Skip to main content
Top

2019 | OriginalPaper | Chapter

Intellectual Property and Technology Transfer: Why We Need a New Agenda

Author : Padmashree Gehl Sampath

Published in: Intellectual Property and Development: Understanding the Interfaces

Publisher: Springer Singapore

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This chapter is a tribute to Pedro Roffe who has been a central figure throughout the technology transfer negotiations at the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, and has since then, worked intensely on numerous questions of balance in the global intellectual property rights system. This chapter is as personal as it is scientific to me: it reminds me of fond mutual interactions, professional debates and thought exchanges on technological learning, transfer, development, dissemination and the role of intellectual property rights that I have shared with him. The chapter begins by tracing the technology transfer debate since its inception to analyze its relationship with the protection of intellectual property rights. Tracing the developments from 1948 to the adoption of the Agreement on Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights in 1995, it identifies two distinct approaches—the developmental approach, as put forward by several developing countries in the 1960s and the welfare approach, which positions IPRs as a reward for inventors for the creation of socially useful information. It argues that the failure of the Code, the inception of the TRIPS Agreement and the subsequent ratcheting up of intellectual property norm setting through free trade agreements (FTAs) that provide TRIPS-plus provisions, are all symptoms of a wider malaise: the persistent (and worsening) lack of balance in the global intellectual property system. An analysis of this wider phenomenon, which the chapter terms the “welfare bias” in the current intellectual property rights system, shows that it is spreading beyond the traditional North-South divide to skew the dividends of innovative activities worldwide. The chapter provides empirical evidence to show how patent reforms may cement returns from innovative activity disproportionately in some contexts to argue that there is a need to re-conceptualize and revitalize the technology transfer debate in the context of the sustainable development goals (SDGs).

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Footnotes
1
United Nations document E/Conf.2/78.
 
2
Article 11(1) states thus: “Progressive industrial and general economic development, as well as reconstruction, requires among other things adequate supplies of capital funds, materials, modern equipment and technology and technical and managerial skills. Accordingly, in order to stimulate and assist in the provision and exchange of these facilities: (a) Members shall co-operate, in accordance with Article 10, in providing or arranging for the provision of such facilities within the limits of their power, and Members shall not impose unreasonable or unjustifiable impediments that would prevent other Members from obtaining on equitable terms any such facilities for their economic development or, in the case of Member countries whose economies have been devastated by war, for their reconstruction; (b) No Member shall take unreasonable or unjustifiable action within its territory injurious to the rights or interests of nationals of other Members in the enterprise, skills, capital, arts or technology, which they have supplied.”
 
3
United Nations (1964).
 
4
In economic thought, there has long been a debate on whether a property rights-based approach that acts as an incentive to innovate through the grant of temporary monopoly rights to the inventor (that restricts competition), is better than the elimination of all barriers to free competition in order to promote innovation, see Schumpeter (1942), pp. 84–85.
 
5
WIPO (2009), paras. 41–46.
 
6
See for example, Chang (2002), Amsden and Chu (2003).
 
7
As considered in this paper, the developmental approach to intellectual property is broader but encompasses the human rights considerations espoused in recent analyses of IPRs, which look at how human rights norms and frameworks can be made to bear upon particular issues, such as access to medicines, access to information, etc. See for example, Brennan et al. (2013).
 
8
The review of major policy milestones also reveals that while developed countries explored stronger IPRs protection, a number of developing countries began to experiment with new legal and institutional mechanisms to achieve similar goals. The Andean Group of countries, for example, adopted a common set of policies for the original six countries. These policies were based on the central concept that a common regime was required on foreign direct investment (FDI), industrial property and transfer of technology. The Indian model included guidelines on foreign collaboration agreements to regulate technology transfer transactions. Other countries that enacted similar laws included Argentina, the Dominican Republic, Ghana, Nepal, Nigeria, Mexico, Portugal, Spain, Yugoslavia, and Zambia (see also Patel et al. 2001). See Gehl Sampath and Roffe (2012), Table 1 on pp. 9–11.
 
