Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Studies in Comparative International Development 2/2019

Open Access 01-05-2019

Leninism and Local Interests: How Cities in China Benefit from Concurrent Leadership Appointments

Authors: David J. Bulman, Kyle A. Jaros

Published in: Studies in Comparative International Development | Issue 2/2019

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

The practice in Leninist political systems of assigning local leaders concurrent seats on higher-level leadership bodies presents a puzzle. In China, for example, a subset of provincial leaders hold seats in the central Politburo, while some city-level leaders hold seats in provincial party standing committees (PPSCs). While some scholars view these concurrent appointments as a form of top-down control or co-optation, others see these arrangements as a reflection of local power and a channel for the assertion of local interests. In this paper, we attempt to adjudicate between these different views empirically by analyzing the patterns and consequences of concurrent appointments of city leaders to China’s PPSCs. We introduce a new typology that distinguishes between the political and economic functions of concurrent appointments to differentiate four possible intergovernmental dynamics of control, co-optation, compromise, and concession. Through analysis of an original dataset on PPSC appointments and case studies of three Chinese cities, we show that concurrent appointments in China’s provinces can function as a means of concession, compromise, or co-optation, but we find little evidence that concurrent appointments allow higher-level authorities to firmly control or economically exploit localities.
Notes

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Introduction

Leninist political systems exemplify hierarchy. The Chinese party-state, for example, is built around a ladder of ascending authority, with party leadership bodies at each level of government that oversee subordinates and control the careers of lower-ranking officials (Landry 2008). Central and provincial leaders can impose dictates on the localities under them at will. The system may tolerate decentralization of administrative authority and “experimentation under hierarchy” (Zheng 2007; Heilmann 2008). But when all is said and done, firm political centralism ensures that it is higher-level decisions that count.
Notwithstanding this hierarchical template, however, Leninist authority structures are not always as clear-cut or rigid as they seem. One example is China’s practice of assigning the leaders of certain localities seats in higher-level party leadership bodies. At any given time, several of China’s provincial-level units enjoy representation on the central Politburo, the elite body of roughly two dozen party heavyweights that oversees key political and policy decisions.1 At the subnational level, provincial party standing committees (PPSCs), the 12–13 member leadership bodies that run China’s regions, routinely allot 1, 2, or even 3 seats to the party chiefs of cities. The presence of lower-level leaders on party leadership bodies often involves a gaopei (“high match”) arrangement, whereby local leaders enjoy a higher party-political rank than they would have based on their local position.
These concurrent leadership appointments—and the tangled political hierarchies they create—are not unique to China. It also has been typical for certain local leaders to hold concurrent higher-level leadership positions in systems like the contemporary Socialist Republic of Vietnam and the historical USSR (Sheng 2009). The USSR Politburo, for instance, often included leaders of key cities and republics. As of 1984, the Politburo of the 26th Party Congress included leaders from Moscow, Leningrad, Kazakhstan, Ukraine, and Georgia (Lane 1985, pp. 166–168). In Vietnam, meanwhile, certain provincial party secretaries, particularly those from Ha Noi and Ho Chi Minh City, concurrently hold appointments in the central party-state (Malesky 2008).
Comparative scholarship on intergovernmental relations, much of which focuses on democratic settings, typically views the presence of local actors in higher-level political bodies as serving the interests of localities rather than higher-level authorities. When subnational units are represented in higher-level decision-making bodies, the thinking goes, they can assert their own political or economic interests. Tarrow (1978), Hutchcroft (2001), Falleti (2005), and Hooghe and Marks (2013), among others, view mechanisms of local representation such as the inclusion of territorial delegates in national legislatures or the participation of subnational actors in national-level bureaucratic processes as institutional factors that empower localities and enable local units to “utilize the center to their advantage” (Tarrow 1978, pp. 20–21). Empirical work from the USA and other democracies shows that localities whose representatives hold key positions in higher-level political bodies derive major benefits from such access (Carsey and Rundquist 1999; Berry and Fowler 2016).
