Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Annals of Finance 3/2020

Open Access 26-05-2020 | Research Article

Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing under fixed and proportional transaction costs

Authors: Martin Brown, Tomasz Zastawniak

Published in: Annals of Finance | Issue 3/2020

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

We show that the absence of arbitrage in a model with both fixed and proportional transaction costs is equivalent to the existence of a family of absolutely continuous single-step probability measures, together with an adapted process with values within the bid-ask intervals that satisfies the martingale property with respect to each of the measures. This extends Harrison and Pliska’s classical Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing to the case of combined fixed and proportional transaction costs.
Notes

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

1 Introduction

The Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing (FTAP), characterising the absence of arbitrage opportunities as equivalent to the existence of a risk neutral probability measure, has been studied for a large variety of financial market models. The first to establish the result for discrete time models with finite state space were Harrison and Pliska (1981). Dalang et al. (1990) extended the theorem to the case of infinite state space, and Delbaen and Schachermayer (1994, 2006) to continuous-time models.
The above classical results apply to frictionless models. Harrison and Pliska’s result was extended to models with proportional transaction costs by Jouini and Kallal (1995), Kabanov and Stricker (2001) and Ortu (2001). Furthermore, Roux (2011) included interest rate spreads in addition to proportional transaction costs. Similarly, the result by Dalang et al. (1990) involving an infinite state space was extended to models with proportional transaction costs by Zhang and Deng (2002), Kabanov et al. (2002) and Schachermayer (2004). Important milestone achievements concerning the Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing in the presence of proportional transaction costs also include, in chronological order, Kabanov (1999), Grigorev (2005), Bouchard (2006), Guasoni (2006), Cherny (2007), Kabanov and Safarian (2009), Guasoni et al. (2010, 2012), Denis and Kabanov (2012), Dolinsky and Soner (2014), Rola (2015), Lépinette and Tran (2016, 2017) and Zhao and Lépinette (2018), among others.
Under fixed transaction costs, to our best knowledge, the equivalence between the absence of arbitrage and the existence of risk neutral measures has so far been studied in just one paper, by Jouini et al. (2001). Moreover, characterizations of no-arbitrage conditions for fixed-cost models in terms of separating risk measures (rather than risk neutral measures) are contained as special cases in the work of Lépinette and Tran (2016, 2017).
The long-standing question of extending the Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing to cover the situation when both fixed and proportional transaction costs apply simultaneously is addressed in the present paper. We use the term ‘combined costs’ as shorthand when referring to this case. Such costs are ubiquitous in the markets, hence it is important to be able to characterise the absence of arbitrage in their presence. In Theorem 1 we show that the absence of arbitrage in a market with combined costs is equivalent to the existence of a family of single-step probability measures absolutely continuous with respect to (but not necessarily equivalent to) the physical probability, along with a martingale with respect to such a family of measures (as defined in Sect. 2) and taking values between the bid and ask prices. By doing so, we extend the classical result of Harrison and Pliska (1981) for a finite state space to the case of combined costs. Later on, in Corollary 2 we provide another equivalent condition for the absence of combined-cost arbitrage, namely the existence of an embedded arbitrage-free model with fixed costs.
The technical difficulties inherent in the problem solved here are due to a combination of two factors. On the one hand, under proportional costs, the absence of arbitrage in the full multi-step model is not equivalent to the condition that every single-step submodel should be arbitrage free (even though such an equivalence holds in frictionless models as well as under fixed costs), preventing an argument by reduction to a single step. On the other hand, fixed costs imply that the set of solvent portfolios suffers from the lack of convexity. While these difficulties have been tackled separately in the context of proportional costs and, respectively, fixed costs only, they require fresh ideas to handle their compounded effect. This is achieved in the proof of Theorem 1.
Finally, we refer to the recent work by Lépinette and Tran (2016, 2017), in which arbitrage in a non-convex market model with friction (including the case of simultaneous fixed and proportional costs) has been considered, and the absence of asymptotic arbitrage has been characterised by the existence of a so-called equivalent separating probability measure. However, no link has been made with risk neutral probabilities, by contrast to the present paper.

