Skip to main content
Top
Published in: International Tax and Public Finance 2/2023

20-01-2022

Gifts to government

Authors: Joel Slemrod, Yulia Kuchumova

Published in: International Tax and Public Finance | Issue 2/2023

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Gifts to government might provide warm glow to some citizens, especially if they can be earmarked toward specific government activities. We develop a model in which such gifts may be privately worthwhile, even for those people who evade taxes, and describe the conditions under which this will be the case. The latter can occur when the warm glow of transferring money to the government via gifts is higher than the warm glow from transferring the money via paying taxes, and additionally, the marginal rate of substitution of warm glow from “donating” to the public good for private good is sufficiently high. We then conduct empirical analyses of explicit gifts to the US federal government over the last century. Although small compared to either federal taxes and expenditures or donations to charitable organizations, we show that they are systematically, although fairly weakly, related to measures of government fiscal activity. The war years and their immediate aftermath dominate the systematic relationships we uncover. This suggests that these gifts are not simply the random, and randomly timed, behavior of an unrepresentative sample of Americans and that this behavior might warrant further empirical analysis.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
During the French Revolution members of the Assembly appealed to the people to make gifts (dons de patriotisme). MacFarlane (1844) relates that “nearly all the members of the Assembly took their silver and gold buckles from their shoes and offered them up on the altar of the country,” followed by women who “brought their spoons and their forks, wedding-rings and nick-nacks.” Even “the prostitutes of Paris and Versailles...offered a share of their earnings....” MacFarlane says that “The epidemic, like other novelties, raged for a time, and then was over.” Mussolini introduced the “ Gold for the Fatherland” initiative, encouraging the public to voluntarily donate gold jewelry such as necklaces and wedding rings to government in exchange for steel wristbands bearing the words “Gold for the Fatherland.” His wife Rachele is reported to have donated her own wedding ring.
 
2
See Bank et al. (2008) for a magisterial history of US wartime “sacrifice.”
 
3
Kang and Rockoff (2015) discuss the US World War I experience, and Jones (1989) discusses American fiscal propaganda during World War II.
 
4
Polenberg (1972) notes that the sale of war bonds in the USA during World War II illustrated the fine line between voluntarism and compulsion. In 1942, most of President Roosevelt’s advisors favored a compulsory savings plan, but the President decided instead to institute a voluntary plan. Those who wanted a compulsory plan argued that a formal and impartial compulsory plan would in fact be less oppressive than the haphazard and unequal community pressure that would be applied to a “voluntary” program.
 
5
Levi (1997) addresses military service as one way in which democratic governments assert their power to tax, and examines why at some times and in some places there is widespread draft evasion and at other times and places there is considerable patriotism and volunteering. In this context, it is fascinating to note that, during World War I, in the USA a system was devised to make conscription look as much like volunteering—even like voting—as possible. Local civilian volunteers would first register eligible young men in much the same way as persons registered to vote; in fact, registration was even held at each precinct’s voting location (Ellis and Noyes, 1990, p. 190).
 
6
While in what follows we usually refer only to tax evasion, we also have in mind tax avoidance. In this paper, it is the act of underpaying taxes that matters regardless of whether it is done legally or illegally.
 
7
Although in the empirical analysis of this paper we focus on gifts made to the federal government, we recognize that gifts to sub-federal governments are non-trivial, and there are reasons to think they are larger than gifts to the federal government. Brunner and Sonstelie (2003) show that, in the late 1990s, in financially strapped California annual contributions to local schools and school districts regularly exceeded $100 per pupil and, in a handful of cases, $1000 per pupil. It makes sense that, in the context of schools and school districts, a small community with close interactions among families has a group identity that could lead to an informal, collective decision about how much to contribute and might also create a social norm that, for some people, overcomes the incentive to free ride on the contributions of others. We leave for future research the question of whether property tax evaders give gifts to their local governments.
 
8
In this model, E can be evasion or avoidance. What matters is that an individual underreports her income by incurring some cost. This cost could be a cost of evasion or avoidance, or both.
 