In Leninist systems, however, the very notion that parochial interests are—or should be—represented in top leadership bodies is more suspect. With political power flowing from the top downward and formal accountability flowing upward, mechanisms that integrate local leaders into higher-level decision-making bodies may play very different roles. China scholars like Huang (1996) and Sheng (2009) see concurrent appointments as fully compatible with—indeed a natural outgrowth of—political hierarchy. Sheng (2009) argues that the presence of local leaders on higher-level bodies is a mode of political control over potentially problematic areas. By keeping local leaders close at hand, the thinking goes, higher-level leaders can keep localist ambitions at bay and ensure compliance with central policies. However, other China scholars, like Lam (2010) and Li (2016), see more ambiguity in the meaning of concurrent appointments. Rather than being a mode of top-down control, concurrent appointments might instead function as a softer form of co-optation, whereby higher-level authorities offer lower-level units expanded resources and political voice in exchange for their support of higher-level priorities, or even as a concession to powerful local actors. Seen this way, concurrent appointments could enable the representation of local interests in higher-level decision-making processes, and could reflect the strength rather than the weakness of local interests.
Different views of how and in whose interest concurrent leadership appointments work cut to fundamental questions about the political economy of Leninist systems. How these arrangements operate in practice has important implications for the way scholars conceptualize political control and interest representation in such polities. Can higher-level authorities subdue interest conflicts and ameliorate central-local conflicts by keeping key local leaders under closer watch? Is there institutional space even at high levels of Leninist party-states for local interests to assert themselves and promote parochial interests? Or perhaps concurrent appointments reflect a shifting intergovernmental bargain, whereby material benefits and “speaking rights” (fayan quan) are traded for political compliance?
After explaining why these questions are difficult to resolve at the theoretical level, this paper analyzes the patterns and outcomes of concurrent appointments empirically. We explore the determinants and outcomes of city leaders’ appointments to provincial leadership bodies, exploiting variation across provinces and over time in concurrent appointments. To guide our analysis, we develop a new typology that disentangles the political and economic dimensions of intergovernmental relations, distinguishing between policy autonomy and distributive outcomes. Drawing on city-level data and a dataset of the membership of PPSCs between 1996 and 2013 as well three city-level case studies, we assess how well concurrent appointment dynamics match the expectations associated with distinct logics of control, co-optation, compromise, and concession. We first analyze which types of cities enjoy PPSC representation and then explore how concurrent appointments affect subnational development and governance dynamics.
Our analysis challenges the idea that concurrent appointments serve simply to reinforce top-down control. Instead, we find that concurrent leadership appointments tend to bring either economic benefits or greater governance autonomy—or both—to the localities concerned. At the same time, our analysis suggests that the presence of city leaders on provincial leadership bodies has different consequences in different cases, and that the function of concurrent appointments differs across cities based on city characteristics. Overall, our findings suggest that China’s political hierarchy allows considerable flexibility, both in the determination of which cities’ leaders get selected for concurrent appointments and in the function of such representation. Even powerful Leninist regimes allow space for local interests to assert themselves in high-level politics and policymaking.