2 Notation and preliminaries

Let T be a positive integer and let \(\left( \varOmega ,\varSigma ,\mathbb {P} \right) \) be a finite probability space equipped with a filtration \(\mathscr {F}=\left( \mathscr {F}_{t}\right) _{t=0}^{T}\). We assume (without loss of generality) that the physical measure \(\mathbb {P}\) satisfies the condition \(\mathbb {P}(A)>0\) for each non-empty \(A\in \mathscr {F}_{T}\), and the sigma-field \(\mathscr {F}_{0}\) has a single atom, that is, \(\mathscr {F} _{0}=\{\emptyset ,\varOmega \}\). We refer to the atoms of \(\mathscr {F}_{t}\) as the nodes at time \(t=0,\ldots ,T\), and write \(\varLambda _{t}\) for the set of nodes at time \(t=0,\ldots ,T\). For any non-terminal node \(\lambda \in \varLambda _{t}\), where \(t=0,\ldots ,T-1\), we denote by \(\mathrm {succ}(\lambda )\) the set of successor nodes of \(\lambda \), that is, nodes \(\mu \in \varLambda _{t+1}\) such that \(\mu \subset \lambda \).
For each \(t=0,\ldots ,T\), we can identify any \(\mathscr {F}_{t}\)-measurable random variable X with a function on \(\varLambda _{t}\), and will write \(X^{\lambda }\) for the value of X at a node \(\lambda \in \varLambda _{t}\).
We shall say that
$$\begin{aligned} Q:=\{Q_{t}^{\lambda }\,|\,t=0,\ldots ,T-1,\lambda \in \varLambda _{t}\} \end{aligned}$$
is a family of absolutely continuous single-step probability measures whenever \(Q_{t}^{\lambda }\) is a probability measure defined on the sigma-field
$$\begin{aligned} \lambda \cap \mathscr {F}_{t+1}:=\left\{ \lambda \cap A\,|\,A\in \mathscr {F} _{t+1}\right\} \end{aligned}$$
for each \(t=0,\ldots ,T-1\) and \(\lambda \in \varLambda _{t}\). Note that absolute continuity of these measures with respect to \(\mathbb {P}\) is automatically ensured by the assumption that \(\mathbb {P}(A)>0\) for each non-empty \(A\in \mathscr {F}_{T}\). Such a family of measures gives rise to a unique probability measure\(~\mathbb {Q}\) defined on the sigma-field\(~\mathscr {F}_{T}\) by
$$\begin{aligned} \mathbb {Q}(\lambda ):=\prod _{t=0}^{T-1}Q_{t}^{\lambda _{t}}(\lambda _{t+1}) \end{aligned}$$
(1)
for any \(\lambda \in \varLambda _{T}\), where \(\lambda _{t}\in \varLambda _{t}\) for \(t=0,\ldots ,T\) is the unique sequence of nodes such that \(\lambda _{0} \supset \cdots \supset \lambda _{T}=\lambda \). In general, the family Q is a richer object than the corresponding measure \(\mathbb {Q}\) in that it carries more information at those nodes \(\lambda \) where \(\mathbb {Q}(\lambda )=0\).
Furthermore, we shall say that an adapted process S is a martingale with respect to the family of measures Q if
$$\begin{aligned} S_{t}^{\lambda }=\sum _{\mu \in \mathrm {succ}(\lambda )}Q_{t}^{\lambda }(\mu )S_{t+1}^{\mu } \end{aligned}$$
(2)
for each \(t=0,\ldots ,T-1\) and \(\lambda \in \varLambda _{t}\). This condition implies that, in particular, S is a martingale (in the usual sense) under the probability measure \(\mathbb {Q}\) related to the family Q by (1). In the case when \(\mathbb {Q}\) is equivalent to the physical probability \(\mathbb {P}\), Eq. (2) is the standard martingale property expressed in terms of the conditional probabilities \(\mathbb {Q}(\mu |\lambda )=Q_{t}^{\lambda }(\mu )\). However, when \(\mathbb {Q}(\lambda )=0\) for some node \(\lambda \) at time t (in which case \(\mathbb {Q}\) is absolutely continuous with respect to \(\mathbb {P}\), but not equivalent to \(\mathbb {P}\)), the conditional probability \(\mathbb {Q} (\mu |\lambda )\) is not well defined. Nonetheless, (2) still applies with \(Q_{t}^{\lambda }(\mu )\) taking over the role of the conditional probability.
Families of absolutely continuous single-step probability measures and martingales with respect to such families of measures will be used to characterise the absence of arbitrage in a market model with combined (fixed and proportional) transaction costs; see Theorem 1.

3 Model with fixed and proportional costs

Let A, B and C be \(\mathbb {R}\)-valued processes adapted to the filtration \(\mathscr {F}\) such that \(0<B\le A<\infty \) and \(0<C<\infty \). We refer to this collection of processes together with the filtration as a combined-cost model, in which AB play the respective roles of ask and bid stock prices, with C representing fixed transaction costs.
The notions of solvency and self-financing can be formalised as follows in the combined-cost model.
Definition 1
(1)
We say that a portfolio \((x,y)\in \mathbb {R}^{2}\) of cash and stock is combined-cost solvent at time \(t=0,\ldots ,T\) and node \(\lambda \in \varLambda _{t}\) when liquidating the stock position leaves a non-negative cash amount
$$\begin{aligned} x+B_{t}^{\lambda }y^{+}-A_{t}^{\lambda }y^{-}-C_{t}^{\lambda }\ge 0 \end{aligned}$$
after the fixed transaction cost \(C_{t}^{\lambda }\) is met, or when both the cash and stock positions are non-negative to begin with, that is,
$$\begin{aligned} x,y\ge 0. \end{aligned}$$
We denote by \(\mathscr {G}_{t}^{\lambda }\) the set of such portfolios (xy).
 
