the UK as measured in a 2005–2010 panel survey. The financial crisis is an event that presented an important economic threat to both individual citizens and the country as a whole. Both fear and anger are appropriate responses to the financial crisis: fear about the potential impact of the economic downturn, anger at the actions that made the crisis possible. Moreover, the survey evidence shows that people varied in their assignment of responsibility for the crisis. While some did assign blame, others were more uncertain about its causes or believed that the crisis ‘just happened’. Among those citizens who did hold specific actors responsible, there was also variation in who was blamed. Many blamed banks and financial institutions in the UK and abroad, but others also saw the national government, the European Union (EU) or other countries as responsible.
In this paper, I show that these variations help to account for why some British citizens were angry and others afraid in reaction to the financial crisis. Specifically, I present evidence that citizens who held an actor responsible for the crisis were more likely to be angry. In addition, citizens were particularly likely to be angry if they held the national government and (to a lesser extent) the EU responsible for the crisis. I argue that this is because citizens believe that these two actors should be under their control and should care about their welfare. In other words, anger is more likely to arise when an accountability relationship is perceived to be broken or violated. These findings are particularly robust given that the availability of panel data means that I can control tightly for emotional and partisan predispositions.
Whether and to whom voters assign blame for the economic situation is important in explaining emotional reactions. This finding significantly advances our understanding of the origins of emotions in politics. Moreover, anger and fear differ in their consequences: I thus show in a concluding analysis that experiencing anger (but not fear) led previous Labour voters to reconsider their vote choice in 2010. This is consistent with the theory that anger activates the approach rather than the avoidance system. Overall, this paper underlines the importance of principal-agent relationships and accountability in analyzing the role of the economy in political behavior. Perceptions of responsibility and control have been central to understanding the impact of economic perceptions on vote choice, and the evidence presented here provides further evidence of their importance in explaining how voters react to economic conditions (on perceptions of responsibility, see, e.g., Rudolph 2003; Hellwig et al. 2008; Marsh and Tilley 2010; Hellwig and Coffey 2011; Hobolt et al. 2013; on the extent of control, see, e.g., Powell and Whitten 1993; Anderson 2000, 2007; Johns 2011).
This paper is structured as follows. I begin by reviewing the differences between fear and anger as discrete emotional reactions and then consider how voters’ emotions may have been shaped by their assessment of responsibility for the financial crisis. I then describe the data, measurement approach and modeling strategy before presenting the results. I conclude by highlighting implications of my findings for understanding emotional reactions to politics in general.

Fear and Anger as Discrete Emotional Responses

Much existing work on the role of voters’ emotions in politics has made use of the two-dimensional valence model of emotions (Marcus et al. 2000; Marcus 2003). This model suggests that positive and negative emotions are arranged on two separate and orthogonal dimensions. This means that positive and negative emotions can co-occur (Cassese and Weber 2011). Neuroscientific research has shown that these positive and negative emotions each affect decision-making (Damasio 1994; Marcus et al. 2000; Valentino et al. 2011; Cassese and Weber 2011). In particular, negative emotions lead to us to try to avoid harm and danger (‘avoidance’), while positive emotions foster reward-seeking and engagement (‘approach’; Gray 1990; Cacioppo et al. 1999; Huddy et al. 2007; Valentino et al. 2011).
In political science, the most prominent use of the two-dimensional model of emotions is as part of the affective intelligence theory (Marcus et al. 2000), which argues that emotions help to determine when we rely on heuristics and when we take decisions more cautiously (though see Ladd and Lenz 2008, 2011). Specifically, positive emotions such as enthusiasm activate the disposition system and reinforce existing behaviors and attitudes. In contrast, negative emotions such as anxiety activate the surveillance system and lead individuals to rely less on habit. Instead, negative emotions are argued to increase information-seeking and careful decision-making. In this approach, fear and anger have generally been treated as part of one underlying dimension containing negative emotions (Marcus and MacKuen 1993; Marcus et al. 2000; Rudolph et al. 2000).2
However, more recently the two-dimensional valence model has been criticized as overly simplistic (e.g. Petersen 2010; Huddy et al. 2007; Valentino et al. 2008, 2011; Smith et al. 2008; Weber 2012; see also Conover and Feldman 1986). Researchers have asked whether a focus on positive and negative emotions fails to account for differences between emotions of the same valence (Cassese and Weber 2011). In particular, it has been questioned whether anger and fear should both be seen as similar, negative emotions. Rather, it is argued that these two emotions should be considered as discrete responses because they are caused by different situational appraisals and because they have different consequences for our behavior (Smith and Ellsworth 1985; Conover and Feldman 1986; Lerner and Keltner 2000, 2001; Huddy et al. 2007; Carver and Harmon-Jones 2009; Petersen 2010; Valentino et al. 2011; Marcus 2013, p. 119).
First, fear and anger may lead us to engage in different kinds of further behavior. While most versions of affective intelligence theory argue that both emotions trigger the surveillance system (Marcus et al. 2000), more recent research indicates that the effects of fear and anger may differ. There is thus some evidence that anxiety leads to problem-focused information-seeking, risk-averse behavior and increased vigilance, while anger increases risk-seeking behavior and the motivation to engage in political action (Lerner and Keltner 2000, 2001; Druckman and McDermott 2008; Carver and Harmon-Jones 2009; Valentino et al. 2009, 2011; Brader et al. 2010; see also MacKuen et al. 2010 for a similar account using AIT theory). As Smith et al. (2008, p. 223) state, ‘anger motivates people to attack and remove the source of action,… and fear motivates people to be cautious and avoid harm’.3
Fear and anger also differ in how they are caused. The main insights into the different origins of fear and anger come from cognitive appraisal theories of emotions (Smith and Ellsworth 1985; Lazarus 1991; Smith et al. 2008; Carver and Harmon-Jones 2009; Cassese and Weber 2011; Valentino et al. 2011). These theories suggest that our emotional responses arise as a consequence of how we understand and interpret the situation we experience. As Best and Krueger (2011, p. 89) note: ‘Because people often appraise the same situation differently, cognitive appraisal theory helps comprehend why people experiencing the same phenomena or event may exhibit different emotions of the same valence.’ The focus of such theories is therefore on the cognitive appraisals that generate specific emotions.4 Whether a threat leads to fear or to anger therefore depends on how a threat is perceived and assessed. In the next section, I will consider how these appraisals may have shaped emotional reactions to the financial crisis.

Fear and Anger as Emotional Responses to the Financial Crisis

The financial crisis since 2007 is likely to have been seen as both a personal and national threat to many people. As a negative stimulus, it will have led to strong emotional responses (‘affective appraisals’), including anger and fear (MacKuen et al. 2010). However, when did the financial crisis cause anger and when did it inspire fear? In line with discrete models of emotion, it is likely that the nature of individuals’ appraisal of the situation was an important determinant of their emotional reactions. Appraisal theories identify a wide variety of important factors, including among others the certainty and legitimacy of the outcome and the relevance of the event (Smith and Ellsworth 1985; Cassese and Weber 2011).

How does Assigning Responsibility Affect Emotional Reactions?

Concerning the financial crisis, one aspect should be particularly important: the assignment of responsibility. Our emotional response to a threat can depend on whether we attribute blame for that threat to an actor, that is, whether we believe that another actor is responsible for the negative stimulus (Lerner and Tiedens 2006).5 In such cases, anger is the likely emotional response (Weiner 1985; Smith and Ellsworth 1985; Conover and Feldman 1986; Frijda 1986; Lazarus and Lazarus 1994; Berkowitz and Harmon-Jones 2004; Lerner and Tiedens 2006; Smith et al. 2008). Lerner and Keltner (2000, p. 479) thus note that individuals react with anger when they think that the situation was ‘brought about by others’ and is ‘under human control’ (see also Brader et al. 2010; Petersen et al. 2012). Smith and Ellsworth (1985) term these aspects of situation ‘other-control’ and ‘other-responsibility’. Thus, anger is caused by events that are the result of actions by an external actor, not by one’s own actions (‘self-control’) or simply the result of fate, luck or circumstance (‘situational control’).6
In contrast, fear is the more likely reaction when the situation cannot be blamed on any specific actor (Lerner and Keltner 2000; though see Smith et al. 2008). As Lerner and Tiedens (2006, p. 117) write, ‘when people feel uncertain or lack confidence about the cause of negative events, they are likely to feel fear and anxiety rather than anger.’7 In other words, fear can be seen as a ‘default’ response to a threat that is maintained if no external source for that threat can be identified.
We know that voters vary in whether they assign responsibility for economic outcomes to various actors. While certainly not an easy task, citizens can and do regularly identify actors responsible for economic developments (e.g., Powell and Whitten 1993; Anderson 2000, 2007; Rudolph and Grant 2002; Rudolph 2003; Marsh and Tilley 2010). The nature of the emotional response to the financial crisis should depend in part on whether an individual believed a specific actor was responsible. The first hypothesis is thus that individuals should experience anger rather than fear if they blame an actor for the financial crisis.