Local Actors in China’s Party Leadership Bodies

Past scholarship offers markedly different interpretations of the political function of concurrent leadership appointments in China. Scholars such as Huang (1996) and Sheng (2009, 2010) contend that concurrent appointment of local leaders to higher-level party leadership bodies enhances top-down control over localities rather than enabling bottom-up interest articulation. When it comes to provincial leaders in China’s Politburo, for example, Sheng (2009) argues that top-down appointment decisions reinforce upward political accountability, create “better alignment of the incentive structure” between local and national leaders, and improve the center’s capacity to monitor subordinates. Political leverage over local leaders helps ensure that localities comply with higher-level directives even when doing so may harm local interests. Huang’s (1996) study of the center’s crackdown on investment in China’s provinces finds that “concurrent centralists”—provincial leaders with Politburo seats—are more responsive to the center’s wishes and willing to impose costs on their jurisdictions. Huang and Sheng (2009) show that concurrent centralists achieve lower provincial inflation rates, which they interpret to mean that concurrent appointments make provinces more compliant with central austerity policies.
Yet, other scholars question whether concurrent appointments strengthen top-down control, noting that such arrangements may increase local actors’ influence over higher-level decisions. Discussing the appointment of certain provincial leaders to the central Politburo, Lam (2010) observes that “the meaning of provincial representation on these central institutions is far from immediately clear,” potentially signaling either “provincial clout” or “national integration.” Indeed, scholars such as Wang and Minzner (2015), Shi (2017), and Ma (2017) view concurrent appointments of the leaders of certain cities or bureaucratic units to provincial leadership bodies as a form of empowerment. As Shi (2017) notes, local leaders who are appointed to higher-level party standing committees “possess greater authority and power than other local officials at the same level in the administrative hierarchy, and are able to obtain favorable policies and policy support for their regions” (p. 83). Empirically, too, close political ties between lower and higher levels, and the representation of localities on higher-level leadership bodies, have been found to advance local interests. Li (1997) notes how Shanghai’s tight political relationship with Beijing cut both ways: while the municipality faced central policy demands and pressure to turn over fiscal revenues, it was also able to assert its interests in central decisions and capture economic resources and policy benefits. Ma (2017) finds that cities holding seats on PPSCs garner more mentions in provincial development plans and are privileged in the building of rail infrastructure. Bulman (2016) shows that counties with party secretaries who sit on prefectural party standing committees achieve faster growth than other counties.
Ultimately, the expected effects of concurrent appointments depend on our assumptions about decision-making processes and politicians’ incentives. Different models of China’s intergovernmental politics—a top-down principal-agent model and a bargaining model—yield contrasting expectations. Under the assumptions of a principal-agent model, concurrent appointments should strengthen top-down control. China’s nomenklatura system is meant to keep local leaders politically accountable to their superiors even as localities exercise a degree of administrative autonomy (Landry 2008). If the party’s chain of command is binding, then closer working ties with superiors should strengthen top-down monitoring and facilitate the sanctioning of subordinates in the event of non-compliance.
However, things are not so simple in practice. If local leaders are accountable to multiple principals, and if their career prospects do not depend solely on direct superiors’ support, they may be less compliant. During their postings, local leaders might become beholden to powerful local interests or find that successful completion of their official duties (needed for political promotion) requires them to cooperate closely with local bureaucratic or economic stakeholders. In such cases, politicians are more likely to defend the parochial interests of their own units and bargain aggressively with higher levels. The existence of rampant interest conflicts and bargaining within the party-state hierarchy is the essence of Lieberthal and Oksenberg’s (1988) “fragmented authoritarianism” model.
Concurrent appointments themselves may actually reinforce these bargaining dynamics, insofar as local leaders’ power, incentives, and relations with superiors are partly endogenous to concurrent appointments. By increasing the political rank and profile of local leaders, concurrent appointments have the potential to weaken top-down sanctioning capacity and upward accountability. The rise in rank that comes with concurrent appointments empowers local leaders—and, indirectly, their jurisdictions—by making them superior in bargaining power to erstwhile equals, and by enabling them to liaise with a broader range of political and bureaucratic actors. And concurrent appointments at the subnational level may create a multilevel game environment that adds to the multiple principals problem: although concurrently appointed local leaders remain subordinate to leaders at the next level up, who stand a half-rank above them, their appointment and removal is typically subject to the approval of party-state actors a full step higher as well. Concurrent appointments may thus dilute the authority and powers of sanction exercised by local leaders’ immediate superiors.
It is thus unclear on theoretical grounds whether concurrent appointments reinforce higher-level control or undermine it. Concurrent appointments could give local leaders more political autonomy from and power over entrenched interests in their jurisdictions, while also making local leaders more responsive to immediate superiors, but they could also give a more powerful political platform to actors who seek to champion local economic interests. Moreover, while either of these dynamics could dominate across the board, there could also be more varied effects on intergovernmental dynamics based on contextual factors. Ultimately, which type of intergovernmental dynamics prevails, or under what conditions different dynamics appear, is a question for empirical analysis.