9
In this period, although developing countries managed to resist revisions to the Paris Convention, the Stockholm Protocol that watered-down copyright protection to address the needs of developing countries began highly untenable and was reversed in 1971 by the Paris revisions to the Berne Convention, in coordination with the Universal Copyright Convention. For an extensive review, see Okediji (2003), p. 187.
 
10
Okediji (2003), p. 318. In the same context, May (2013), p. 17, notes: “When thinking about the incidence of property and property rights there are two issues that need to be explored. First, there is the actual appearance of property as an institution which protects certain interests in society in a specific manner. And second, and by no means less important, there is a parallel history of the ways in which the institution of property has been legitimized and justified within the social relations in which it appears.”
 
11
UNCTAD (1985).
 
12
At the start of the Code negotiations, the original intent of developing countries was to have a binding treaty on the topic. During the course of the negotiations, developing countries eventually accepted that the Code would be a set of guidelines on the topic of technology transfer.
 
13
Reichman (2008), p. 79.
 
14
Article 7 provides that: “The protection and enforcement of intellectual property rights should contribute to the promotion of technological innovation and to the transfer and dissemination of technology, to the mutual advantage of producers and users of technological knowledge and in a manner conducive to social and economic welfare, and to a balance of rights and obligations.” Article 8(1) provides that: “Members may, in formulating or amending their laws and regulations, adopt measures necessary to protect public health and nutrition, and to promote the public interest in sectors of vital importance to their socio-economic and technological development, provided that such measures are consistent with the provisions of this Agreement.”
 
15
Anderson (1998), p. 660.
 
16
Dreyfuss and Frankel (2015), p. 559.
 
17
See discussion in Dreyfuss and Frankl (2015).
 
18
In addition to recourse to the WTO Dispute Settlement Body, the TRIPS Agreement obliges members to provide for extensive domestic enforcement of IPRs.
 
19
See Articles 3 and 4 of the TRIPS Agreement.
 
20
Okediji (2014), p. 209.
 
21
Abbott (1997).
 
22
A few important exceptions abound. Ginarte and Park (1997) and Park (2008) outline an index of patent rights that in conjunction with other variables, offers the possibility to measure the welfare effects of patents in different industries.
 
23
See for example Cottier (2017a), Correa (2000), Matthews and Correa (2011), Abbott (1989).
 
24
See Kur (2014).
 
25
Dreyfuss and Frankl (2015) argue in this context that a predominant interest in the TRIPS Agreement was the possibility for inventors to enforce the same level of protection in all countries in order to ensure that profits remained amongst the original design and equipment manufacturers of global value chains, p. 557.
 
26
Cottier (2017a).
 
27
See Footnote 14.
 
28
See for example Matthews and Correa (2011).
 
29
Gervais (2014).
 
30
See for example, Slade (2011).
 
31
Cottier (2017a), p. 19 notes: “These objectives, however, are locked in by treaty law and language and bound to respect the essence of intellectual property rights.”
 
32
See again, Cottier (2017a).
 
33
In the pharmaceutical sector for example, the grant of spurious patents through national standards that allow local firms to evergreen their patents secures them longer periods of monopoly on the national market and also enables them to fight for similar rights abroad.
 
34
Gehl Sampath and Roffe (2017).
 
35
Sell (2011).
 
36
In contrast with the EU, the US has followed a clear strategy of aligning the regulatory regime of the partner countries in FTAs with those of its own. See Gehl Sampath and Roffe (2017) for a detailed discussion.
 
37
Frankel (2011).
 
38
Cottier (2017b).
 
39
See for example, Watal (2001), Drahos (2002), Cottier (2017b).
 
40
Gehl Sampath (2018). The TPP and US-Korea Free Trade Agreement (KORUS) for example, both have extensive IPRs chapters, in addition to references to IPRs in other chapters such as investment, e-commerce and enforcement, among others.
 
41
See Seuba (2017).
 
42
Seuba (2013, 2017).
 
43
Cottier (2017a), p. 21.
 
44
See Correa (2017). This does not take into account any new changes introduced by the new Comprehensive and Progressive Agreement on the TPP (the CPTPP or the TPP 11) that has been agreed upon by the Member countries of the TPP in November 2017.
 