(2)
We define a combined-cost self-financing strategy as an \(\mathbb {R}^{2}\)-valued \(\mathscr {F}\)-predictable process \((X,Y)=\{(X_{t} ,Y_{t})\}_{t=0}^{T+1}\) such that
$$\begin{aligned} (X_{t}^{\lambda }-X_{t+1}^{\lambda },Y_{t}^{\lambda }-Y_{t+1}^{\lambda } )\in \mathscr {G}_{t}^{\lambda } \end{aligned}$$
for each \(t=0,\ldots ,T\) and \(\lambda \in \varLambda _{t}\).
 
Remark 1
We can also consider the combined-cost liquidation value
$$\begin{aligned} L_{t}^{\lambda }(x,y):=x+(B_{t}^{\lambda }y^{+}-A_{t}^{\lambda }y^{-} -C_{t}^{\lambda })\mathbf {1}_{y\notin [0,C_{t}^{\lambda }/B_{t}^{\lambda }]} \end{aligned}$$
of a portfolio \((x,y)\in \mathbb {R}^{2}\) at time \(t=0,\ldots ,T\) and node \(\lambda \in \varLambda _{t}\). Observe that \((x,y)\in \mathscr {G}_{t}^{\lambda }\) is equivalent to \(L_{t}^{\lambda }(x,y)\ge 0\). Figure 1 shows a typical set \(\mathscr {G}_{t}^{\lambda }\) of combined-cost solvent portfolios.

4 Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing under fixed and proportional costs

Definition 2
A combined-cost self-financing strategy (XY) will be referred to as a combined-cost arbitrage opportunity whenever the following conditions hold:
(1)
\((X_{0},Y_{0})=(0,0)\),
 
(2)
\(X_{T+1}\ge 0\) and \(Y_{T+1}\ge 0\),
 
(3)
\(X_{T+1}^{\lambda }>0\) for some \(\lambda \in \varLambda _{T}\).
 
Remark 2
The absence of combined-cost arbitrage can be described in terms of the liquidation value introduced in Remark 1. Namely, there is no combined-cost arbitrage opportunity if and only if \(L_{T}(X_{T} ,Y_{T})=0\) for every combined-cost self-financing strategy (XY) such that \((X_{0},Y_{0})=(0,0)\) and \(L_{T}(X_{T},Y_{T})\ge 0\). This is a direct extension of the classical no-arbitrage (NA) condition studied by Kabanov and Stricker (2001), Schachermayer (2004) and others.
The Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing extends to the case of a combined-cost model as follows.
Theorem 1
The following conditions are equivalent:
(1)
There is no combined-cost arbitrage opportunity in the model with ask and bid prices AB and fixed costs C;
 
(2)
There exist an adapted process S and a family of absolutely continuous single-step probability measures Q such that S is a martingale with respect to the family Q and \(B\le S\le A\).
 