Rethinking the Function of Concurrent Appointments

To help break this theoretical deadlock about the function of concurrent appointments, we differentiate between two dimensions of intergovernmental relations that do not necessarily move together in practice. One aspect of the relationship between higher-level and lower-level authorities concerns the degree of local policy autonomy that lower levels enjoy vis-à-vis their immediate superiors. At issue here is the degree to which lower-level units can pursue policies of their own devising, rather than being subordinated to higher-level plans and policies. If concurrent appointments tighten higher-level control, local units with concurrent appointments should display less policy activism of their own and adhere more closely to the priorities of higher-level authorities. On the other hand, if concurrent appointments enhance the autonomy of localities, there should be evidence that sub-units with concurrently appointed leaders are more likely than other units to devise policies that serve their own interests and challenge higher-level authority.
A different dimension of the relationship between higher- and lower-level actors concerns local economic benefits, or the distribution of economic costs and benefits between different government levels and territorial units. For reasons of career advancement, political patronage, or personal enrichment (Shih 2008; Landry et al. 2018), local leaders in China strive to attract resources to their jurisdictions and achieve strong economic performance. However, their ability to do so depends in part on their relationship with higher-level authorities. If, as Huang (1996) argues, concurrent leadership appointments help to ensure lower-level compliance with higher-level policies, the localities in question may have to pay a price in terms of development opportunities or economic resources. They may experience stricter economic regulation and reduced resource inflows, including lower levels of investment or fiscal transfers. They may also experience expanded outflows in the form of higher rates of taxation or fiscal revenue remittance. By contrast, if concurrent appointments advance local interests, or function as part of a bargain whereby political compliance is traded for material benefits, then localities whose leaders sit in higher-level decision-making bodies may capture more economic opportunities.
Taking these two dimensions into account, we construct a typology of four different intergovernmental dynamics that could arise from concurrent appointments, which we call control, co-optation, compromise, and concession. It is important to emphasize that, beyond simply being points along a spectrum from higher-level power to lower-level power, these are qualitatively different dynamics that have varying implications for the distribution of policymaking power and the allocation of costs and benefits (See Table 1).
Table 1
Varying concurrent appointment dynamics
https://static-content.springer.com/image/art%3A10.1007%2Fs12116-019-09279-0/MediaObjects/12116_2019_9279_Tab1_HTML.png
Control, as we conceptualize it, is an intergovernmental relationship that serves the interests of higher-level authorities. The representation of local leaders on higher-level political bodies helps higher-level authorities more effectively monitor and enforce costly policies against localities. Such a dynamic is associated with less policy autonomy for localities, and is not likely to bring economic benefits.
Co-optation, in contrast, serves the interests of both higher-level authorities and localities. Localities sacrifice some of their policymaking autonomy, adhering closely to the dictates of higher-level authorities. At the same time, however, they derive economic benefits from a closer relationship with higher levels.
Compromise, as we define it, also addresses the interests of both higher-level authorities and localities, but in a different way. Localities with concurrently appointed leaders enjoy a greater degree of policymaking autonomy, allowing lower-level officials to tailor policies to local concerns. However, the localities do not enjoy increased economic support from above.
Finally, concession describes a scenario where concurrent appointments work to both the political and economic advantage of local interests. Under such an arrangement, localities retain a high degree of policymaking autonomy and also are able to advance their material interests by influencing higher-level policy decisions.
We expect that, for a given time and place, intergovernmental dynamics should approximate one of these four types. It seems likely, however, that different concurrent appointment dynamics may coexist in different places at the same time, or that dynamics may change over time in the same place. One possibility we explore below is that different types of localities are subject to different intergovernmental dynamics. China’s localities vary widely in terms of their economic importance and political significance, and local leaders may be concurrently appointed to higher-level leadership bodies for varying reasons and on different terms. This, in turn, could affect the development and governance outcomes associated with concurrent appointments.