Accountability Relationships and Anger

The expectation above is simple: assigning blame for a threat leads to increased anger compared to fear. Yet cognitive appraisal theories also indicate that the relationship between blame and emotional reactions may be more nuanced than this. It may matter what kind of actor we assign blame to, or more specifically whether there is a principal-agent relationship with that actor. Anger rather than fear should be more likely if this is the case. This is because individuals will be more likely to react with anger if they believe the threat to be caused by an external actor who (1) they should have control over but who (2) has paid insufficient regard to their welfare. I will address these two points in turn.
First, it has been established that anger is more likely if individuals themselves believe that they have some control over remedying the situation (Smith and Ellsworth 1985; Lazarus and Lazarus 1994; Lerner and Keltner 2001; Smith et al. 2008; Valentino et al. 2009). If they do believe this, then anger is a more likely reaction than fear. This appraisal is what Smith and Ellsworth (1985) refer to as ‘self-control’ and ‘self-responsibility’: the extent to which the individuals themselves believe that they have control over and responsibility for the events.8 Smith et al. (2008) note that other work uses similar terms such as control potential (Roseman et al. 1990), controllability (Frijda et al. 1989) or coping potential (Lazarus 2001). In political science, this has usually been termed political efficacy (Easton 1965; Easton and Dennis 1967; Balch 1974; Niemi et al. 1991).9 When the perception of efficacy is low, fear is the likely emotional reaction, while higher levels are associated with anger (Lerner and Keltner 2001). Thus, Valentino et al. (2009, p. 310) note that ‘[f]ear occurs when…the situation appears to be outside the individual’s control, while anger is more likely when the individual perceives herself to be in control of the causal agent.’ We are likely to react with anger when we think that we can control the external actor behind the threat, but with fear if addressing a threat by an actor of whom we are not the principal.
However, the key point that causes anger in politics may be that the agent over whom we nominally have control has not acted in ways that benefit us. Recent research in evolutionary psychology has argued that anger arises when ‘the other party is not placing ‘‘sufficient’’ weight on [our] welfare’ (Sell et al. 2009, p. 15074). This may particularly be the case when we have some control over the actor, since that leads us to expect benefits in return. This means that anger rather than fear may be the result of situations where we are disappointed about an actor who should be caring more about our welfare. In related work, anger has been seen to be caused when individuals believe an action to be illegitimate or improper (Berkowitz and Harmon-Jones 2004): ‘An angering event is one in which someone or something challenges what ‘ought’ to happen’ (Frijda 1986, p. 199; see also Petersen et al. 2012). Importantly, Roseman et al. (1996) argue that the perception of illegitimacy needs to be coupled with control potential to lead to anger. The question is not whether individuals have actual control over the external actor, but whether they believe they should have such control. In sum, angry emotional reactions may arise in particular when voters blame an actor with whom the principal-agent relationship is malfunctioning.
With regard to the financial crisis (and the economy in general), citizens can be said to be the principals of their national government, for example through elections (Müller 2000). At the very least, they are likely to hold the normative belief that these actors should be their agents and thus accountable to them. This institutionalized principal-agent relationship stands in contrast to the weak (or even non-existent) accountability ties that link citizens to other economic actors such as businesses, banks and foreign countries. Concerning the European Union, there is a weaker link between citizens and the EU’s political institutions. Nevertheless, though the chain of accountability is less direct, the EU is also under clearer citizen control than, say, banks or mortgage companies; at the very least, voters may expect the EU to be more responsive to citizen concerns.
Importantly, citizens are likely to have varied in whom they held responsible for the financial crisis. While some will have blamed banks and mortgage companies, others may have held governments responsible as well. In general, voters vary in who they believe has the most influence on economic outcomes. For example, they differ in they extent they see the government as responsible for the economy (Powell and Whitten 1993; Anderson 2000, 2007; Rudolph 2003). For example, in the 2005 BES pre-election survey, 25 % of respondents said that the government influences the performance of the economy ‘a great deal’, 54 % ‘a fair amount’, 11 % ‘not very much’ or ‘not at all’, with 9 % ticking ‘don’t know’.10 It is likely that this also applies to other actors with potential influence on the economy such as the European Union, banks, businesses and foreign countries and governments.
In sum, in the context of the financial crisis citizens should be angry rather than afraid if they blame the national government (and to a lesser extent the EU) for the threat, and they should be afraid rather than angry if they see the threat’s cause as associated with actors outside of clear principal-agent relationships such as banks or foreign governments.11 My second hypothesis is therefore that individuals should be more likely to experience anger rather than fear if they blame the national government or the EU for the financial crisis than if they blame other actors.

Measuring Fear and Anger Using the BES Internet Panel

I study voters’ emotional reactions to the financial crisis in Great Britain using data from a 6-year internet panel survey carried out by the British Election Study (2010). This survey had nine waves, three each in the two election years (2005 and 2010) and one each in 2006, 2008 and 2009. The waves used in this paper are shown in Table 1. Sanders et al. (2007, 2011) show that the sample used by the BES internet panel is very similar to that of a representative in-person sample. Identical models of vote choice run with the in-person and internet surveys also yield almost identical model parameters (Sanders et al. 2007).
Table 1
BES internet panel
Wave
Date
Respondents
Questions
1
March/April 2005
7793
Emotional predispositions
3
May 2005
5910
Vote choice
4
May 2006
6,186
Attention to politics
Internal efficacy
Party identification
Party affect (like-dislike)
Economic ideology
6
July 2009
4,048
Assignment of responsibility
7
March/April 2010
3,402
Emotional reactions
9
May 2010
2,781
Vote choice
I construct my measure of emotional reactions to the financial crisis based on a question asked in the pre-election survey 2010 (wave 7). This survey asked two questions about respondents’ feelings about the economy: ‘Which, if any, of the following words describe your feelings about the country’s general economic situation?’ and ‘Which, if any, of the following words describe your feelings about how you have been personally affected by the current financial crisis?’. The respondents were given eight emotions to choose from: angry, happy, disgusted, hopeful, uneasy, confident, afraid and proud. They could also select ‘no feelings’ or ‘don’t know’. Of these eight emotions, respondents were allowed to choose up to four. I treat ‘angry’ as the indicator of anger and ‘afraid’ and ‘uneasy’ as indicators of fear.
My main dependent variable is the proportion of ‘anger’ relative to the total number of angry and fearful emotions selected by the respondent.12 This variable ranges from 0 to 1. Around 8 % of respondents selected neither angry nor fearful emotions. These respondents were coded as having a proportion of 0 angry emotions, but the statistical results do not change if this group of respondents is omitted (see supplemental material). In the analysis below, I do not take into account the total number of angry and fearful emotions selected; additional analyses presented in the supplemental materials show that the substance of the findings does not differ depending on the total number of these emotions selected by the respondents.
Figure 1 presents a histogram of angry and fearful emotional reactions to the economy and the financial crisis in Britain in 2010. A little more than a third of respondents do not select anger at all. For about a quarter of respondents, anger makes up 50 % or more of the angry and fearful emotions selected. The remaining group of respondents, making up more than a third of the total, can be classified as slightly angry: while they do select that emotion, they do so less often than fearful emotions.