Proof
To prove the implication \((1)\Rightarrow (2)\), assume that there is no combined-cost arbitrage opportunity. We begin by constructing two adapted processes U and V by backward induction:
$$\begin{aligned} U_{T}^{\lambda }:=A_{T}^{\lambda },\quad V_{T}^{\lambda }:=B_{T}^{\lambda } \end{aligned}$$
for each \(\lambda \in \varLambda _{T}\), and
$$\begin{aligned} U_{t-1}^{\lambda }:=\max _{\mu \in \mathrm {succ}(\lambda )}(U_{t}^{\mu }\wedge A_{t}^{\mu }),\quad V_{t-1}^{\lambda }:=\min _{\mu \in \mathrm {succ}(\lambda )}(V_{t}^{\mu }\vee B_{t}^{\mu }) \end{aligned}$$
for each \(t=1,\ldots ,T\) and \(\lambda \in \varLambda _{t-1}\).
Having constructed the processes U and V, we claim that for each \(t=0,\ldots ,T-1\) there exist stopping times \(\sigma ,\tau >t\) such that
$$\begin{aligned} U_{t}\ge A_{\sigma },\quad V_{t}\le B_{\tau }. \end{aligned}$$
We prove the existence of \(\sigma \) by backward induction. For \(\tau \) the argument is similar and will be omitted for brevity. For \(t=T-1\) we get \(U_{T-1}\ge A_{\sigma }\) by putting \(\sigma :=T\). Now suppose that for some \(t=1,\ldots ,T-1\) we have already established that there is a stopping time \(\eta >t\) such that \(U_{t}\ge A_{\eta }\). Let us put
$$\begin{aligned} \sigma :=\eta \mathbf {1}_{\left\{ A_{t}>U_{t}\right\} }+t\mathbf {1}_{\left\{ A_{t}\le U_{t}\right\} }. \end{aligned}$$
It follows that
$$\begin{aligned} U_{t-1}\ge U_{t}\wedge A_{t}=U_{t}\mathbf {1}_{\left\{ A_{t}>U_{t}\right\} }+A_{t}\mathbf {1}_{\left\{ A_{t}\le U_{t}\right\} }\ge A_{\eta } \mathbf {1}_{\left\{ A_{t}>U_{t}\right\} }+A_{t}\mathbf {1}_{\left\{ A_{t}\le U_{t}\right\} }=A_{\sigma }, \end{aligned}$$
completing the proof of the claim.
Next we show that
$$\begin{aligned} V_{t}\vee B_{t}\le U_{t}\wedge A_{t} \end{aligned}$$
(3)
for each \(t=0,\ldots ,T\). Suppose that this were not so, and take the largest \(t=0,\ldots ,T\) such that (3) is violated. Since \(U_{T}=A_{T}\), \(V_{T}=B_{T}\) and \(B_{T}\le A_{T}\), it follows that \(t<T\), and we have \(V_{t+1}\vee B_{t+1}\le U_{t+1}\wedge A_{t+1}\), which implies that \(V_{t}\le U_{t}\). Moreover, we know that \(B_{t}\le A_{t}\). Hence, for (3) to be violated, at least one of the following two inequalities would have to hold at some node \(\lambda \in \varLambda _{t}\):
(a)
\(V_{t}^{\lambda }>A_{t}^{\lambda }\). We know that there is a stopping time \(\tau >t\) such that \(B_{\tau }\ge V_{t}\), so \(B_{\tau }>A_{t}\) on \(\lambda \). In this case the strategy to buy a large enough position in stock for \(A_{t} ^{\lambda }\) at time t and node \(\lambda \), and to sell it for \(B_{\tau }\) at time \(\tau \) for any scenario belonging to \(\lambda \) (and otherwise to do nothing) would be a combined-cost arbitrage opportunity. To be precise, such a strategy (XY) could be defined as
$$\begin{aligned} (X_{s},Y_{s}):=\left\{ \begin{array} [c]{ll} (0,0) &{}\quad \text {for }\quad s=0,\ldots ,t,\\ \mathbf {1}_{\lambda }(-A_{t}z-C_{t},z) &{} \quad \text {for }\quad s=t+1,\ldots ,\tau ,\\ \mathbf {1}_{\lambda }(-A_{t}z+B_{\tau }z-C_{t}-C_{\tau },0) &{} \quad \text {for }\quad s=\tau +1,\ldots ,T+1, \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$
for a large enough number \(z>0\) such that \(\left( -A_{t}+B_{\tau }\right) z>C_{t}+C_{\tau }\) on \(\lambda \). This can be done because, on a finite probability space, the random variables \(-A_{t}+B_{\tau }>0\) and \(C_{t}+C_{\tau }\) take only finitely many values, hence there are constants \(m,M>0\) such that \(-A_{t}+B_{\tau }>m\) and \(C_{t}+C_{\tau }<M\), and we can put \(z:=M/m\).
 
(b)
\(U_{t}^{\lambda }<B_{t}^{\lambda }\). We know that there is a stopping time \(\sigma >t\) such that \(A_{\sigma }\le U_{t}\), so \(A_{\sigma }<B_{t}\) on \(\lambda \). The strategy (XY) defined as
$$\begin{aligned} (X_{s},Y_{s}):=\left\{ \begin{array} [c]{ll} (0,0) &{} \quad \text {for }\quad s=0,\ldots ,t,\\ \mathbf {1}_{\lambda }(B_{t}z-C_{t},-z) &{} \quad \text {for }\quad s=t+1,\ldots ,\sigma ,\\ \mathbf {1}_{\lambda }(B_{t}z-A_{\sigma }z-C_{t}-C_{\sigma },0) &{}\quad \text {for }\quad s=\sigma +1,\ldots ,T+1, \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$
would be a combined-cost arbitrage opportunity when \(z>0\) is large enough so that \(\left( B_{t}-A_{\sigma }\right) z>C_{t}+C_{\sigma }\) on \(\lambda \). Such a number z can be found in a similar manner as in (a).
 