45
On this point, it is debatable whether all countries—especially developing countries—need the same kind of checks and balances that exist in major trading economies of the world, or whether they need more stringent measures to safeguard their local economic interests.
 
46
Roffe (2014), p. 25.
 
47
Noting the same, Roffe (2014) discusses the case of US-Peru Free Trade Agreement where the said situation was the case and Peru underwent a period of uncertainty and domestic law revisions to meet the standards of its FTA partner.
 
48
See Seuba (2013).
 
49
See Roffe (2014).
 
50
For example, Singapore-Australia, Thailand-New Zealand, the TPP, South-Korea-Singapore are all FTAs that contain regulatory templates on IPRs, enforcement and digital trade. See also Baldwin and Jaimovich (2012) for a general exposition.
 
51
Abbott (1997) notes that the TRIPS Agreement became an agenda point in the WTO when it became clear that the World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO) was unable to shepherd revisions to the Paris and Berne Conventions to accommodate globalization.
 
52
Buckman (2005), p. 94, for instance, quotes an interview with a Chief Executive of Pfizer stating “…[o]ur combined strength allowed us to establish global private sector/ government network to lay the ground for what became TRIPS.”
 
53
Frankel (2011), pp. 39–40 notes: “The fundamental conflict between trade liberalisation and intellectual property barriers lies awkwardly within the TRIPS Agreement framework. The failure of the TRIPS Agreement to deal effectively with parallel importing is a stark example.”
 
54
See for example, Anderson and Gallini (1998).
 
55
Frankel (2011), p. 36.
 
56
See Godt (2008).
 
57
The Economist (2016a).
 
58
See Lemley (2002).
 
59
Kur and Grosse Ruse-Khan (2011), Cottier (2017a).
 
60
Baker (2015).
 
61
Bessen and Meuer (2008) make the point in the context of the US, arguing that IPRs have become subject to regulatory capture by large companies dominating the knowledge-intensive industries, with a view to raising institutional barriers to entry and thus defend or expand their market power.
 
62
See Tirole (2015).
 
63
Bessen (2016) argues that the rising corporate profits are also due to corporate success at political lobbying.
 
64
The Economist (2016b).
 
65
The summary presented here is based on joint work done with Walter Park using US Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) data under arrangements that maintain legal confidentiality requirements. Full details of the empirical work and related analysis are presented in Gehl Sampath and Park (2019) (forthcoming).
 
66
Market concentration, in this context, can be simply denoted as a share of the market held by the top firms in that particular sector.
 
67
Gehl Sampath and Park (2019) (forthcoming). A cross-section of the evidence generated by the analysis has been presented in UNCTAD (2017).
 
68
The analysis uses data from data sources on global companies. Data for US foreign affiliates is taken from the US Bureau of Economic Analysis, which conducts annual and benchmark surveys of US multinational parent companies and their foreign affiliates around the world (BE-10 and BE-11 surveys), as well as annual and benchmark surveys of US affiliates of foreign MNCs (BE-12 and BE-15 surveys). For a guide, see https://​www.​bea.​gov/​surveys/​pdf/​a-guide-to-bea-direct-investment-surveys.​pdf. Accessed December 10, 2017. The second is Thomson Reuters Eikon and Datastream, which provide data on private and public companies, with headquarters around the world.
 
69
For market concentration trends in these sectors, see Bouhia (2018) (forthcoming). For a discussion on the reliance of patents in these sectors, see Ivus et al. (2016).
 
70
Sectors are identified by four-digit NAICS codes (2002 version). ICT includes semiconductors, electronics, hardware and software. Given the relatively small number of US pharmaceutical companies’ affiliates in the developing world, we pool the pharmaceutical firms with the non-pharmaceutical chemical firms.
 
71
Park (2008). The Patent index is the unweighted sum of five separate scores for: coverage (inventions that are patentable); membership in international treaties; duration of protection; enforcement mechanisms; and restrictions (for example, compulsory licensing in the event that a patented invention is not sufficiently exploited).
 