Measures of Blame Assignment and Control Variables

Before analyzing the causes of anger and fear as emotional reactions to the financial crisis, I describe the model set-up, including the additional controls needed. First, the key predictor variables of fear and anger concern the responsibility of other actors for the financial crisis. One key advantage of using panel data is that I can measure perceptions of responsibility and emotional reactions in separate waves. These are taken from an earlier wave than the emotion measure in order to reduce the problem known as simultaneity in survey response, i.e. that survey participants try to remain consistent in their responses within one survey (Abelson 1968; Schwarz and Sudman 1992). Specifically, I use a question from wave 6 (July 2009) that measures blame assignment directly. Respondents were asked: ‘Who do you think is responsible for the current financial crisis?’ and were then asked to choose as many actors as they wished out of a list of eleven options. The answers ‘Gordon Brown’ and ‘the British government’ were coded as blaming the Labour government. Further indicators for responsibility are (1) international financiers and banks (both British and American), (2) American actors (George W. Bush, Barack Obama and the American government), (3) the European Union, (4) people with big mortgages or (5) no one, also including ‘don’t knows’.
The responses to this question in 2009 are shown in Table 2. As multiple selections were possible, the column entries add up to more than 100 %. Almost all respondents (86.6 %) hold national or international banks responsible for the crisis. About half of respondents believe that the US and British governments hold some responsibility, while only 20 % see the EU as responsible for the crisis. (Recall that this survey was carried out in July 2009, so before the crisis began to center on Greece, Italy and Spain.) 9 % of respondents selected ‘don’t know’ or ‘no actor responsible’ as their reply to this question.
Table 2
Assignments of responsibility for the financial crisis, 2009
Actors responsible
n
in %
Banks
3,499
86.6
National government
1,929
47.8
US government
1,791
44.3
Mortgage holders
1,142
28.3
European Union
818
20.3
Don’t know/no one
365
9.0
Total
4,040
 
Note Multiple answers possible. Data from wave 6 (July 2009) of the BES internet panel 2005–2010. Unweighted results shown. For coding details, see text
I have suggested that blaming the national government and the EU leads to anger more than blaming other actors due to the existence of a principal-agent relationship, which in turn creates the possibility that individuals will believe that they have coping potential and that the actor blamed has acted improperly in neglecting their welfare. Unfortunately, the presence of these two perceptions (coping potential and disregard for welfare) cannot be tested directly using the data available. For one, the survey does not include measures that assess whether respondents think that governments should be responsive (rather than whether they are responsive). I do control for general efficacy using a measure from the 2006 wave that asked respondents to rate their influence on politics on a scale of 0–10.13 Yet this overall measure of efficacy does not capture whether respondents believe they should have influence over politics, and it is precisely this frustration and discrepancy that should lead to anger (Berkowitz and Harmon-Jones 2004). In addition, disregard for welfare is not measured either: there are no items that ask whether governments have a duty to care for their citizens or whether this duty has been violated during the crisis.
In the model, I also control for further factors that may be important influences on both emotional reactions to the financial crisis and on assignments of responsibility. Another advantage of the panel data is that I can measure these important confounders before the crisis occurred. First, I control for emotional predispositions towards anger and fear. To do so, I include a variable from wave 1 (March/April 2005) that measures the proportion of anger about the economy relative to the total number of angry and fearful emotions. This variable has three possible values: 0, 0.5 and 1. Respondents who were neither angry nor fearful are coded as 0. I also include a further variable from wave 1 that measures the proportion of anger about two unrelated matters, namely the National Health Service and the Iraq war. This index also ranges from 0 to 1 and has eight possible values. Overall, these two variables control for any factors that generally influence why people say they are angry rather than fearful about the economy or general political topics.
I also control for partisan affect. It is very important to control tightly for this given its strong influence on emotional reactions (Ladd and Lenz 2008, 2011), on perceptions of the economy (e.g. Gerber and Huber 2010) and on survey response overall (Rahn et al. 1994). I control for partisan affect by including indicators for party identification with the three main parties and for general affect for them, as measured in the last pre-crisis wave. Party identification is thus coded 1 for Labour, Conservative and Liberal Democrat identifiers respectively in wave 4 (May 2006), 0 otherwise.14 Those with a different or no party identification are used as the reference category. General affect is measured using the 0–10 like-dislike score for the three parties, also from wave 4 (May 2006), with higher values indicating more positive evaluations.15
I also control for economic ideology, measured as respondents’ preferences on cutting taxes or spending more on public services on a 0–10 scale. Left-wing respondents may be more likely to be angry about the crisis: ideologically, they may react more negatively towards financial institutions than right-wing voters. Since left–right economic ideology may also color opinions on responsibility for and handling of the crisis (Anderson 2007), it is important to control for this factor.16 Finally, I control for attention to politics in 2006 as panel attrition might be higher among respondents with lower levels of political interest.17

Results

I model the dependent variable using ordinary least squares (OLS) regression; results using ordinal logistic regression lead to substantively identical results (see supplemental information). I present eight models (Tables 3, 4). The first four test the first hypothesis, so whether responsibility attributions increase anger relative to fear, first without control variables (Model 1) and then with different sets of attitudinal controls (Models 2–4). The second four models test the second hypothesis, so whether anger is more likely if the national government is blamed rather than other external actors, again without (Model 5) and with the various controls (Models 6–8). Below, I discuss results mainly from Models 3 and 7, which include the main attitudinal and partisan controls, but the results are consistent across models.
Table 3
Assignment of responsibility and emotional reactions (1)
 
Model 1
Model 2
Model 3
Model 4
No controls
Minimal controls
Controls for party ID
Controls for party affect
Actors responsible, 2009
    
 Actor blamed (Ref: no one/DK)
0.102*** (0.024)
0.074** (0.026)
0.072** (0.026)
0.070** (0.027)
Emotional predispositions, 2005
 Proportion of anger, economy
 
0.167*** (0.031)
0.140*** (0.031)
0.107*** (0.032)
 Proportion of anger, NHS and Iraq
 
0.140*** (0.020)
0.122*** (0.020)
0.093*** (0.020)
Left–right economic ideology, 2006
 
0.019*** (0.003)
0.013*** (0.003)
0.010*** (0.003)
Attention to politics, 2006
 
0.010*** (0.003)
0.011*** (0.003)
0.009** (0.003)
Political efficacy, 2006
 
−0.007** (0.003)
−0.006* (0.003)
−0.004 (0.003)
Party identification, 2006
    
 Labour
  
−0.075*** (0.014)
−0.022 (0.017)
 Conservative
  
0.025 (0.015)
−0.004 (0.018)
 Liberal democrat
  
−0.041* (0.020)
−0.025 (0.021)
Party affect, 2006
    
 Labour
   
−0.015*** (0.003)
 Conservative
   
0.003 (0.003)
 Liberal democrat
   
−0.003 (0.003)
Constant
0.192*** (0.023)
0.029 (0.030)
0.085** (0.031)
0.162*** (0.038)
Observations
2,530
2,298
2,298
2,241
R 2
0.007
0.087
0.105
0.119
Adjusted R 2
0.007
0.084
0.102
0.114
Note The dependent variable is the proportion of ‘anger’ relative to the total number of angry and fearful emotions selected by the respondent (range: 0–1). Respondents selecting neither angry nor fearful emotions coded as 0. Standard errors in parentheses. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001. Data from BES internet panel 2005–2010. For coding details of the predictor variables, see text
Table 4
Assignment of responsibility and emotional reactions (2)
 
Model 5
Model 6
Model 7
Model 8
No controls
Minimal controls
Controls for party ID
Controls for party affect
Actors responsible, 2009
 National government
0.146*** (0.013)
0.105*** (0.014)
0.089*** (0.014)
0.074*** 0.015)
 United States
−0.018 (0.012)
−0.007 (0.013)
−0.005 (0.013)
−0.003 (0.013)
 Banks
−0.073** (0.028)
−0.034 (0.029)
−0.028 (0.029)
−0.029 (0.030)
 Mortgage holders
−0.002 (0.012)
−0.002 (0.012)
−0.004 (0.012)
−0.001 (0.012)
 European Union
0.032* (0.014)
0.036* (0.015)
0.037* (0.015)
0.039** (0.015)
 Don’t know/no one
−0.094** (0.036)
−0.051 (0.039)
−0.052 (0.038)
−0.059 (0.039)
Emotional predispositions, 2005
 Proportion of anger, economy
 