City Leaders on Provincial Party Standing Committees

In the remainder of the paper, we examine appointments of prefectural-level leaders to China’s PPSCs to tests the empirical validity of the four dynamics discussed above. We focus on concurrent appointments to PPSCs for several reasons. First, provinces, and provincial-level institutions, are extremely important in China’s politics. Chinese provinces are comparable in population and economic terms to major countries and serve as key units of administration in China’s multilevel polity. Within provinces, PPSCs are the paramount decision-making bodies: they are the locus of political authority and oversee key personnel, policy, and allocative choices (Li 2007; Tan 2004; Bulman and Jaros 2018). While the internal workings of PPSCs remain opaque, several facts are clear. Such committees typically contain 12–13 members, including the provincial party secretary, the provincial governor, and other senior party and government officials. Whereas the top provincial leaders, the party secretary and governor, hold full provincial/ministerial-level rank, second-tier members of the PPSC have deputy-provincial rank. Members of PPSCs not only have a voice at the highest level of provincial politics; by virtue of their elite rank, they also have opportunities to interface directly with the party center. Indeed, all PPSC members’ appointments require Beijing’s approval (Zheng 2007; Landry 2008).
Besides PPSCs’ intrinsic importance, analysis at the subnational level allows us to take advantage of abundant data and empirical variation. Whereas studies of concurrent appointments of provincial leaders to the central Politburo are constrained by a small sample size (31 provincial-level units), we are able to collect data for roughly 300 prefectural-level units. And although the composition of PPSCs is largely standardized across provinces, there is marked variation in the extent to which local (prefectural-level) leaders are included, facilitating analysis of the consequences of concurrent appointments.
Information on the types of localities selected for concurrent appointments to higher-level leadership bodies may offer clues about the intended goals of such appointments, but there is little clear codification of the rules governing these appointments. This practice belongs more to the realm of “informal institutions” (Helmke and Levitsky 2004), or what are described in the Chinese context as “unwritten rules” (qian guize). According to reports from the Chinese media, the concurrent appointment of city-level leaders to PPSCs follows multiple logics in practice (Diyi caijing ribao 2014; Xin jing bao 2015). First, there is a subset of cities whose leaders appear to be concurrently appointed to PPSCs as a rule. This subset includes provincial capitals and deputy-provincial cities, which are generally the largest and most politically and economically important cities in China’s provinces.2 Second, there are cities of economic or historical importance whose leaders appear to enjoy semi-institutionalized concurrent appointments, having gained PPSC seats and held onto them across multiple leadership transitions. Third, there is a subset of cities with more sporadic and unpredictable concurrent leadership appointments.
Our own data on PPSC lineups, drawing on a dataset originally constructed by Bulman and Jaros (2018), confirm this breakdown of “represented” cities into distinct tiers. Across the entire sample from 1996 to 2013, which includes data for all provincial-level units excluding China’s four centrally governed municipalities (Beijing, Tianjin, Shanghai, and Chongqing), 696 prefecture-years have a prefecture party secretary represented on the PPSC, 11.5% of the sample. Four hundred thirty-seven of these representation years belong to provincial capital cities, which typically hold seats on the PPSC. A further 85 representation years belong to non-capital deputy-provincial cities, namely Xiamen, Shenzhen, Dalian, Qingdao, and Ningbo. These cities already enjoy expanded formal economic and fiscal powers, and PPSC representation may thus have different effects for them. This leaves 174 prefecture-years with semi-institutionalized or sporadic concurrent appointments, or 3.3% of all non-capitals and non-deputy-provincial city observations. While representation of such cities is fairly rare, it has become more common over time, though this increase is not monotonic (see Fig. 1).
Although only 3.3% of non-capitals and non-deputy-provincial city-years have concurrently appointed leaders, a much larger sample of cities—44 (14.5%)—have concurrently appointed leaders for at least 1 year (see Table 4 in the appendix for a list of these cities). Six of these are represented for 10 or more years (more than half of the years in the sample). These six—Yanbian, Sanya, Suzhou, Yan’an, Ganzhou, and Luoyang—form a disparate group, including one of China’s richest cities (Suzhou), a geopolitically important autonomous prefecture that shares a border with North Korea (Yanbian), and two cities that played important historic roles as CCP base areas (Yan’an and Ganzhou).
The makeup of this subset suggests that cities’ economic and/or political importance influences selection for concurrent appointments; logit regressions of PPSC concurrent appointments on a set of potential explanatory factors in the statistical appendix confirm this expectation (see Table 5). Excluding capitals and deputy-provincial cities, which are always represented, levels of GDP, FDI, and revenue in a city are associated with a greater likelihood of representation, as is historical importance as key revolutionary base areas, which we proxy with “red tourism” status.3 These results underscore the fact that there are multiple logics of representation. Provincial capitals and deputy-provincial cities enjoy regularized PPSC representation. Cities of economic importance, such as Suzhou, as well as historically and politically important “red cities,” like Yan’an, enjoy quasi-institutionalized representation. Other cities enjoy more sporadic and unpredictable PPSC representation.
By themselves, the characteristics of localities represented on PPSCs do not clarify the political functions served by concurrent leadership appointments. Regular representation in PPSCs of politically important and economically important cities, as well as the more sporadic representation of other cities, could be compatible with the distinct logics of control, co-optation, compromise, or concession. However, the fact that various classes of cities are selected for concurrent appointments underscores the possibility that there are different logics and consequences of PPSC representation for different cities.