9
We use the assumption that there is only one kind of public good in order to focus on the question of the co-existence of gifts and evasion while keeping the analysis simple. This assumption, however, limits our ability to distinguish between unconditional and conditional (targeted) gifts. There is empirical evidence that giving increases when the donor believes she has some say in what the (non-government) gift goes to. It is suggested, for example, by a field experiment involving alumni of an Ivy League university described in Kessler et al. (2019). They find that this group, especially the rich and powerful among them, increase giving by 100–350% when they are given a sense of agency regarding what purpose their gift might be used for. To incorporate this aspect of giving, in Appendix D we extend our model by allowing for two kinds of public goods as well as conditional and unconditional gifts.
 
10
Strictly positive values of x and n can be guaranteed by assuming infinite marginal utility of x at \(x=0\) and of n at \(n=0\).
 
11
In this case, the Lagrange multiplier \(\lambda \) is equal to zero because the constraint \(Dg+E\le y\) cannot be binding. A binding \(Dg+E\le y\) in this case would lead either to a violation of \(x>0\) or of \(n>0\).
 
12
Li et al. (2015) provide support for this assertion. In a real-donation laboratory experiment, they compare giving to the US federal general revenue fund with directed giving to particular government organizations, and find that directed giving more than doubles both the likelihood of giving and the size of contributions.
 
13
Our model ignores some factors that might affect the aggregate amount of gifts to government. One is that people can get warm glow not only from donating (and paying taxes) to government, but also from donating to a variety of private charities, and they choose those that best fit their preferences. Another is that many people do not have complete information on the menu of charities available, or even about the possibility of giving gifts to government. Moreover, people are more likely to give when they are asked: Information dissemination and solicitation play an important role in charitable donation. These aspects could be incorporated by extending our model and adopting the logic introduced in Andreoni and Abigail Payne (2003). Such an extended model would suggest that, if the government wants to stimulate the gifts to government, it should raise the warm glow from gifts to government relative to warm glow from private donations, by for example raising people’s trust in the government or improving the government’s efficiency. Note that, in periods of (popular) wars, the warm glow from gifts to government could be naturally elevated because of rise in the patriotism and pride. Additionally, raising the awareness of the opportunity to donate to the government funds would likely raise the number of gift givers.
 
14
Note that the model does not address the point made by Yitzhaki (1974) that a high tax rate may increase evasion if the cost of (detected) evasion is proportional to the tax evaded, rather than—as here—the income understated.
 
15
The budget constraint can be expressed as \(x^{*}+pn^{*}=\alpha y\), where \(p=\frac{1-Dt}{{\widetilde{a}}-bDt}\) and \(\alpha =1-t+bt\frac{1-Dt}{{\widetilde{a}}-bDt},\) where \({\widetilde{a}}\equiv a(1-Dt)\).
 
16
The collected data are available from the openICPSR, see Slemrod and Kuchumova (2021) for the complete reference to the data.
 
17
Internal Revenue Service (2006).
 
18
In 1947, right after World War II, $12 million in gifts was donated. In 1991, during the Gulf War, $6 million was donated. In 2001, at the start of the Afghanistan war, $27 million was donated.
 
19
Philipps (2005). This is an example of a direct (although lagged) link between tax evasion and gifts to government.
 
20
See, for example, Tyler (2006).
 
21
This is highly negatively correlated with the share of total federal expenditure dedicated to welfare and social insurance spending, and so the estimated coefficients can also be interpreted as (the negative of) the effect of the latter.
 
22
The budget constraint can be expressed as \(x^{*}+pn^{*}t=\alpha y\) where \(p=\frac{1-Dt}{{\widetilde{a}}-bDt}\) and \(\alpha =1-t-bt\frac{1-Dt}{{\widetilde{a}}-bDt}\) and \({\widetilde{a}}\equiv a(1-Dt)\).
 