0.121*** (0.031)
0.109*** (0.031)
0.090** (0.031)
 Proportion of anger, NHS and Iraq
 
0.122*** (0.020)
0.112*** (0.020)
0.092*** (0.020)
Left–right economic ideology, 2006
 
0.014*** (0.003)
0.011*** (0.003)
0.009** (0.003)
Attention to politics, 2006
 
0.008** (0.003)
0.009** (0.003)
0.008** (0.003)
Political efficacy, 2006
 
−0.005 (0.003)
−0.005 (0.003)
−0.003 (0.003)
Party identification, 2006
 Labour
  
−0.050*** (0.015)
−0.017 (0.017)
 Conservative
  
0.016 (0.015)
−0.001 (0.018)
 Liberal democrat
  
−0.026 (0.019)
−0.016 (0.021)
Party affect, 2006
 Labour
   
−0.010*** (0.003)
 Conservative
   
0.001 (0.003)
 Liberal democrat
   
−0.002 (0.003)
Constant
0.286*** (0.028)
0.115** (0.037)
0.148*** (0.038)
0.206*** (0.044)
Observations
2,530
2,298
2,298
2,241
R 2
0.080
0.126
0.133
0.140
Adjusted R 2
0.078
0.122
0.128
0.133
Note The dependent variable is the proportion of ‘anger’ relative to the total number of angry and fearful emotions selected by the respondent (range: 0–1). Respondents selecting neither angry nor fearful emotions coded as 0. Standard errors in parentheses. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001. Data from BES internet panel 2005–2010. For coding details of the predictor variables, see text
Before we turn to the results relevant to the two hypotheses, I briefly describe the effects of the control variables, which mostly have the expected effects and are consistent across models. Thus, emotional predispositions are very influential: those voters who felt angrier about either the economy or Iraq and the NHS in 2005 are also more likely to feel angry about the financial crisis in 2010. Party identification with Labour reduces anger. The same pattern also holds if we control for general party affect (Model 4). These results are consistent with a partisan impact on emotional reactions (Ladd and Lenz 2008, 2011): since ‘their’ government was in charge, Labour supporters may have been less likely to experience anger. The more right-wing voters are in terms of economic ideology, the more likely they are to feel angry about the financial crisis; this goes against the prediction based on ideology, but fits with the impact of party affect. It may be that this item captures opposition to the fact that the crisis led to increased budget deficits and tax increases without cutting social spending. Finally, higher levels of attention to politics increase the probability of feeling angry compared to feeling afraid, while political efficacy has a weak but significant effect on the nature of negative emotional reactions.18
I begin with the first hypothesis, which states that citizens are more likely to feel anger if they blame an external actor. The key variable here is whether respondents chose one or more of the actors on the list of potential actors responsible; in other words, they did not answer ‘no one’ or ‘don’t know’. Models 1–4 show that people who blamed an actor were more likely to be angry compared to those respondents who did not.19 The increase in the proportion of anger relative to all anger/fear mentions is about 0.07. The effect is significant at the 0.05 level in all models. The effect is also of very similar magnitude to that of identifying with Labour and larger than that of economic ideology and attention to politics. There is thus support for the hypothesis that a substantively important predictor of anger about the crisis is whether an actor was seen as responsible for it.
The second hypothesis argued that the effect of blame assignment may be more nuanced, in that it matters whom citizens assign blame to. This hypothesis is tested in Models 5–8 (Table 4), where our main attention should be on the different responsibility indicators.
The results provide strong support for the hypothesis. Voters who believe that the UK government was one of the actors responsible for the financial crisis are more likely to be angry. The proportion of anger relative to all anger/fear mentions increases by 0.09 on the 0–1 scale. This effect is significant at the 0.001 level and substantively large compared to those of party identification, ideology and attention to politics. Blaming the EU also increases the proportion of anger relative to all anger/fear mentions; at 0.04 (p < 0.05), this effect is smaller than that of blaming the national government (Wald test, p < 0.05). The coefficient for blaming banks is negative but only significant in models without controls.
In sum, holding the UK government responsible has a large effect on the proportion of anger within anger and fear, while blaming the EU has a smaller, but still significant effect. Together with the fact that blaming banks has no significant effect, this pattern of results indicates that an accountability relationship appears to be necessary for blame to result in anger. Finally, the reasons why blaming banks and not blaming an actor at all fail to lead to anger are different: in the former case, the reason is a lack of an accountability relationship, while in the latter case the reason is the failure to identify an external cause for the threat.

The Consequences of Emotional Reactions

Anger should activate the approach system and lead individuals to attempt to remove the source of harm, while fear should activate the avoidance system and lead to risk-averse behavior. This expectation can be applied to vote choice after the financial crisis. The default decision of British citizens who voted Labour in 2005 might be to vote Labour again in 2010. However, anger about the financial crisis might lead such voters to re-evaluate their standing decision and try to remove Labour government, i.e. the source of the threat. In contrast, fear might lead voters to stick with their standing decision.20 So, I expect Labour voters in 2005 who are angry about the financial crisis to be less likely to vote Labour again in 2010. In contrast, Labour voters in 2010 who are fearful about the crisis should be likely to vote Labour again.
I test this using a binary logistic regression model (Table 5). The sample in Models 9 and 10 is restricted to Labour voters in 2005 who also voted in 2010. The dependent variable is measured as 1 if the respondent voted for Labour again in 2010, 0 if he/she voted for another party. Anger is measured as the number of times the respondent selected ‘angry’ as an emotion regarding the economy and the financial crisis; this variable ranges from 0 to 2. Fear is measured as the number of times the respondent selected ‘afraid’ and ‘uneasy’ as an emotion regarding the economy and the financial crisis; this variable ranges from 0 to 4. Model 9 shows the results of a simple model, while Model 10 adds key controls for emotional predispositions, partisan leanings and economic evaluations (see supplemental information for coding details).
Table 5
Emotional reactions and vote choice
 
Model 9
Model 10
Model 11
Model 12
2005 labour voters only
All 2005 voters
No controls
Controls included
No controls
Controls included
Anger mentions, 2010 (0–2)
−0.410** (0.129)
−0.344* (0.155)
0.063 (0.080)
−0.013 (0.108)
Fear mentions, 2010 (0–4)
−0.193* (0.082)
−0.074 (0.101)
−0.032 (0.054)
−0.051 (0.069)
Voted labour in 2005
  
0.298 (0.213)
−0.612* (0.266)
Voted labour * Anger mentions
  
−0.474** (0.152)
−0.378* (0.173)
Voted labour * Fear mentions
  
−0.162 (0.098)
−0.074 (0.113)
Identified with party of 2005 vote, 2006
 
1.216*** (0.300)
 
1.166*** (0.145)
Like-dislike for party of 2005 vote, 2006
 
0.189** (0.062)
 
0.182*** (0.035)
Anger mentions, NHS and Iraq, 2005 (0–2)
 
0.355 (0.194)
 
0.170 (0.100)
Fear mentions, NHS and Iraq, 2005 (0–4)
 
−0.027 (0.111)
 
−0.009 (0.061)
Anger mention, economy, 2005 (0/1)
 
1.034 (0.588)
 
−0.196 (0.211)
Fear mentions, economy, 2005 (0–2)
 
−0.470 (0.279)
 
−0.171 (0.149)
Personally affected by crisis, 2010 (0–3)
 
0.357* (0.180)
 
0.186 (0.102)
Egocentric economic evaluations, 2010
 
−0.141 (0.182)
 
−0.169 (0.106)
Sociotropic economic evaluations, 2010
 
−0.320* (0.151)
 
0.049 (0.089)
Constant
1.081*** (0.161)
−0.969 (0.617)
0.782*** (0.139)
−0.568 (0.358)
Observations
516
476
1,678
1,425
Note The dependent variable is 1 if the respondent voted for the same party in 2005 and 2010, 0 if not. Standard errors in parentheses. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001. Data from BES internet panel 2005–2010. For coding details of the predictor variables, see text
Based on Model 9, we can calculate that previous Labour supporters were about 14 % less likely to vote for Labour in 2010 if they were very angry about the economy rather than not angry at all.21 This effect is significant at the .05 level, and it is also substantively large: to compare, the effect of identifying with Labour in 2005 increases the probability of voting for Labour again in 2010 by 27 %.
Models 11 and 12 show that the effect of anger was restricted to Labour voters. These models use the full sample of 2005 voters; the dependent variable is 1 if the respondent voted for the same party as in 2005, 0 if not. Emotional reactions are interacted with having voted Labour in 2005. The negative statistical significance of the interaction term along with the absence of an effect among other voters shows that anger led to a change in behavior specifically among previous Labour voters.