This contradicts the assumption that there is no combined-cost arbitrage opportunity. Claim (3) has therefore been proved.
We are ready to construct a process S and a family of single-step probability measures Q by induction. At time \(t=0\) we take any value
$$\begin{aligned} S_{0}\in [V_{0}\vee B_{0},U_{0}\wedge A_{0}]. \end{aligned}$$
Now suppose that an \(\mathscr {F}_{t}\)-measurable random variable \(S_{t} \in [V_{t}\vee B_{t},U_{t}\wedge A_{t}]\) has already been constructed for some \(t=0,\ldots ,T-1\). For each \(\lambda \in \varLambda _{t}\) we have
$$\begin{aligned} V_{t+1}^{\nu }\vee B_{t+1}^{\nu }= V_{t}^{\lambda }\le S_{t}^{\lambda }\le U_{t}^{\lambda }= U_{t+1}^{\mu }\wedge A_{t+1}^{\mu } \end{aligned}$$
for some \(\mu ,\nu \in \mathrm {succ}(\lambda )\). If \(\mu \ne \nu \), we put
$$\begin{aligned} S_{t+1}^{\mu }:=U_{t+1}^{\mu }\wedge A_{t+1}^{\mu },\quad S_{t+1}^{\nu } :=V_{t+1}^{\nu }\vee B_{t+1}^{\nu } \end{aligned}$$
and, for any \(\eta \in \mathrm {succ}(\lambda )\) other than \(\mu \) or \(\nu \), we take as \(S_{t+1}^{\eta }\) any value
$$\begin{aligned} S_{t+1}^{\eta }\in [V_{t+1}^{\eta }\vee B_{t+1}^{\eta },U_{t+1}^{\eta }\wedge A_{t+1}^{\eta }]. \end{aligned}$$
This means that
$$\begin{aligned} \min _{\mu \in \mathrm {succ}(\lambda )}S_{t+1}^{\mu }\le S_{t}^{\lambda }\le \max _{\mu \in \mathrm {succ}(\lambda )}S_{t+1}^{\mu }, \end{aligned}$$
so there is a probability measure \(Q_{t}^{\lambda }\) on the sigma-field \(\lambda \cap \mathscr {F}_{t+1}\) such that (2) holds. But if \(\mu =\nu \), then we put
$$\begin{aligned} S_{t+1}^{\mu }:=S_{t}^{\lambda } \end{aligned}$$
and, for any \(\eta \in \mathrm {succ}(\lambda )\) other than \(\mu \), we take as \(S_{t+1}^{\eta }\) any value
$$\begin{aligned} S_{t+1}^{\eta }\in [V_{t+1}^{\eta }\vee B_{t+1}^{\eta },U_{t+1}^{\eta }\wedge A_{t+1}^{\eta }]. \end{aligned}$$
Moreover, we put \(Q_{t}^{\lambda }(\mu ):=1\) and \(Q_{t}^{\lambda }(\eta ):=0\) for any \(\eta \in \mathrm {succ}(\lambda )\) other than \(\mu \), which defines a probability measure \(Q_{t}^{\lambda }\) on the sigma-field \(\lambda \cap \mathscr {F}_{t+1}\) such that (2) holds. This construction produces an adapted process S such that \(B\le S\le A\), and a family of absolutely continuous single-step probability measures Q such that S is a martingale with respect to the family Q. The implication \((1)\Rightarrow (2)\) has been proved.
Conversely, to verify that \((2)\Rightarrow (1)\), we assume that condition (2) holds and, to argue by reductio ad absurdum, suppose that there is a combined-cost arbitrage opportunity (XY). Condition (2) implies that
$$\begin{aligned} X_{t}^{\lambda }+S_{t-1}^{\lambda }Y_{t}^{\lambda }\ge \min _{\mu \in \mathrm {succ}(\lambda )}(X_{t}^{\lambda }+S_{t}^{\mu }Y_{t}^{\lambda }) \end{aligned}$$
(4)
for each \(t=1,\ldots ,T\) and \(\lambda \in \varLambda _{t-1}\). Next, since (XY) is a combined-cost self-financing strategy, it follows that, for each \(t=0,\ldots ,T\) and \(\lambda \in \varLambda _{t}\),
$$\begin{aligned}&X_{t}^{\lambda }-X_{t+1}^{\lambda }+S_{t}^{\lambda }(Y_{t}^{\lambda } -Y_{t+1}^{\lambda })\nonumber \\&\quad \quad \quad \ge X_{t}^{\lambda }-X_{t+1}^{\lambda }+B_{t}^{\lambda } (Y_{t}^{\lambda }-Y_{t+1}^{\lambda })^{+}-A_{t}^{\lambda }(Y_{t}^{\lambda }-Y_{t+1}^{\lambda })^{-}\nonumber \\&\quad \quad \quad \ge C_{t}^{\lambda }>0 \end{aligned}$$
(5)
or
$$\begin{aligned} X_{t}^{\lambda }\ge X_{t+1}^{\lambda },\quad Y_{t}^{\lambda }\ge Y_{t+1} ^{\lambda }. \end{aligned}$$
(6)
Hence
$$\begin{aligned} X_{t}+S_{t}Y_{t}\ge X_{t+1}+S_{t}Y_{t+1} \end{aligned}$$
(7)
for each \(t=0,\ldots ,T\). We can show by backward induction that
$$\begin{aligned} X_{t+1}+S_{t}Y_{t+1}\ge 0 \end{aligned}$$
(8)
for each \(t=0,\ldots ,T\). Clearly, (8) holds for \(t=T\), given that \(X_{T+1}\ge 0\) and \(Y_{T+1}\ge 0\). Now suppose that (8) holds for some \(t=1,\ldots ,T\). Take any \(\lambda \in \varLambda _{t-1}\). Then
$$\begin{aligned} X_{t}^{\lambda }+S_{t-1}^{\lambda }Y_{t}^{\lambda }\ge \min _{\mu \in \mathrm {succ}(\lambda )}(X_{t}^{\lambda }+S_{t}^{\mu }Y_{t}^{\lambda })\ge \min _{\mu \in \mathrm {succ}(\lambda )}(X_{t+1}^{\lambda }+S_{t}^{\mu } Y_{t+1}^{\lambda })\ge 0, \end{aligned}$$
where the first inequality holds by (4), the second by (7) and the last one by the induction hypothesis, completing the backward induction argument.
To proceed further, let us put
$$\begin{aligned} t:=\max \{s=0,\ldots ,T+1\,|\,X_{0}\ge \cdots \ge X_{s}\text { and }Y_{0} \ge \cdots \ge Y_{s}\}. \end{aligned}$$
Since (XY) is a combined-cost arbitrage opportunity, we know that \(X_{0}=Y_{0}=0\) and \(X_{T+1}^{\lambda }>0\) for some \(\lambda \in \varLambda _{T}\). If \(t=T+1\), it would mean that \(0=X_{0}\ge X_{T+1}^{\lambda }>0\), a contradiction. On the other hand, if \(t\le T\), then there would be a \(\lambda \in \varLambda _{t}\) such that (6) fails, so (5) would have to hold, implying that
$$\begin{aligned} X_{t}^{\lambda }+S_{t}^{\lambda }Y_{t}^{\lambda }>X_{t+1}^{\lambda } +S_{t}^{\lambda }Y_{t+1}^{\lambda }\ge 0, \end{aligned}$$
where the last inequality follows from (8). However, that too is impossible as \(X_{t}\le X_{0}=0\) and \(Y_{t}\le Y_{0}=0\). This contradiction completes the proof.