Political and Economic Outcomes of Concurrent Appointments

We next turn to a quantitative assessment of the relationship between concurrent appointments and city-level outcomes. Are concurrent appointments associated with enhanced or reduced policy autonomy for the localities concerned? Are they associated with more or fewer economic benefits? The partially endogenous nature of concurrent appointments makes precise estimates of their causal effects difficult. Still, we can assess whether, or in which instances, the outcomes of concurrent appointments match the expectations of control, co-optation, compromise, or concession.
While concurrent appointments are identifiable using our dataset of PPSC membership, measuring city-level policymaking autonomy and distributive outcomes presents challenges. In assessing the level of policymaking autonomy cities enjoy vis-à-vis provincial authorities, our theoretical concern is whether cities merely implement provincial-level programs and policies or whether they undertake major policy initiatives of their own. Given the difficulty of directly gauging local policy activism of this sort, we use an indirect measure. Following an approach similar to Malesky’s (2008) analysis of regional policymaking autonomy in Vietnam, we use the frequency of national media coverage on reform-related topics in a given locality as a proxy for local policy activism. Specifically, we search online Peoples Daily (renmin ribao) archives for articles that include the combination of a city’s name and one or more of four terms related to local reforms and experimentation: reform (gaige), innovation (chuangxin), pilot experiment (shidian), and model (shifan). This data collection yields city-year information on the number of article hits, comparable across cities over time, which we use as our policy autonomy proxy.
There are two key reasons why the degree of national-level media coverage related to reforms is a credible measure of local policy activism. First, reform-related coverage suggests that a city has a dynamic policymaking environment. Regardless of whether a city pioneers reforms on its own or is tapped from above to pilot new policies, policy innovation requires delegating discretion to front-line officials. Second, because the relevant media organs are not under the control of the localities themselves, national coverage attests to the external “newsworthiness” of developments occurring in a given city. Besides capturing instances where cities are mentioned in connection with reforms and policy experimentation, including reform-related search terms also helps to avoid excessive mismeasurement due to news stories about topics unrelated to public policies (e.g., natural disasters or corruption).
Of course, this measure is imperfect and picks up noise as well as signal (i.e., some identified news stories have little relation to policy autonomy or to the city in question). To ensure that the measure is capturing what we expect it to, we conduct a data validation exercise involving in-depth content analysis of a random sub-sample of identified articles. This exercise, which is detailed in the appendix, finds that around one-third of sampled articles very clearly report on local innovations and policy experiments; 8% are pure noise, with no substantive relation to the city in question; and the remainder are more ambiguous in their discussion of local policies but at least somewhat consistent with a policy autonomy interpretation. There is thus considerable measurement error, but because we only use this proxy as a dependent variable in our analyses, this error should not bias results, though it will tend to inflate standard errors and reduce the power of the regressions.4
To assess the relationship between concurrent appointments and local economic outcomes, we test whether cities with concurrently appointed leaders exhibit systemically different local economic growth rates and fiscal balances. First, we examine whether localities’ rates of GDP and fixed-asset investment (FAI) growth systematically vary when local leaders have concurrent appointments. Investment and GDP growth in China are highly influenced by government behavior, so these growth rates help identify whether or not higher-level policies support the economic development of localities. In addition to growth measures, we also examine fiscal outcomes, including revenue and expenditure shares of GDP as well as localities’ fiscal gaps (i.e., the gap between expenditure and revenue shares of GDP). Increased revenue shares of GDP reflect greater success in fiscal extraction.5 If this is matched by rising local expenditures, localities can be said to benefit. However, if higher revenue shares are not matched by rising expenditure (fiscal gaps decline), this may indicate greater upward revenue transfers at a cost to localities. Fiscal balances thus reflect a different kind of economic outcome that may or may not parallel FAI and GDP growth trends.
To test the relationship between concurrent appointments and local policy autonomy and economic outcomes, we regress these variables of interest on a dummy variable for city-years with concurrent appointments, controlling for income levels (logged per capita GDP), size (population), economic structure (primary and tertiary shares of GDP), and economic openness (FDI). To control for time-invariant differences across localities, our main analysis includes prefecture-level fixed effects. This requires us to exclude capital cities and deputy-provincial cities from the analysis.6 Robustness checks in the appendix include provincial fixed effects and cluster standard errors at the prefectural level, thus allowing us to control for capital and deputy-provincial status as well as autonomous cities, “red” cities, and border cities (as defined in the previous section). All regressions include year fixed effects. The appendix includes summary statistics and a discussion of data collection, data assumptions, and missing data.
Our baseline regression results appear in Table 2. With regard to policy autonomy, we find that when cities have concurrently appointed leaders, they are significantly more likely to be mentioned in central news stories related to reform, which indicates greater local policy activism. When it comes to economic outcomes, cities display significantly faster GDP growth when they have concurrently appointed leaders. Fixed-asset investment growth is also faster, though not significantly so. And when cities have concurrently appointed leaders, they display greater revenue shares of GDP that are largely matched by greater expenditure shares, resulting in no significant fiscal gap. These results thus suggest that concurrent leadership appointments are associated with greater policy autonomy and enhanced economic benefits for cities, most closely matching a concession interpretation.
Table 2
Concurrent appointment effects on policy autonomy and distributive outcomes
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
News frequency
GDP growth