Discussion and Conclusion

When are voters angry in reaction to the economic situation, and when are they afraid? In this paper, I have argued that citizens respond with anger when they hold an external actor responsible for the crisis. Moreover, anger is particularly likely when individuals see the actor responsible as their agent. Individuals are more likely to get angry if they think the threat arose due to the actions of an agent who should have placed greater weight on their welfare. These two hypotheses held in the case of the financial crisis: voters were angrier when they assigned blame for the crisis, but anger was increased only when they blamed the national government and, to a lesser extent, the EU.
These findings are important because understanding how citizens vary in how they interpret and appraise negative events helps us explain why their political reactions to these events differ (MacKuen et al. 2010). There has been a lot of recent work examining how variation in emotional reactions leads to differences in political behavior, for example in terms of vote choice, political attitudes, participation and learning (Weber 2012). However, a full picture of the importance of emotions in politics also requires an understanding of the determinants of these emotional reactions. This paper shows that the nature of blame assignment has a strong influence on emotional reactions.
Finally, it is important to note important limitations of the present findings; these also present potential ways of extending this research. First, it was not possible to test the specific causal mechanism why individuals were angry about the economy when they blamed their political agents. It was suggested that the likely cause is a perception that the actor should be under the individual’s control but that has paid insufficient attention to the individual’s welfare. Due to the lack of suitable survey measures in the British Election Study, the accuracy of this suggested mechanism cannot be definitively confirmed here.
Second, this paper has argued that the causal arrow between anger and blame is in the following direction: a threat to an individual arises; the individual decides whether or not to assign blame for that threat to an actor; this appraisal of the situation leads the individual to experience certain emotions, including anger and fear. However, it may also be that angry individuals seek to assign blame (Frijda 1993; Berkowitz and Harmon-Jones 2004), and that such people may decide to blame in particular those actors whose principal they are. Existing research in psychology has not been able to disentangle these two plausible causal stories, and providing a clearer causal account should be a task for future research.
Third, this research has highlighted the importance of distinguishing between fear and anger. However, other negative emotions exist as well. In particular, disgust has been shown to have political importance (e.g. Vandenbroek 2011; Banks and Valentino 2012), and its origins also deserve to be studied.
Finally, future work should engage in a comparative effort. Blame assignments are strongly shaped by institutional arrangements. For example, voters may be more willing to attribute responsibility for economic outcomes to the government where there is ‘clarity of responsibility’ (Powell and Whitten 1993; Anderson 2000), both at the national level and across other levels of governance. Whether there is clarity of responsibility depends partly on the institutional structure of the state; for example, electoral systems affect the existence of clear alternatives in a party system (Powell and Vanberg 2000). This may also mean that anger in reaction to negative economic events is also greater in systems with higher clarity of responsibility. As a result, how emotional reactions to political events differ across countries may depend on quite familiar concepts and institutions related to citizen control. These emotions may then play an important role in determining how the economy influences political behavior.

Acknowledgments

I would like to thank the editors and the three anonymous reviewers for the comments on earlier versions of this article. Research on this article was financed by the Austrian Science Fund under the ‘Austrian National Election Study’ project (AUTNES, S10902-G11).
Open AccessThis article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License which permits any use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author(s) and the source are credited.
Appendix

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.
Footnotes
1
In this paper, fear and anxiety are treated as synonymous terms.
 
2
One important exception is MacKuen et al. (2010), who argue that aversion, which includes anger and disgust, activates the disposition system, just like positive emotions.
 
3
In their summary of recent research on the consequences of fear and anger, Valentino et al. (2008, p. 249) however note that while the finding that anger mobilizes action is clear and strong, the consequences of fear may be more variable.
 
4
This fits with the way political science researchers measure emotional responses, namely by asking participants in surveys and experiments to report their emotional reactions (Valentino et al. 2011). This means that the emotions political scientists generally tend to study are emotions that are consciously experienced and are reported after some level of individual self-examination.
 
5
It is worth noting that the link between blame and anger is not undisputed. For example, Berkowitz and Harmon-Jones (2004, p. 117) write that ‘[t]he anger evoked by the aversive state of affairs could at times seem unreasonable to those affected and thereby provoke a search for some external source to blame,… perhaps in an attempt to justify the feelings, ideas, and impulses that are experienced.’ A similar argument is made by Frijda (1993). At the very least, there may be a reciprocal relationship between blame and anger.
 
6
In a different context and based on evolutionary psychology, Petersen et al. (2012) show that anger towards welfare recipients depends on whether they are seen as responsible for their own poverty, e.g. because they lack motivation to work.
 
7
They add that sadness is caused when we blame general ‘situational’ events for the threat and shame/guilt when we blame ourselves for the event.
 
8
See Berkowitz and Harmon-Jones (2004, p. 116) for arguments against the importance of coping potential as a cause of anger.
 
9
The concept of self-control does not clearly relate to either internal or external efficacy. Internal efficacy is the extent to which an individual considers herself to be competent to understand and participate in politics, external efficacy the extent an individual considers the government to be responsive to citizen demands (Niemi et al. 1991). A perception of control over actors arguably requires both types of efficacy.
 
10
Weighted using YouGov’s non-political weight. The distribution of responses is similar if we use the same question asked in the 2010 survey and if we use the 2005 question asking about government influence on one’s personal financial situation.
 
11
Unfortunately, the BES questionnaire does not contain items that measure the extent to which individuals see situational causes as responsible for the crisis (e.g. globalization, capitalism or greed). Cognitive appraisal theories would predict that perceptions of situational control should lead to increased fear relative to anger.
 
12
‘Disgust’, the final negative emotion that respondents could select, is left out of the analysis. While potentially related to anger (Marcus et al. 2000; MacKuen et al. 2010), many researchers now separate these two emotions (e.g. Vandenbroek 2011; Banks and Valentino 2012).
 
13
The question text is: ‘On a scale from 0 to 10, where 10 means a great deal of influence and 0 means no influence, how much influence do you have on politics and public affairs?’.
 
14
Wave 4 answers used because the party identification questions were not asked in the standard format in wave 1. The question text from wave 4 is: ‘Generally speaking, do you think of yourself as Labour, Conservative, Liberal Democrat or what?’.
 
15
The question text is: ‘On a scale that runs from 0 to 10, where 0 means strongly dislike and 10 means strongly like, how to you feel about the Labour Party?’.
 
16
0 means that ‘government should cut taxes a lot and spend much less on health and social services’, and 10 that ‘government should raise taxes a lot and spend much more on health and social services’. The coding of this variable was reversed in the analysis.
 
17
The question text is: ‘On a scale of 0–10, how much attention do you generally pay to politics?’.
 
18
This weak effect can be explained by the decision to include respondents without any emotion in the model; models excluding these respondents show no significant effect of political efficacy (see supplemental information).
 
19
Note that respondents expressing neither anger nor fear are coded as 0. The results do not change substantively if these respondents are excluded (see supplemental material).
 
20
Looking at turnout is not possible using the panel data due to the very low number of respondents reporting abstention in 2010.
 
21
These predicted probabilities are calculated using the observed-values approach suggested in Hanmer and Ozan Kalkan (2012).
 