5 Fixed costs

A fixed-cost model involves two processes S and C adapted to the filtration \(\mathscr {F}\), where \(0<S<\infty \) represents the stock prices and \(0<C<\infty \) the fixed transaction costs. This is a special case of the combined-cost model when the ask and bid prices coincide. Hence, fixed-cost solvent portfolios, fixed-cost self-financing strategies and fixed-cost arbitrage opportunities are covered by Definitions 1 and 2 with \(A:=B:=S\). In this case Theorem 1 reduces to the following result.
Corollary 1
The following conditions are equivalent:
(1)
There is no fixed-cost arbitrage opportunity in the model with stock prices S and fixed costs C;
 
(2)
There exists a family of absolutely continuous single-step probability measures Q such that S is a martingale with respect to Q.
 
This version of the Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing under fixed costs is similar to that obtained by Jouini et al. (2001). However, our method of proof (the proof of Theorem 1) is different. Moreover, the equivalent condition for the absence of fixed-cost arbitrage is expressed in terms of single-step measures only, whereas that in Jouini et al. (2001) relies on a larger family of measures.
As a consequence of Theorem 1, together with Corollary 1, we also obtain an alternative characterisation of the absence of combined-cost arbitrage in terms of an embedded arbitrage-free fixed-cost model. It resembles earlier results for proportional transaction costs, which involve embedding an arbitrage-free frictionless model; for example, see Roux (2011).
Corollary 2
The following conditions are equivalent:
(1)
There is no combined-cost arbitrage opportunity in the model with ask and bid prices AB and fixed costs C;
 
(2)
There exists a process S adapted to the filtration \(\mathscr {F}\) such that \(B\le S\le A\) and the model with stock prices S and fixed costs C admits no fixed-cost arbitrage opportunity.
 