72
See footnote 67. Although ideally, profitability data for US MNC foreign affiliates in Brazil, India and China would have been better for this analysis, given its unavailability, sales per worker thus provide a second-best approximation of profitability performance.
 
73
These results could not be discussed here at length. See Gehl Sampath and Park (2019) (forthcoming) for full details of the econometric model, estimation and results.
 
74
For the entire empirical analysis, see Gehl Sampath and Park (2019) (forthcoming).
 
75
India has been highly cautious about IPRs protection beyond what is contained in the TRIPS Agreement, whereas China’s patent system has several specificities, including that utility models are widely used in China, which are more easily registered than invention patents that take anywhere between 3 and 5 years to register on an average. China also does not recognize designs unless they are registered as design patents in which case a protection of 10 years is granted (as opposed to 25 years in the EU).
 
76
See Council of Economic Advisors (2016).
 
77
See WIPO (2017), Thun and Sturgeon (2017).
 
78
See De Vries et al. (2017) who find, in a study of 4703 start-ups in the US, that in heavily concentrated industries characterized by higher barriers to entry and greater technological investments, start-ups rely on patents as their initial IP strategy, whereas in other sectors where this is not the case, they begin by filing trademarks.
 
79
The 3D printing industry, for instance, is rather concentrated with a handful of firms, where 3D Systems Corp (NYSE: DDD) and Exone (NASDAQ: Xone) are in the lead, as is the case of robotics where most of the companies are situated in the industrial economies (see Gehl Sampath (2018)). For an account of how concentrated the robotics market is, see Keisner et al. (2016).
 
80
A good example is the increasing emphasis on e-commerce in FTAs, and the important role played by IPRs in the development of the e-commerce industry. New e-commerce applications, such as the Internet of Things require multiple layers of technologies to interact for the creation of applications where many patents coexist potentially and there may be a number of other IPRs at play as well.
 
81
In contrast, the Agenda does not mention IPRs except in the context of access to medicines and the Doha Declaration on Public Health.
 