Literature
go back to reference Abelson, R. P. (1968). Theories of cognitive consistency: A sourcebook. Chicago: Rand McNally. Abelson, R. P. (1968). Theories of cognitive consistency: A sourcebook. Chicago: Rand McNally.
go back to reference Anderson, C. J. (2000). Economic voting and political context: A comparative perspective. Electoral Studies, 19, 151–170.CrossRef Anderson, C. J. (2000). Economic voting and political context: A comparative perspective. Electoral Studies, 19, 151–170.CrossRef
go back to reference Anderson, C. J. (2007). The end of economic voting? Contingency dilemmas and the limits of democratic accountability. Annual Review of Political Science, 10, 271–296.CrossRef Anderson, C. J. (2007). The end of economic voting? Contingency dilemmas and the limits of democratic accountability. Annual Review of Political Science, 10, 271–296.CrossRef
go back to reference Balch, G. I. (1974). Multiple indicators in survey research: The concept of ‘Sense of Political Efficacy’. Political Methodology, 1, 1–43. Balch, G. I. (1974). Multiple indicators in survey research: The concept of ‘Sense of Political Efficacy’. Political Methodology, 1, 1–43.
go back to reference Banks, A. J., & Valentino, N. A. (2012). Emotional substrates of white racial attitudes. American Journal of Political Science, 56(2), 286–297.CrossRef Banks, A. J., & Valentino, N. A. (2012). Emotional substrates of white racial attitudes. American Journal of Political Science, 56(2), 286–297.CrossRef
go back to reference Berkowitz, L., & Harmon-Jones, E. (2004). Toward an understanding of the determinants of anger. Emotion, 4(2), 107–130.CrossRef Berkowitz, L., & Harmon-Jones, E. (2004). Toward an understanding of the determinants of anger. Emotion, 4(2), 107–130.CrossRef
go back to reference Best, S. J., & Krueger, B. S. (2011). Government monitoring and political participation in the United States: The distinct roles of anger and anxiety. American Politics Research, 39, 85–117.CrossRef Best, S. J., & Krueger, B. S. (2011). Government monitoring and political participation in the United States: The distinct roles of anger and anxiety. American Politics Research, 39, 85–117.CrossRef
go back to reference Brader, T. (2005). Striking a responsive chord: How campaign ads motivate and persuade voters by appealing to emotions. American Journal of Political Science, 49(2), 388–405. Brader, T. (2005). Striking a responsive chord: How campaign ads motivate and persuade voters by appealing to emotions. American Journal of Political Science, 49(2), 388–405.
go back to reference Brader, T. (2006). Campaigning for hearts and minds: How emotional appeals in political ads work. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Brader, T. (2006). Campaigning for hearts and minds: How emotional appeals in political ads work. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
go back to reference Brader, T., Groenendyk, E. W., & Valentino, N. A. (2010). Fight or flight? When political threats arouse public anger and fear. Paper presented at the Midwest Political Science Association Annual Meeting, 2011, Chicago, IL, March 31–April 3. Brader, T., Groenendyk, E. W., & Valentino, N. A. (2010). Fight or flight? When political threats arouse public anger and fear. Paper presented at the Midwest Political Science Association Annual Meeting, 2011, Chicago, IL, March 31–April 3.
go back to reference Cacioppo, J. T., Gardner, W. L., & Berntson, G. G. (1999). The affect system has parallel and integrative processing components: Form follows function. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 76(5), 839–855.CrossRef Cacioppo, J. T., Gardner, W. L., & Berntson, G. G. (1999). The affect system has parallel and integrative processing components: Form follows function. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 76(5), 839–855.CrossRef
go back to reference Carver, C., & Harmon-Jones, E. (2009). Anger is an approach-related affect: Evidence and implications. Psychological Bulletin, 135, 183–204.CrossRef Carver, C., & Harmon-Jones, E. (2009). Anger is an approach-related affect: Evidence and implications. Psychological Bulletin, 135, 183–204.CrossRef
go back to reference Cassese, E., & Weber, C. (2011). Emotion, appraisals, and attitudes towards crime. Journal of Integrated Social Sciences, 2(1), 63–97. Cassese, E., & Weber, C. (2011). Emotion, appraisals, and attitudes towards crime. Journal of Integrated Social Sciences, 2(1), 63–97.
go back to reference Conover, P. J., & Feldman, S. (1986). Emotional reactions to the economy: I’m mad as hell and I’m not going to take it anymore. American Journal of Political Science, 30, 50–78.CrossRef Conover, P. J., & Feldman, S. (1986). Emotional reactions to the economy: I’m mad as hell and I’m not going to take it anymore. American Journal of Political Science, 30, 50–78.CrossRef
go back to reference Damasio, A. R. (1994). Descartes’ error: Emotion, reason, and the human brain. New York: GP Putnam’s Sons. Damasio, A. R. (1994). Descartes’ error: Emotion, reason, and the human brain. New York: GP Putnam’s Sons.
go back to reference Druckman, J., & McDermott, R. (2008). Emotion and the framing of risky choice. Political Behavior, 30, 297–321.CrossRef Druckman, J., & McDermott, R. (2008). Emotion and the framing of risky choice. Political Behavior, 30, 297–321.CrossRef
go back to reference Eagly, A., & Chaiken, S. (1993). The psychology of attitudes. Fort Worth, TX: Harcourt. Eagly, A., & Chaiken, S. (1993). The psychology of attitudes. Fort Worth, TX: Harcourt.
go back to reference Easton, D. (1965). A systems analysis of political life. New York: Wiley. Easton, D. (1965). A systems analysis of political life. New York: Wiley.
go back to reference Easton, D., & Dennis, J. (1967). The child’s acquisition of regime norms: Political efficacy. The American Political Science Review, 61(1), 25–38.CrossRef Easton, D., & Dennis, J. (1967). The child’s acquisition of regime norms: Political efficacy. The American Political Science Review, 61(1), 25–38.CrossRef
go back to reference Frijda, N. H. (1986). The emotions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Frijda, N. H. (1986). The emotions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Frijda, N. H. (1993). The place of appraisal in emotion. Cognition and Emotion, 7, 357–387.CrossRef Frijda, N. H. (1993). The place of appraisal in emotion. Cognition and Emotion, 7, 357–387.CrossRef
go back to reference Frijda, N. H., Kuipers, P., & ten Schure, E. (1989). Relations among emotion, appraisal and emotional action readiness. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 57, 212–228.CrossRef Frijda, N. H., Kuipers, P., & ten Schure, E. (1989). Relations among emotion, appraisal and emotional action readiness. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 57, 212–228.CrossRef
go back to reference Gerber, A. S., & Huber, G. A. (2010). Partisanship, political control, and economic assessments. American Journal of Political Science, 54(1), 163–173.CrossRef Gerber, A. S., & Huber, G. A. (2010). Partisanship, political control, and economic assessments. American Journal of Political Science, 54(1), 163–173.CrossRef
go back to reference Gray, J. A. (1990). Brain systems that mediate both emotion and cognition. Cognition and Emotion, 4(3), 269–288. Gray, J. A. (1990). Brain systems that mediate both emotion and cognition. Cognition and Emotion, 4(3), 269–288.
go back to reference Groenendyk, E. (2011). Current emotion research in political science: How emotions help democracy overcome its collective action problem. Emotion Review, 3, 455–463.CrossRef Groenendyk, E. (2011). Current emotion research in political science: How emotions help democracy overcome its collective action problem. Emotion Review, 3, 455–463.CrossRef
go back to reference Hanmer, M. J., & Ozan Kalkan, K. (2012). Behind the curve: Clarifying the best approach to calculating predicted probabilities and marginal effects from limited dependent variable models. American Journal of Political Science, 57(1), 263–277.CrossRef Hanmer, M. J., & Ozan Kalkan, K. (2012). Behind the curve: Clarifying the best approach to calculating predicted probabilities and marginal effects from limited dependent variable models. American Journal of Political Science, 57(1), 263–277.CrossRef
go back to reference Hellwig, T., & Coffey, E. (2011). Public opinion, party messages, and responsibility for the financial crisis in Britain. Electoral Studies, 30, 417–426.CrossRef Hellwig, T., & Coffey, E. (2011). Public opinion, party messages, and responsibility for the financial crisis in Britain. Electoral Studies, 30, 417–426.CrossRef