6 Concluding remarks

In this work the classical Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing due to Harrison and Pliska (1981) is extended to discrete market models with simultaneous fixed and proportional transaction costs and finite state space. This also extends later work on the Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing under proportional costs such as Jouini and Kallal (1995), Kabanov and Stricker (2001), Ortu (2001) and Roux (2011), and under fixed costs as in Jouini et al. (2001).
Developments for models with infinite state space and/or continuous time and/or several assets are likely to follow. Moreover, as the Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing has now been established for markets with simultaneous fixed and proportional costs, it will inform research on pricing and hedging derivative securities in this setting.

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to express their gratitude to the anonymous reviewer, whose constructive comments and suggestions helped to improve the clarity of the paper and to correct some mistakes.

Compliance with ethical standards

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.
Open AccessThis article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Literature
go back to reference Bouchard, B.: No-arbitrage in discrete-time markets with proportional transaction costs and general information structure. Finance Stoch 10, 276–297 (2006)CrossRef Bouchard, B.: No-arbitrage in discrete-time markets with proportional transaction costs and general information structure. Finance Stoch 10, 276–297 (2006)CrossRef
go back to reference Cherny, A.: General arbitrage pricing model: II–transaction costs. Séminaire de Probabilités XL. Lectures Notes in Mathematics, vol. 1899, pp. 447–461. Berlin: Springer (2007) Cherny, A.: General arbitrage pricing model: II–transaction costs. Séminaire de Probabilités XL. Lectures Notes in Mathematics, vol. 1899, pp. 447–461. Berlin: Springer (2007)
go back to reference Dalang, R.C., Morton, A., Willinger, W.: Equivalent martingale measures and no-arbitrage in stochastic securities market models. Stoch Stoch Rep 29, 185–201 (1990)CrossRef Dalang, R.C., Morton, A., Willinger, W.: Equivalent martingale measures and no-arbitrage in stochastic securities market models. Stoch Stoch Rep 29, 185–201 (1990)CrossRef
go back to reference Delbaen, F., Schachermayer, W.: The fundamental theorem of asset pricing for unbounded stochastic processes. Math Ann 312, 215–250 (1994)CrossRef Delbaen, F., Schachermayer, W.: The fundamental theorem of asset pricing for unbounded stochastic processes. Math Ann 312, 215–250 (1994)CrossRef
go back to reference Delbaen, F., Schachermayer, W.: The Mathematics of Arbitrage. Berlin: Springer (2006) Delbaen, F., Schachermayer, W.: The Mathematics of Arbitrage. Berlin: Springer (2006)
go back to reference Denis, E., Kabanov, Y.: Consistent price systems and arbitrage opportunities of the second kind in models with transaction costs. Finance Stoch 16, 135–154 (2012)CrossRef Denis, E., Kabanov, Y.: Consistent price systems and arbitrage opportunities of the second kind in models with transaction costs. Finance Stoch 16, 135–154 (2012)CrossRef
go back to reference Dolinsky, Y., Soner, Y.M.: Robust hedging with proportional transaction costs. Finance Stoch 18, 327–347 (2014)CrossRef Dolinsky, Y., Soner, Y.M.: Robust hedging with proportional transaction costs. Finance Stoch 18, 327–347 (2014)CrossRef
go back to reference Guasoni, P.: No arbitrage under transaction costs, with fractional Brownian motion and beyond. Math Finance 16, 569–582 (2006)CrossRef Guasoni, P.: No arbitrage under transaction costs, with fractional Brownian motion and beyond. Math Finance 16, 569–582 (2006)CrossRef
go back to reference Guasoni, P., Rásonyi, M., Schachermayer, W.: The fundamental theorem of asset pricing for continuous processes under small transaction costs. Ann Finance 6, 157–191 (2010)CrossRef Guasoni, P., Rásonyi, M., Schachermayer, W.: The fundamental theorem of asset pricing for continuous processes under small transaction costs. Ann Finance 6, 157–191 (2010)CrossRef
go back to reference Guasoni, P., Lépinette, E., Rásonyi, M.: The fundamental theorem of asset pricing under transaction costs. Finance Stoch 16, 741–777 (2012)CrossRef Guasoni, P., Lépinette, E., Rásonyi, M.: The fundamental theorem of asset pricing under transaction costs. Finance Stoch 16, 741–777 (2012)CrossRef
go back to reference Grigoriev, P.: On low dimensional case in the fundamental asset pricing theorem under transaction costs. Stat Decis 23, 33–48 (2005) Grigoriev, P.: On low dimensional case in the fundamental asset pricing theorem under transaction costs. Stat Decis 23, 33–48 (2005)