Literature
go back to reference Abbott, F. M. (1989). Protecting first world assets in the third world: Intellectual property negotiations in the GATT multilateral framework. Vanderbilt Journal of Transnational Law, 22(4), 689–745. Abbott, F. M. (1989). Protecting first world assets in the third world: Intellectual property negotiations in the GATT multilateral framework. Vanderbilt Journal of Transnational Law, 22(4), 689–745.
go back to reference Abbott, F. M. (1997). WTO dispute settlement and the agreement on trade related aspects of intellectual property. In E.-U. Petersmann (Ed.), International trade law and the GATT/WTO dispute settlement system (pp. 415–437). London: Kluwer Law International. Abbott, F. M. (1997). WTO dispute settlement and the agreement on trade related aspects of intellectual property. In E.-U. Petersmann (Ed.), International trade law and the GATT/WTO dispute settlement system (pp. 415–437). London: Kluwer Law International.
go back to reference Amsden, A. H., & Chu, W. (2003). Beyond late development: Taiwan’s upgrading policies. Cambridge, Massachusetts: The MIT Press.CrossRef Amsden, A. H., & Chu, W. (2003). Beyond late development: Taiwan’s upgrading policies. Cambridge, Massachusetts: The MIT Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Anderson, R. D. (1998). The interface between competition policy and intellectual property in the context of the international trading system. Journal of International Economic Law, 1(4), 655–678.CrossRef Anderson, R. D. (1998). The interface between competition policy and intellectual property in the context of the international trading system. Journal of International Economic Law, 1(4), 655–678.CrossRef
go back to reference Anderson, R. D., & Gallini, N. T. (Eds.). (1998). Competition policy and intellectual property rights in the knowledge-based economy. Calgary: University of Calgary Press. Anderson, R. D., & Gallini, N. T. (Eds.). (1998). Competition policy and intellectual property rights in the knowledge-based economy. Calgary: University of Calgary Press.
go back to reference Baker, D. (2015). The upward redistribution of income: Are rents the story? Working Paper. Washington DC: Centre for Economic and Policy Research. Baker, D. (2015). The upward redistribution of income: Are rents the story? Working Paper. Washington DC: Centre for Economic and Policy Research.
go back to reference Baldwin, R., & Jaimovich, D. (2012). Are free trade agreements contagious? Journal of International Economics, 88, 1–16.CrossRef Baldwin, R., & Jaimovich, D. (2012). Are free trade agreements contagious? Journal of International Economics, 88, 1–16.CrossRef
go back to reference Bessen, J. (2016). Accounting for rising corporate profits: Intangibles or regulatory rents? Boston University School of Law, Law and Economics Working Paper No. 16-18. Bessen, J. (2016). Accounting for rising corporate profits: Intangibles or regulatory rents? Boston University School of Law, Law and Economics Working Paper No. 16-18.
go back to reference Bessen, J., & Meurer, M. J. (2008). Patent failure: How judges, bureaucrats and lawyers put innovators at risk. Princeton University Press. Bessen, J., & Meurer, M. J. (2008). Patent failure: How judges, bureaucrats and lawyers put innovators at risk. Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Buckman, G. (2005). Global trade: Past mistakes, future choices. Fernwell Publishing Limited. Buckman, G. (2005). Global trade: Past mistakes, future choices. Fernwell Publishing Limited.
go back to reference Chang, H. J. (2002). Kicking away the ladder: Development strategy in historical perspective. London: Anthem Press. Chang, H. J. (2002). Kicking away the ladder: Development strategy in historical perspective. London: Anthem Press.
go back to reference Correa, C. M. (2000). Intellectual property rights, the WTO and developing countries: The TRIPS Agreement and policy options. London/New York: Zed Books. Correa, C. M. (2000). Intellectual property rights, the WTO and developing countries: The TRIPS Agreement and policy options. London/New York: Zed Books.
go back to reference Correa, C. M. (2017). Intellectual property in the trans-pacific partnership: Increasing the barriers for the access to affordable medicines. South Centre Research Paper. Correa, C. M. (2017). Intellectual property in the trans-pacific partnership: Increasing the barriers for the access to affordable medicines. South Centre Research Paper.
go back to reference Cottier, T. (2017a). Embedding intellectual property in international law. In P. Roffe & X. Seuba (Eds.), Current alliances in international intellectual property law making: The emergence and impact of mega-regionals (pp. 15–44). Geneva: A CEIPI-ICTSD Publication Series. Cottier, T. (2017a). Embedding intellectual property in international law. In P. Roffe & X. Seuba (Eds.), Current alliances in international intellectual property law making: The emergence and impact of mega-regionals (pp. 15–44). Geneva: A CEIPI-ICTSD Publication Series.