go back to reference Hellwig, T. T., Ringsmuth, E. M., & Freeman, J. R. (2008). The American public and the room to maneuver: Responsibility attributions and policy efficacy in an era of globalization. International Studies Quarterly, 52, 855–880.CrossRef Hellwig, T. T., Ringsmuth, E. M., & Freeman, J. R. (2008). The American public and the room to maneuver: Responsibility attributions and policy efficacy in an era of globalization. International Studies Quarterly, 52, 855–880.CrossRef
go back to reference Hobolt, S. B., Tilley, J., & Wittrock, J. (2013). Listening to the government: How information shapes responsibility attributions. Political Behavior, 35(1), 153–174.CrossRef Hobolt, S. B., Tilley, J., & Wittrock, J. (2013). Listening to the government: How information shapes responsibility attributions. Political Behavior, 35(1), 153–174.CrossRef
go back to reference Huddy, L., Feldman, S., & Cassese, E. (2007). On the distinct political effects of anxiety and anger. In W. R. Neuman, G. E. Marcus, A. N. Crigler, & M. MacKuen (Eds.), The affect effect: Dynamics of emotion in political thinking and behaviour. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. Huddy, L., Feldman, S., & Cassese, E. (2007). On the distinct political effects of anxiety and anger. In W. R. Neuman, G. E. Marcus, A. N. Crigler, & M. MacKuen (Eds.), The affect effect: Dynamics of emotion in political thinking and behaviour. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.
go back to reference Huddy, L., Feldman, S., Taber, C., & Lahav, G. (2005). Threat, anxiety, and support of antiterrorism policies. American Journal of Political Science, 49, 593–608.CrossRef Huddy, L., Feldman, S., Taber, C., & Lahav, G. (2005). Threat, anxiety, and support of antiterrorism policies. American Journal of Political Science, 49, 593–608.CrossRef
go back to reference Johns, R. (2011). Credit where it’s due? Valence politics, attributions of responsibility, and multi-level elections. Political Behavior, 33, 53–77.CrossRef Johns, R. (2011). Credit where it’s due? Valence politics, attributions of responsibility, and multi-level elections. Political Behavior, 33, 53–77.CrossRef
go back to reference Ladd, J. M. D., & Lenz, G. S. (2008). Reassessing the role of anxiety in vote choice. Political Psychology, 29, 275–296.CrossRef Ladd, J. M. D., & Lenz, G. S. (2008). Reassessing the role of anxiety in vote choice. Political Psychology, 29, 275–296.CrossRef
go back to reference Ladd, J. M., & Lenz, G. S. (2011). Does anxiety improve voters’ decision making? Political Psychology, 32, 347–361.CrossRef Ladd, J. M., & Lenz, G. S. (2011). Does anxiety improve voters’ decision making? Political Psychology, 32, 347–361.CrossRef
go back to reference Lazarus, R. S. (1991). Emotion and adaptation. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Lazarus, R. S. (1991). Emotion and adaptation. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Lazarus, R. S. (2001). Relational meaning and discrete emotions. In K. R. Scherer, A. Schorr, & T. Johnstone (Eds.), Appraisal processes in emotion: Theory, methods, research. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Lazarus, R. S. (2001). Relational meaning and discrete emotions. In K. R. Scherer, A. Schorr, & T. Johnstone (Eds.), Appraisal processes in emotion: Theory, methods, research. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Lazarus, R. S., & Lazarus, B. N. (1994). Passion and reason: Making sense of our emotions. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Lazarus, R. S., & Lazarus, B. N. (1994). Passion and reason: Making sense of our emotions. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Leach, C. W., Iyer, A., & Pedersen, A. (2006). Anger and guilt about in-group advantage explain the willingness for political action. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 32, 1232–1245.CrossRef Leach, C. W., Iyer, A., & Pedersen, A. (2006). Anger and guilt about in-group advantage explain the willingness for political action. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 32, 1232–1245.CrossRef
go back to reference Lerner, J. S., & Keltner, D. (2000). Beyond valence: Toward a model of emotion-specific influences on judgement and choice. Cognition and Emotion, 14, 473–493.CrossRef Lerner, J. S., & Keltner, D. (2000). Beyond valence: Toward a model of emotion-specific influences on judgement and choice. Cognition and Emotion, 14, 473–493.CrossRef
go back to reference Lerner, J. S., & Keltner, D. (2001). Fear, anger, and risk. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 81, 146–159.CrossRef Lerner, J. S., & Keltner, D. (2001). Fear, anger, and risk. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 81, 146–159.CrossRef
go back to reference Lerner, J. S., & Tiedens, L. Z. (2006). Portrait of the angry decision maker: How appraisal tendencies shape anger’s influence on cognition. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 19, 115–137.CrossRef Lerner, J. S., & Tiedens, L. Z. (2006). Portrait of the angry decision maker: How appraisal tendencies shape anger’s influence on cognition. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 19, 115–137.CrossRef
go back to reference MacKuen, M., Wolak, J., Keele, L., & Marcus, G. (2010). Civic engagements: Resolute partisanship or reflective deliberation. American Journal of Political Science, 54, 440–458.CrossRef MacKuen, M., Wolak, J., Keele, L., & Marcus, G. (2010). Civic engagements: Resolute partisanship or reflective deliberation. American Journal of Political Science, 54, 440–458.CrossRef
go back to reference Marcus, G. E. (2003). The psychology of emotion and politics. In L. Huddy, D. Sears, & R. Jervis (Eds.), Oxford Handbook of Political Psychology. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Marcus, G. E. (2003). The psychology of emotion and politics. In L. Huddy, D. Sears, & R. Jervis (Eds.), Oxford Handbook of Political Psychology. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Marcus, G. E. (2013). Political psychology: Neuroscience, genetics, and politics. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Marcus, G. E. (2013). Political psychology: Neuroscience, genetics, and politics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Marcus, G. E., & MacKuen, M. B. (1993). Anxiety, enthusiasm, and the vote: The emotional underpinnings of learning and involvement during presidential campaigns. American Political Science Review, 87, 672–685.CrossRef Marcus, G. E., & MacKuen, M. B. (1993). Anxiety, enthusiasm, and the vote: The emotional underpinnings of learning and involvement during presidential campaigns. American Political Science Review, 87, 672–685.CrossRef
go back to reference Marcus, G. E., Neuman, W. R., & MacKuen, M. B. (2000). Affective intelligence and political judgment. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. Marcus, G. E., Neuman, W. R., & MacKuen, M. B. (2000). Affective intelligence and political judgment. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.
go back to reference Marsh, M., & Tilley, J. (2010). The attribution of credit and blame to governments and its impact on vote choice. British Journal of Political Science, 40(1), 115–134.CrossRef Marsh, M., & Tilley, J. (2010). The attribution of credit and blame to governments and its impact on vote choice. British Journal of Political Science, 40(1), 115–134.CrossRef
go back to reference Müller, W. C. (2000). Political parties in parliamentary democracies: Making delegation and accountability work. European Journal of Political Research, 37, 309–333. Müller, W. C. (2000). Political parties in parliamentary democracies: Making delegation and accountability work. European Journal of Political Research, 37, 309–333.
go back to reference Niemi, R. G., Craig, S. C., & Mattei, F. (1991). Measuring internal political efficacy in the 1988 National Election Study. American Political Science Review, 85(4), 1407–1413.CrossRef Niemi, R. G., Craig, S. C., & Mattei, F. (1991). Measuring internal political efficacy in the 1988 National Election Study. American Political Science Review, 85(4), 1407–1413.CrossRef
go back to reference Petersen, M. B. (2010). Distinct emotions, distinct domains: Anger, anxiety and perceptions of intentionality. Journal of Politics, 72(2), 357–365.CrossRef Petersen, M. B. (2010). Distinct emotions, distinct domains: Anger, anxiety and perceptions of intentionality. Journal of Politics, 72(2), 357–365.CrossRef
go back to reference Petersen, M. B., Sznycer, D., Cosmides, L., & Tooby, J. (2012). Who deserves help? Evolutionary psychology, social emotions, and public opinion about welfare. Political Psychology, 33(3), 395–418.CrossRef Petersen, M. B., Sznycer, D., Cosmides, L., & Tooby, J. (2012). Who deserves help? Evolutionary psychology, social emotions, and public opinion about welfare. Political Psychology, 33(3), 395–418.CrossRef