FAI growth
Revenue share of GDP
Expenditure share of GDP
Fiscal gap share of GDP
Concurrent PPSC appointment
2.239* (1.74)
2.146** (2.47)
2.475 (0.82)
0.734*** (2.76)
1.086* (1.79)
0.413 (0.75)
Log GDP per capita (1000 RMB)
4.185*** (3.98)
2.729*** (3.85)
8.450*** (3.45)
− 5.955*** (− 27.55)
− 13.91*** (− 28.24)
− 8.012*** (− 17.80)
Population (millions)
− 0.807 (− 0.90)
0.188 (0.31)
3.037 (1.45)
− 1.145*** (− 6.53)
− 2.492*** (− 6.22)
− 1.325*** (− 3.63)
Primary share of GDP (%)
− 0.0487 (− 1.17)
− 0.0276 (− 0.99)
0.432*** (4.47)
− 0.0605*** (− 7.08)
− 0.148*** (− 7.56)
− 0.0898*** (− 5.05)
Tertiary share of GDP (%)
0.166*** (4.25)
− 0.105*** (− 4.00)
− 0.0644 (− 0.71)
0.0798*** (10.11)
0.108*** (5.96)
0.0293* (1.79)
FDI (million USD)
0.00751*** (8.41)
− 0.00236*** (− 3.92)
− 0.00848*** (− 4.08)
0.00189*** (10.62)
0.000175 (0.43)
− 0.00167*** (− 4.50)
Constant
− 30.35** (− 2.39)
− 17.33** (− 2.03)
− 81.35*** (− 2.75)
72.24*** (28.04)
172.5*** (29.31)
100.7*** (18.76)
Observations
3283
3283
3283
2788
2830
2788
All regressions include year and city fixed effects. t statistics in parentheses. *p < 0.10; **p < 0.05; ***p < 0.01
The above outcomes are based on an aggregated analysis, but, as noted earlier, concurrent appointments might have different consequences for different types of cities. To explore this possibility, we repeat the regression analysis using different subsets of relevant cities. Figure 2 below presents coefficient plots with 95% confidence intervals from regressions on four city-type sub-samples: the full sample, a sample of “rich” cities (defined here as those with GDP above the 75th percentile distribution in any given year), a sample of all “red” cities, and a sample of non-rich, non-red cities. (See Tables 8, 9, and 10 for full results.) To make the results more comparable, we use standardized z-scores rather than original values and present the results visually. When limiting the regressions to city-type sub-samples, the coefficient on the concurrent appointment dummy variable represents the difference in outcomes between represented cities and non-represented cities of the same type, rather than against all non-represented cities.7
Results for the full sample, which echo the findings reported above in Table 2, are consistent with a concession interpretation, showing higher news frequency and better economic outcomes for cities with concurrent appointments. Interestingly, however, we find that concurrent appointments are associated with different outcomes for different types of cities. For the subset of rich cities, results largely match the aggregate results, but with larger and more statistically significant coefficients on the distributive outcomes. Here, concurrent appointments are associated with higher relative news frequency, higher growth and investment, and a combination of higher revenue and higher expenditure. This matches a concession interpretation. By contrast, outcomes for red cities more closely fit a compromise interpretation. Red cities with concurrent appointments experience much higher news frequency than red cities without concurrent appointments, suggesting higher policy autonomy. In terms of distributive outcomes, however, red cities exhibit no changes in GDP growth and slower FAI growth, with no clear significant changes in fiscal behavior. Finally, for the set of cities that are neither rich nor red, concurrent appointments show no clear relationship to the political and economic outcomes of interest. This implies either that concurrent appointments have no effect or, more likely, that they have disparate effects across these cities, perhaps determined by other contextual factors.
Two main conclusions stand out from this regression analysis. First, contrary to the idea that concurrent appointments are a mode of top-down control that imposes costs on cities, concurrent appointments are not associated with reduced policy autonomy or major economic costs. Instead, concurrent appointments are often associated with more reform-related news coverage and greater local economic benefits for localities, providing qualified support for the logics of concession, compromise, or co-optation.
Second, concurrent appointments have different consequences for different classes of cities. This suggests that concurrent appointments follow different political logics depending on local context, and that the effects of concurrent appointments may depend on the reasons why cities gained PPSC representation in the first place. Rich cities have many economic resources at their disposal and, given their wealth and importance as economic hubs, have some bargaining power with central and provincial governments even in the absence of concurrent appointments. These underlying economic and political strengths may make it easier for concurrently appointed city leaders to use their PPSC perch to advocate for local interests. Red cities, by contrast, lack strong local resource bases or strategic economic importance. As hallowed historical grounds, however, they enjoy special attention from China’s central party-state.8 To the extent that such cities’ concurrent appointments come as a gift of empowerment from Beijing, such cities may have more political scope to undertake policies independent of their provincial superiors. As poor localities, however, such cities still need provincial support for their economic development, and this may be harder to come by if they are perceived as insubordinate. For other cities, which have neither special economic influence nor special central-level political support, concurrent appointments may be driven more by provincial-level policy agendas. Depending on what these agendas are, concurrent appointments might either work in favor of cities’ interests or against them.
Of course, while the above analysis shows compelling correlations, it does not provide conclusive evidence of the causal effects of concurrent appointments. Including city fixed effects and a battery of controls helps us control for several confounding factors. However, we cannot fully rule out the possibility of endogeneity: it is possible that cities expected to have greater economic vitality or policy experiments are assigned leaders with concurrent appointments, and not that concurrent appointments lead to these outcomes. Additionally, it is possible that concurrent appointments are typically granted to highly motivated or highly capable leaders, and that observed outcomes are based on these leader characteristics rather than institutional arrangements. To help clarify the causal sequences and causal logics at play, the next section uses process-tracing of concurrent appointment outcomes in different Chinese cities. Additionally, the online appendix explores the question of individual characteristics versus institutional arrangements in greater depth, providing preliminary evidence for an institutional interpretation based on observed leader characteristics and the city-level outcomes of different leaders prior to their concurrent PPSC appointments.