Literature
go back to reference Andreoni, J. (1990). Impure altruism and donations to public goods: A theory of warm-glow giving. The Economic Journal, 100, 464–477.CrossRef Andreoni, J. (1990). Impure altruism and donations to public goods: A theory of warm-glow giving. The Economic Journal, 100, 464–477.CrossRef
go back to reference Andreoni, J., & Abigail Payne, A. (2003). Do government grants to private charities crowd out giving or fund-raising? American Economic Review, 93(3), 792–812.CrossRef Andreoni, J., & Abigail Payne, A. (2003). Do government grants to private charities crowd out giving or fund-raising? American Economic Review, 93(3), 792–812.CrossRef
go back to reference Associated Press. (1998). “Generous Donations Do Little for Deficit.” April 9. Associated Press. (1998). “Generous Donations Do Little for Deficit.” April 9.
go back to reference Bank, S. A., Stark, K. J., & Thorndike, J. J. (2008). War and taxes: Is there an American tradition of wartime sacrifice? Urban Institute Press. Bank, S. A., Stark, K. J., & Thorndike, J. J. (2008). War and taxes: Is there an American tradition of wartime sacrifice? Urban Institute Press.
go back to reference Brunner, E., & Sonstelie, J. (2003). School finance reform and voluntary fiscal federalism. Journal of Public Economics, 87(9–10), 2157–2185.CrossRef Brunner, E., & Sonstelie, J. (2003). School finance reform and voluntary fiscal federalism. Journal of Public Economics, 87(9–10), 2157–2185.CrossRef
go back to reference Carter, S. B., Gartner, S. S., Haines, M. R., Olmstead, A. L., Sutch, R., & Wright, G. (Eds.). (2006). Historical statistics of the United States. Cambridge University Press. Carter, S. B., Gartner, S. S., Haines, M. R., Olmstead, A. L., Sutch, R., & Wright, G. (Eds.). (2006). Historical statistics of the United States. Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Ellis, S. J., & Noyes, K. H. (1990). By the people: A history of Americans as volunteers. Jossey-Boss. Ellis, S. J., & Noyes, K. H. (1990). By the people: A history of Americans as volunteers. Jossey-Boss.
go back to reference Hungerman, D. M. (2014). Public goods, hidden income, and tax evasion: Some nonstandard results from the warm-glow model. Journal of Development Economics, 109, 188–212.CrossRef Hungerman, D. M. (2014). Public goods, hidden income, and tax evasion: Some nonstandard results from the warm-glow model. Journal of Development Economics, 109, 188–212.CrossRef
go back to reference Internal Revenue Service. (2006). 2005 Data book. Publication 55B. Internal Revenue Service. (2006). 2005 Data book. Publication 55B.
go back to reference Internal Revenue Service. (2019). Tax gap estimates for tax years 2011–2013. Publication 1415 (Rev. 9-2019). Internal Revenue Service. (2019). Tax gap estimates for tax years 2011–2013. Publication 1415 (Rev. 9-2019).
go back to reference Jones, C. (1989). Class tax to mass tax: The role of propaganda in the expansion of the income tax during World War II. Buffalo Law Review, 37, 685–737. Jones, C. (1989). Class tax to mass tax: The role of propaganda in the expansion of the income tax during World War II. Buffalo Law Review, 37, 685–737.
go back to reference Kang, S. W., & Rockoff, H. (2015). Capitalizing patriotism: The liberty loans of World War I. Financial History Review, 22, 45–78.CrossRef Kang, S. W., & Rockoff, H. (2015). Capitalizing patriotism: The liberty loans of World War I. Financial History Review, 22, 45–78.CrossRef
go back to reference Kessler, J. B., Milkman, K. L., & Yiwei Zhang, C. (2019). Getting the rich and powerful to give. Management Science, 65(9), 4049–4062.CrossRef Kessler, J. B., Milkman, K. L., & Yiwei Zhang, C. (2019). Getting the rich and powerful to give. Management Science, 65(9), 4049–4062.CrossRef