go back to reference Harrison, J.M., Pliska, S.R.: Martingales and stochastic integrals in the theory of continuous trading. Stoch Process Appl 11, 215–260 (1981)CrossRef Harrison, J.M., Pliska, S.R.: Martingales and stochastic integrals in the theory of continuous trading. Stoch Process Appl 11, 215–260 (1981)CrossRef
go back to reference Jouini, E., Kallal, H.: Martingales and arbitrage in securities markets with transaction costs. J Econ Theory 66, 178–197 (1995)CrossRef Jouini, E., Kallal, H.: Martingales and arbitrage in securities markets with transaction costs. J Econ Theory 66, 178–197 (1995)CrossRef
go back to reference Jouini, E., Kallal, H., Napp, C.: Arbitrage and viability in securities markets with fixed trading costs. J Math Econ 35, 197–221 (2001)CrossRef Jouini, E., Kallal, H., Napp, C.: Arbitrage and viability in securities markets with fixed trading costs. J Math Econ 35, 197–221 (2001)CrossRef
go back to reference Kabanov, Y.M.: Hedging and liquidation under transaction costs in currency markets. Finance Stoch 3, 237–248 (1999)CrossRef Kabanov, Y.M.: Hedging and liquidation under transaction costs in currency markets. Finance Stoch 3, 237–248 (1999)CrossRef
go back to reference Kabanov, Y., Safarian, M.: Markets with Transaction Costs: Mathematical Theory. Berlin: Springer (2009) Kabanov, Y., Safarian, M.: Markets with Transaction Costs: Mathematical Theory. Berlin: Springer (2009)
go back to reference Kabanov, Y.M., Stricker, C.: The Harrison–Pliska arbitrage pricing theorem under transaction costs. J Math Econ 35, 185–196 (2001)CrossRef Kabanov, Y.M., Stricker, C.: The Harrison–Pliska arbitrage pricing theorem under transaction costs. J Math Econ 35, 185–196 (2001)CrossRef
go back to reference Kabanov, Y.M., Rásonyi, M., Stricker, C.: No-arbitrage criteria for financial markets with efficient friction. Finance Stoch 6, 371–382 (2002)CrossRef Kabanov, Y.M., Rásonyi, M., Stricker, C.: No-arbitrage criteria for financial markets with efficient friction. Finance Stoch 6, 371–382 (2002)CrossRef
go back to reference Lepinette, E., Tran, T.: General financial market model defined by a liquidation value. Stochastics 88, 437–459 (2016)CrossRef Lepinette, E., Tran, T.: General financial market model defined by a liquidation value. Stochastics 88, 437–459 (2016)CrossRef
go back to reference Lepinette, E., Tran, T.: Arbitrage theory for non convex financial market models. Stoch Process Appl 127, 3331–3353 (2017)CrossRef Lepinette, E., Tran, T.: Arbitrage theory for non convex financial market models. Stoch Process Appl 127, 3331–3353 (2017)CrossRef
go back to reference Ortu, F.: Arbitrage, linear programming and martingales in securities markets with bid-ask spreads. Decis Econ Finance 24, 79–105 (2001)CrossRef Ortu, F.: Arbitrage, linear programming and martingales in securities markets with bid-ask spreads. Decis Econ Finance 24, 79–105 (2001)CrossRef
go back to reference Rola, P.: Arbitrage in markets with bid-ask spreads. The fundamental theorem of asset pricing in finite discrete time markets with bid-ask spreads and a money account. Ann Finance 11, 453–475 (2015)CrossRef Rola, P.: Arbitrage in markets with bid-ask spreads. The fundamental theorem of asset pricing in finite discrete time markets with bid-ask spreads and a money account. Ann Finance 11, 453–475 (2015)CrossRef
go back to reference Roux, A.: The fundamental theorem of asset pricing in the presence of bid-ask and interest rate spreads. J Math Econ 47, 159–163 (2011)CrossRef Roux, A.: The fundamental theorem of asset pricing in the presence of bid-ask and interest rate spreads. J Math Econ 47, 159–163 (2011)CrossRef
go back to reference Schachermayer, W.: The fundamental theorem of asset pricing under proportional transaction costs in finite discrete time. Math Finance 14, 19–48 (2004)CrossRef Schachermayer, W.: The fundamental theorem of asset pricing under proportional transaction costs in finite discrete time. Math Finance 14, 19–48 (2004)CrossRef
go back to reference Zhang, S., Xu, C., Deng, X.: Dynamic arbitrage-free asset pricing with proportional transaction costs. Math Finance 12, 89–97 (2002)CrossRef Zhang, S., Xu, C., Deng, X.: Dynamic arbitrage-free asset pricing with proportional transaction costs. Math Finance 12, 89–97 (2002)CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing under fixed and proportional transaction costs
Authors
Martin Brown
Tomasz Zastawniak
Publication date
26-05-2020
Publisher
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Published in
Annals of Finance / Issue 3/2020
Print ISSN: 1614-2446
Electronic ISSN: 1614-2454
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10436-020-00367-z

Other articles of this Issue 3/2020

Annals of Finance 3/2020 Go to the issue