go back to reference Cottier, T. (2017b). Intellectual property and mega-regional trade agreements: Progress and opportunities missed. In S. Griller, W. Obwexer, & E. Vranes (Eds.), Mega-regional agreements CETA, TTIP and TiSA: New orientations for EU external economic relations. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Cottier, T. (2017b). Intellectual property and mega-regional trade agreements: Progress and opportunities missed. In S. Griller, W. Obwexer, & E. Vranes (Eds.), Mega-regional agreements CETA, TTIP and TiSA: New orientations for EU external economic relations. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference De Vries, G., Pennings, E., Block, J. H., & Fisch, C. (2017). Trademark or patent? The effects of market concentration, customer type and venture capital financing on start-ups initial IP applications. Industry and Innovation, 24(4), 325–345.CrossRef De Vries, G., Pennings, E., Block, J. H., & Fisch, C. (2017). Trademark or patent? The effects of market concentration, customer type and venture capital financing on start-ups initial IP applications. Industry and Innovation, 24(4), 325–345.CrossRef
go back to reference Drahos, P. (2002). Developing countries and international intellectual property standard-setting. The Journal of World Intellectual Property, 5(5), 765–789.CrossRef Drahos, P. (2002). Developing countries and international intellectual property standard-setting. The Journal of World Intellectual Property, 5(5), 765–789.CrossRef
go back to reference Dreyfuss, R., & Frankel, S. (2015). From incentive to commodity to asset: How international law is reconceptualising intellectual property. Michigan Journal of International Law, 36(4), 557–602. Dreyfuss, R., & Frankel, S. (2015). From incentive to commodity to asset: How international law is reconceptualising intellectual property. Michigan Journal of International Law, 36(4), 557–602.
go back to reference Frankel, S. (2011). Some consequences of misinterpreting the TRIPS Agreement. Victoria University of Wellington Legal Research Papers, Paper No. 37. Frankel, S. (2011). Some consequences of misinterpreting the TRIPS Agreement. Victoria University of Wellington Legal Research Papers, Paper No. 37.
go back to reference Gehl Sampath, P. (2018). Regulating the digital economy: Are we heading for a win-win or a lose-lose? UNU-MERIT Working Paper Series No. 5. Gehl Sampath, P. (2018). Regulating the digital economy: Are we heading for a win-win or a lose-lose? UNU-MERIT Working Paper Series No. 5.
go back to reference Gehl Sampath, P., & Park, W. G. (2019). Patents and market concentration: Evidence and policy implications (forthcoming). Gehl Sampath, P., & Park, W. G. (2019). Patents and market concentration: Evidence and policy implications (forthcoming).
go back to reference Gehl Sampath, P., & Roffe, P. (2012). Unpacking the international intellectual property debate: Fifty years and beyond. Working Paper. Geneva: ICTSD. Gehl Sampath, P., & Roffe, P. (2012). Unpacking the international intellectual property debate: Fifty years and beyond. Working Paper. Geneva: ICTSD.
go back to reference Gehl Sampath, P., & Roffe, P. (2017). The transpacific partnership agreement: A stroke of genius or a tragedy of sorts. In P. Roffe & X. Seuba (Eds.), Current alliances in international intellectual property law making: The emergence and impact of mega-regionals (pp. 109–133). Geneva: A CEIPI-ICTSD Publication Series. Gehl Sampath, P., & Roffe, P. (2017). The transpacific partnership agreement: A stroke of genius or a tragedy of sorts. In P. Roffe & X. Seuba (Eds.), Current alliances in international intellectual property law making: The emergence and impact of mega-regionals (pp. 109–133). Geneva: A CEIPI-ICTSD Publication Series.
go back to reference Gervais, D. (2014). Current issues in international intellectual property norm-making. In J. Drexl, H. Grosse Ruse-Khan, & S. Nadde-Phlix (Eds.), EU bilateral trade agreements and intellectual property: For better or worse? (pp. 3–16). Berlin: Springer. Gervais, D. (2014). Current issues in international intellectual property norm-making. In J. Drexl, H. Grosse Ruse-Khan, & S. Nadde-Phlix (Eds.), EU bilateral trade agreements and intellectual property: For better or worse? (pp. 3–16). Berlin: Springer.
go back to reference Ginarte, J. C., & Park, W. G. (1997). Intellectual property rights and economic growth. Contemporary Economic Policy, 15(3), 51–61.CrossRef Ginarte, J. C., & Park, W. G. (1997). Intellectual property rights and economic growth. Contemporary Economic Policy, 15(3), 51–61.CrossRef