go back to reference Lebergott, S. (1957). Annual estimates of unemployment in the United States, 1900–1954. In U.-N. Bureau (Ed.), The measurement and behavior of unemployment. NBER. Lebergott, S. (1957). Annual estimates of unemployment in the United States, 1900–1954. In U.-N. Bureau (Ed.), The measurement and behavior of unemployment. NBER.
go back to reference Levi, M. (1997). Consent, dissent, and patriotism. Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Levi, M. (1997). Consent, dissent, and patriotism. Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Li, S. X., Eckel, C. C., Grossman, P. J., & Brown, T. L. (2011). Giving to government: Voluntary taxation in the lab. Journal of Public Economics, 95, 1190–1201.CrossRef Li, S. X., Eckel, C. C., Grossman, P. J., & Brown, T. L. (2011). Giving to government: Voluntary taxation in the lab. Journal of Public Economics, 95, 1190–1201.CrossRef
go back to reference Li, S. X., Eckel, C. C., Grossman, P. J., & Brown, T. L. (2015). Directed giving enhances voluntary giving to government. Economics Letters, 133, 51–54.CrossRef Li, S. X., Eckel, C. C., Grossman, P. J., & Brown, T. L. (2015). Directed giving enhances voluntary giving to government. Economics Letters, 133, 51–54.CrossRef
go back to reference MacFarlane, C. (1844). The French revolution. Charles Knight and Co. MacFarlane, C. (1844). The French revolution. Charles Knight and Co.
go back to reference Philipps, D. (2005). Would you tip the IRS? The Gazette. Philipps, D. (2005). Would you tip the IRS? The Gazette.
go back to reference Podkul, C. (2011). Showdown encourages citizens to give gifts to reduce debt. The Washington Post. Podkul, C. (2011). Showdown encourages citizens to give gifts to reduce debt. The Washington Post.
go back to reference Polenberg, R. (1972). War and society: The United States, 1941–1945. Greenwood Press. Polenberg, R. (1972). War and society: The United States, 1941–1945. Greenwood Press.
go back to reference Ribar, D. C., & Wilhelm, M. O. (2002). Altruistic and joy-of-giving motivations in charitable behavior. Journal of political Economy, 110(2), 425–457.CrossRef Ribar, D. C., & Wilhelm, M. O. (2002). Altruistic and joy-of-giving motivations in charitable behavior. Journal of political Economy, 110(2), 425–457.CrossRef
go back to reference Ruggles, S., Katie, G., Ronald, G., Josiah, G., & Matthew, S. (2015). Integrated public use microdata series: Version 6.0. University of Minnesota. Ruggles, S., Katie, G., Ronald, G., Josiah, G., & Matthew, S. (2015). Integrated public use microdata series: Version 6.0. University of Minnesota.
go back to reference Slemrod, J. (2019). Tax compliance and enforcement. Journal of Economic Literature, 57, 904–954.CrossRef Slemrod, J. (2019). Tax compliance and enforcement. Journal of Economic Literature, 57, 904–954.CrossRef
go back to reference Slemrod, J., & Weber, C. (2012). Evidence of the invisible: Toward a credibility revolution in the empirical analysis of tax evasion and the informal economy. International Tax and Public Finance, 19(1), 25–53.CrossRef Slemrod, J., & Weber, C. (2012). Evidence of the invisible: Toward a credibility revolution in the empirical analysis of tax evasion and the informal economy. International Tax and Public Finance, 19(1), 25–53.CrossRef
go back to reference Yitzhaki, S. (1974). A note on income tax evasion: A theoretical analysis. Journal of Public Economics, 3(2), 201–202.CrossRef Yitzhaki, S. (1974). A note on income tax evasion: A theoretical analysis. Journal of Public Economics, 3(2), 201–202.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Gifts to government
Authors
Joel Slemrod
Yulia Kuchumova
Publication date
20-01-2022
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
International Tax and Public Finance / Issue 2/2023
Print ISSN: 0927-5940
Electronic ISSN: 1573-6970
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-021-09715-9

Other articles of this Issue 2/2023

International Tax and Public Finance 2/2023 Go to the issue