go back to reference Powell, G. B., & Vanberg, G. S. (2000). Election laws, disproportionality and median correspondence: Implications for two visions of democracy. British Journal of Political Science, 30, 383–411.CrossRef Powell, G. B., & Vanberg, G. S. (2000). Election laws, disproportionality and median correspondence: Implications for two visions of democracy. British Journal of Political Science, 30, 383–411.CrossRef
go back to reference Powell, G. B., & Whitten, G. (1993). A cross-national analysis of economic voting: Taking account of the political context. American Journal of Political Science, 37(2), 391–414.CrossRef Powell, G. B., & Whitten, G. (1993). A cross-national analysis of economic voting: Taking account of the political context. American Journal of Political Science, 37(2), 391–414.CrossRef
go back to reference Rahn, W. M., Krosnick, J. A., & Breuning, M. (1994). Rationalization and derivation processes in survey studies of political candidate evaluation. American Journal of Political Science, 38, 582–600.CrossRef Rahn, W. M., Krosnick, J. A., & Breuning, M. (1994). Rationalization and derivation processes in survey studies of political candidate evaluation. American Journal of Political Science, 38, 582–600.CrossRef
go back to reference Roseman, I. J., Antoniou, A. A., & Jose, P. E. (1996). Appraisal determinants of emotions: Constructing a more accurate and comprehensive theory. Cognition and Emotion, 10, 241–277.CrossRef Roseman, I. J., Antoniou, A. A., & Jose, P. E. (1996). Appraisal determinants of emotions: Constructing a more accurate and comprehensive theory. Cognition and Emotion, 10, 241–277.CrossRef
go back to reference Roseman, I. J., Spindel, M. S., & Jose, P. E. (1990). Appraisals of emotion-eliciting events: Testing a theory of discrete emotions. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 59, 899–915.CrossRef Roseman, I. J., Spindel, M. S., & Jose, P. E. (1990). Appraisals of emotion-eliciting events: Testing a theory of discrete emotions. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 59, 899–915.CrossRef
go back to reference Rudolph, T. J. (2003). Who’s responsible for the economy? The formation and consequences of responsibility attributions. American Journal of Political Science, 47, 698–713.CrossRef Rudolph, T. J. (2003). Who’s responsible for the economy? The formation and consequences of responsibility attributions. American Journal of Political Science, 47, 698–713.CrossRef
go back to reference Rudolph, T. J., & Grant, J. T. (2002). An attributional model of economic voting: Evidence from the 2000 presidential election. Political Research Quarterly, 55(4), 805–823.CrossRef Rudolph, T. J., & Grant, J. T. (2002). An attributional model of economic voting: Evidence from the 2000 presidential election. Political Research Quarterly, 55(4), 805–823.CrossRef
go back to reference Rudolph, T. J., Gangl, A., & Stevens, D. (2000). The effects of efficacy and emotions on campaign involvement. Journal of Politics, 62, 1189–1197.CrossRef Rudolph, T. J., Gangl, A., & Stevens, D. (2000). The effects of efficacy and emotions on campaign involvement. Journal of Politics, 62, 1189–1197.CrossRef
go back to reference Sanders, D., Clarke, H. D., Stewart, M. C., & Whiteley, P. (2007). Does mode matter for modeling political choice? Evidence from the 2005 British Election Study. Political Analysis, 15(3), 257–285.CrossRef Sanders, D., Clarke, H. D., Stewart, M. C., & Whiteley, P. (2007). Does mode matter for modeling political choice? Evidence from the 2005 British Election Study. Political Analysis, 15(3), 257–285.CrossRef
go back to reference Sanders, D., Clarke, H. D., Stewart, M. C., & Whiteley, P. (2011). Downs, Stokes and the dynamics of electoral choice. British Journal of Political Science, 41, 287–314.CrossRef Sanders, D., Clarke, H. D., Stewart, M. C., & Whiteley, P. (2011). Downs, Stokes and the dynamics of electoral choice. British Journal of Political Science, 41, 287–314.CrossRef
go back to reference Schwarz, N., & Sudman, S. (Eds.). (1992). Context effects in social and psychological research. New York: Springer Verlag. Schwarz, N., & Sudman, S. (Eds.). (1992). Context effects in social and psychological research. New York: Springer Verlag.
go back to reference Sell, A., Tooby, J., & Cosmides, L. (2009). Formidability and the logic of human anger. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 106(35), 15073–15078.CrossRef Sell, A., Tooby, J., & Cosmides, L. (2009). Formidability and the logic of human anger. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 106(35), 15073–15078.CrossRef
go back to reference Smith, H. J., Cronin, T., & Kessler, T. (2008). Anger, fear, or sadness: Faculty members’ emotional reactions to collective pay disadvantage. Political Psychology, 29, 221–246.CrossRef Smith, H. J., Cronin, T., & Kessler, T. (2008). Anger, fear, or sadness: Faculty members’ emotional reactions to collective pay disadvantage. Political Psychology, 29, 221–246.CrossRef
go back to reference Smith, C. A., & Ellsworth, P. C. (1985). Patterns of cognitive appraisal in emotion. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 48, 813–838.CrossRef Smith, C. A., & Ellsworth, P. C. (1985). Patterns of cognitive appraisal in emotion. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 48, 813–838.CrossRef
go back to reference Valentino, N. A., Brader, T., Groenendyk, E. W., Gregorowicz, K., & Hutchings, V. (2011). Election night’s alright for fighting: The role of emotions in political participation. Journal of Politics, 73(1), 156–170.CrossRef Valentino, N. A., Brader, T., Groenendyk, E. W., Gregorowicz, K., & Hutchings, V. (2011). Election night’s alright for fighting: The role of emotions in political participation. Journal of Politics, 73(1), 156–170.CrossRef
go back to reference Valentino, N. A., Gregorowicz, K., & Groenendyk, E. W. (2009). Efficacy, emotions and the habit of participation. Political Behavior, 31, 307–330.CrossRef Valentino, N. A., Gregorowicz, K., & Groenendyk, E. W. (2009). Efficacy, emotions and the habit of participation. Political Behavior, 31, 307–330.CrossRef
go back to reference Valentino, N. A., Hutchings, V. L., Banks, A. J., & Davis, A. K. (2008). Is a worried citizen a good citizen? Emotions, political information seeking, and learning via the internet. Political Psychology, 29(2), 247–273.CrossRef Valentino, N. A., Hutchings, V. L., Banks, A. J., & Davis, A. K. (2008). Is a worried citizen a good citizen? Emotions, political information seeking, and learning via the internet. Political Psychology, 29(2), 247–273.CrossRef
go back to reference van Zomeren, M., Spears, R., Fischer, A., & Leach, C. W. (2004). Put your money where your mouth is! Explaining collective action tendencies through group-based anger and group efficacy. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 87, 649–664.CrossRef van Zomeren, M., Spears, R., Fischer, A., & Leach, C. W. (2004). Put your money where your mouth is! Explaining collective action tendencies through group-based anger and group efficacy. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 87, 649–664.CrossRef
go back to reference Vandenbroek, L. M. (2011). Disentangling aversion: Experimentally testing the impact of disgust and anger on political participation. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Seattle, September 2011. Vandenbroek, L. M. (2011). Disentangling aversion: Experimentally testing the impact of disgust and anger on political participation. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Seattle, September 2011.
go back to reference Weber, C. (2012). Emotions, campaigns and political participation. Political Research Quarterly, 66(2), 414–428. Weber, C. (2012). Emotions, campaigns and political participation. Political Research Quarterly, 66(2), 414–428.
go back to reference Weiner, B. (1985). An attributional theory of achievement motivation and emotion. Psychological Review, 92, 548–573.CrossRef Weiner, B. (1985). An attributional theory of achievement motivation and emotion. Psychological Review, 92, 548–573.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Fear and Anger in Great Britain: Blame Assignment and Emotional Reactions to the Financial Crisis
Author
Markus Wagner
Publication date
01-09-2014
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Political Behavior / Issue 3/2014
Print ISSN: 0190-9320
Electronic ISSN: 1573-6687
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11109-013-9241-5

Other articles of this Issue 3/2014

Political Behavior 3/2014 Go to the issue

Premium Partner