go back to reference Godt, C. (2008). The role of patents in scientific competition: A closer look at the phenomenon of royalty stacking. In M. Albert, D. Schmidtchen, & S. Voigt (Eds.), Conferences on new political economy: Scientific competition (pp. 151–171). Tubingen: Mohr Siebeck. Godt, C. (2008). The role of patents in scientific competition: A closer look at the phenomenon of royalty stacking. In M. Albert, D. Schmidtchen, & S. Voigt (Eds.), Conferences on new political economy: Scientific competition (pp. 151–171). Tubingen: Mohr Siebeck.
go back to reference Keisner, A., Raffo, J., & Wunsch-Vincent, S. (2016). Robotics: Breakthrough technologies, innovation, intellectual property. Foresight and STI Governance, 10(2), 7–27.CrossRef Keisner, A., Raffo, J., & Wunsch-Vincent, S. (2016). Robotics: Breakthrough technologies, innovation, intellectual property. Foresight and STI Governance, 10(2), 7–27.CrossRef
go back to reference Kur, A., & Grosse Ruse-Khan, H. (2011). Enough is enough—The notion of binding ceilings in international intellectual property protection. In A. Kur & M. Levin (Eds.), Intellectual property rights in a fair world trade system: Proposals for reform of TRIPS (pp. 359–407). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRef Kur, A., & Grosse Ruse-Khan, H. (2011). Enough is enough—The notion of binding ceilings in international intellectual property protection. In A. Kur & M. Levin (Eds.), Intellectual property rights in a fair world trade system: Proposals for reform of TRIPS (pp. 359–407). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRef
go back to reference Lemley, M. A. (2002). Intellectual property rights and standard setting organisations. California Law Review, 90(6), 1889–1980.CrossRef Lemley, M. A. (2002). Intellectual property rights and standard setting organisations. California Law Review, 90(6), 1889–1980.CrossRef
go back to reference Matthews, D., & Correa, C. M. (2011). The Doha declaration ten years on and its impact on access to medicines and the right to health. Discussion Paper. UNDP. Matthews, D., & Correa, C. M. (2011). The Doha declaration ten years on and its impact on access to medicines and the right to health. Discussion Paper. UNDP.
go back to reference May, C. (2013). The global political economy of intellectual property rights: The new enclosures. London/New York: Routledge.CrossRef May, C. (2013). The global political economy of intellectual property rights: The new enclosures. London/New York: Routledge.CrossRef
go back to reference Okediji, R. (2003). The international relations of intellectual property: Narratives of developing country participation in the global intellectual property system. Singapore Journal of International and Comparative Law, 7, 315–385. Okediji, R. (2003). The international relations of intellectual property: Narratives of developing country participation in the global intellectual property system. Singapore Journal of International and Comparative Law, 7, 315–385.
go back to reference Okediji, R. (2014). Legal innovation in international intellectual property relations: Revisiting twenty-one years of the TRIPS agreement. University of Pennsylvania Journal of International Economic Law, 36(1), 191–268. Okediji, R. (2014). Legal innovation in international intellectual property relations: Revisiting twenty-one years of the TRIPS agreement. University of Pennsylvania Journal of International Economic Law, 36(1), 191–268.
go back to reference Park, W. G. (2008). International patent protection: 1960–2005. Research Policy, 37, 761–766.CrossRef Park, W. G. (2008). International patent protection: 1960–2005. Research Policy, 37, 761–766.CrossRef
go back to reference Patel, S. J., Roffe, P., & Yusuf, A. (Eds.). (2001). International technology transfer: The origins and aftermath of the United Nations negotiations on a draft code of conduct. The Hague: Kluwer Law International. Patel, S. J., Roffe, P., & Yusuf, A. (Eds.). (2001). International technology transfer: The origins and aftermath of the United Nations negotiations on a draft code of conduct. The Hague: Kluwer Law International.
go back to reference Reichman, J. H. (2008). Universal minimum standards of intellectual property protection under the TRIPS component of the WTO Agreement. In C. M. Correa & A. Abdulqawi (Eds.), Intellectual property and international trade: The TRIPS Agreement (pp. 23–82). The Netherlands: Kluwer Law International. Reichman, J. H. (2008). Universal minimum standards of intellectual property protection under the TRIPS component of the WTO Agreement. In C. M. Correa & A. Abdulqawi (Eds.), Intellectual property and international trade: The TRIPS Agreement (pp. 23–82). The Netherlands: Kluwer Law International.
go back to reference Roffe, P. (2014). Intellectual property chapters in free trade agreements: Their significance and systemic implications. In J. Drexl, H. Grosse Ruse-Khan, & S. Nadde-Phlix (Eds.), EU bilateral trade agreements and intellectual property: For better or worse? (pp. 17–40). Berlin: Springer.CrossRef Roffe, P. (2014). Intellectual property chapters in free trade agreements: Their significance and systemic implications. In J. Drexl, H. Grosse Ruse-Khan, & S. Nadde-Phlix (Eds.), EU bilateral trade agreements and intellectual property: For better or worse? (pp. 17–40). Berlin: Springer.CrossRef
go back to reference Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). Capitalism, socialism and democracy. New York: Harper Torch Books. Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). Capitalism, socialism and democracy. New York: Harper Torch Books.
go back to reference Sell, S. K. (2011). TRIPS was never enough: Vertical forum shifting, FTAs, ACTA and TPP. Journal of Intellectual Property Law, 18(2), 447–478. Sell, S. K. (2011). TRIPS was never enough: Vertical forum shifting, FTAs, ACTA and TPP. Journal of Intellectual Property Law, 18(2), 447–478.
go back to reference Seuba, X. (2013). Intellectual property in preferential trade agreements: What treaties, what content? The Journal of World Intellectual Property, 16(5–6), 240–261.CrossRef Seuba, X. (2013). Intellectual property in preferential trade agreements: What treaties, what content? The Journal of World Intellectual Property, 16(5–6), 240–261.CrossRef
go back to reference Seuba, X. (2017). The global regime for the enforcement of intellectual property rights. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Seuba, X. (2017). The global regime for the enforcement of intellectual property rights. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Slade, A. (2011). Articles 7 and 8 of the TRIPS agreement: A force for convergence within the international IP system. The Journal of World Intellectual Property, 14(6), 413–440. Slade, A. (2011). Articles 7 and 8 of the TRIPS agreement: A force for convergence within the international IP system. The Journal of World Intellectual Property, 14(6), 413–440.
go back to reference The Economist. (2016a). The problem with profits. Leaders, March 26. The Economist. (2016a). The problem with profits. Leaders, March 26.
go back to reference The Economist. (2016b). Too much of a good thing. Briefing, March 26. The Economist. (2016b). Too much of a good thing. Briefing, March 26.
go back to reference Thun, E., & Sturgeon, T. (2017). When global technology meets local standards. MIT Industrial Performance Center Working Paper Series. Thun, E., & Sturgeon, T. (2017). When global technology meets local standards. MIT Industrial Performance Center Working Paper Series.
go back to reference Tirole, J. (2015). Market failure and public policy. American Economic Review, 105(6), 1665–1682.CrossRef Tirole, J. (2015). Market failure and public policy. American Economic Review, 105(6), 1665–1682.CrossRef
go back to reference Watal, J. (2001). Intellectual property rights in the WTO and developing countries. The Netherlands: Kluwer Law International. Watal, J. (2001). Intellectual property rights in the WTO and developing countries. The Netherlands: Kluwer Law International.
go back to reference WIPO. (2009). Report on the international patent system. SCP/12/3. Geneva: WIPO. WIPO. (2009). Report on the international patent system. SCP/12/3. Geneva: WIPO.
go back to reference WIPO. (2017). Intangible capital in global value chains. The World Intellectual Property Report. Geneva: WIPO. WIPO. (2017). Intangible capital in global value chains. The World Intellectual Property Report. Geneva: WIPO.
go back to reference United Nations. (1964). The role of patents in the transfer of technology to developing countries. Report of the Secretary General. New York: United Nations. United Nations. (1964). The role of patents in the transfer of technology to developing countries. Report of the Secretary General. New York: United Nations.
go back to reference UNCTAD. (1985). Draft international Code of Conduct on the transfer of technology, as at the close of the sixth session of Conference on 5 June 1985. United Nations document, No.TD/CODE TOT/47. Geneva: United Nations. UNCTAD. (1985). Draft international Code of Conduct on the transfer of technology, as at the close of the sixth session of Conference on 5 June 1985. United Nations document, No.TD/CODE TOT/47. Geneva: United Nations.
go back to reference UNCTAD. (2017). Beyond austerity: Toward a new global deal. Trade and Development Report. Geneva: United Nations. UNCTAD. (2017). Beyond austerity: Toward a new global deal. Trade and Development Report. Geneva: United Nations.
Metadata
Title
Intellectual Property and Technology Transfer: Why We Need a New Agenda
Author
Padmashree Gehl Sampath
Copyright Year
2019
Publisher
Springer Singapore
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-13-2856-5_3