Different Models of Concurrent Appointment: Zhuhai, Ganzhou, and Xiangyang

While the analysis in the previous section suggests that concurrent appointments often benefit localities in terms of resource distribution and/or policymaking autonomy, it points to different concurrent appointment dynamics for different types of cities. To further clarify how concurrent appointments affect political and economic outcomes for different classes of cities and to begin shedding light on the causal mechanisms at work, this section examines the cases of Zhuhai (Guangdong), Ganzhou (Jiangxi), and Xiangyang (Hubei), drawing on a combination of Chinese media reports, secondary literature, and evidence from interviews.
The specific cases of Zhuhai, Ganzhou, and Xiangyang are selected for two main reasons. First, they represent different classes of cities: Zhuhai is a relatively wealthy coastal city (a rich city), Ganzhou is a former revolutionary base area (a red city), and Xiangyang, a minor inland industrial center, is neither. Second, these cities exhibit variation over time in concurrent PPSC appointments, enabling before-and-after comparisons. These cases provide qualitative evidence of both the circumstances and effects of concurrent appointments. They also illustrate the distinct dynamics of concession, compromise, and co-optation, as seen in Fig. 3, which compares measures of local autonomy and economic outcomes in the three cities during years with and without concurrent appointments.

Concurrent Appointment as Concession: Zhuhai

The case of Zhuhai city in Guangdong province approximates the idea of concurrent appointments as concession, whereby the leaders of localities with particular clout or importance gain PPSC seats and use this perch to promote local interests. Since the early 1990s, two Zhuhai leaders have concurrently served on Guangdong’s PPSC: Liang Guangda, between 1993 and 1998, and Li Jia, from 2012 until 2016, when he was removed from his post on corruption grounds. Although the leadership tenures of Liang and Li differed in some respects, both periods saw Zhuhai capture local economic benefits and launch high-profile policy initiatives that reflected some degree of autonomy. As Fig. 3 shows, during the terms of these leaders, Zhuhai achieved faster growth and a higher media profile.
Though small in population terms and outshined by leading Guangdong cities like Guangzhou and Shenzhen, Zhuhai has had outsize economic and geographic importance during the reform era. Sitting at the southwest corner of the Pearl River Delta (PRD), opposite Hong Kong and Shenzhen and directly bordering Macao, Zhuhai hosted one of China’s original four special economic zones (SEZs) and has served as the PRD’s western gateway (Sheng and Tang 2013). Given Zhuhai’s strategic location and economic role, it is not surprising that the city has enjoyed PPSC representation more than once.
When Liang Guangda became Zhuhai’s party chief in 1993, he had already developed a reputation as a locally oriented politician and economic booster, having reportedly declined opportunities to enter the provincial government (Lam 1999, p. 278). Between the mid 1980s and the early 1990s, Liang had served in Zhuhai, holding the post of deputy party secretary and mayor. In the same year that Liang became Zhuhai’s party chief, he also joined Guangdong’s PPSC. During the mid-1990s, Liang showed that he was unafraid to pursue developmental mega-projects even when provincial support was lacking. Liang promoted construction of a new Zhuhai-Guangzhou rail line in hopes that such a link would stimulate local economic growth. After being stonewalled by top provincial leaders in 1994, Liang made a political end run around them, seeking central support for the project (Xu and Yeh 2013). This brought resentment from Liang’s immediate superiors. As Xu and Yeh (2013) explain, “following central approval, Guangdong had to give its consent, but made it clear that the province would not invest in the railway because highways, rather than railways, were seen as the priority for provincial investment” (p. 140). Although Zhuhai’s rail project gained temporary momentum during Liang’s tenure, progress halted in 1998 after Liang left his leadership post. Liang’s gambit failed in the end, but Zhuhai’s defiance of provincial authority shows the difficulty of controlling cities with high-ranking leaders at the helm.
Over the following decade, Zhuhai’s economic position in Guangdong weakened. The city’s share of Guangdong’s provincial economic output fell from 3.1% in 1999 to 2.6% in 2012. This relative economic decline was not reversed until 2012, when another local leader gained a concurrent PPSC seat, and Zhuhai’s share of Guangdong’s GDP again began to climb (CDO; authors’ calculations). That year, Li Jia, who had risen through the ranks in another Guangdong locality, was installed as Zhuhai party secretary and also obtained a concurrent PPSC seat. As in the 1990s, having a leader with PPSC rank boosted Zhuhai’s policy activism and economic development.
While Zhuhai’s fading fortunes had begun to revive in 2009, when the city’s Hengqin island was granted enhanced economic and administrative powers as a state-level “New Area” (Ngo et al. 2017), a clearer inflection point came in 2012. During Li Jia’s tenure, Zhuhai again assumed a high-profile economic and policy role, positioning itself as a key engine of China’s “maritime economy.” In June 2013, Zhuhai announced that the Ferretti Group, one of the world’s largest yacht-making conglomerates, would spend three billion yuan to establish a new Asia headquarters in the city (Zhuhai tequ bao 2013). During the following 2 years, Li engaged with entrepreneurs, central government officials, and provincial policymakers, highlighting Zhuhai’s role in China’s maritime economy development and “Made in China 2025” strategies (Zhuhai tequ bao 2014; Zhongguo haiyang bao 2014; Zhuhai tequ bao 2015). This local boosterism paid dividends. In late 2015, Zhuhai, along with Guangzhou and Shenzhen, won permission from the central government to establish one of China’s pilot Free Trade Zones (FTZs) (Nanfang ribao 2015). Like the SEZ status granted three decades earlier, the FTZ designation was a major political achievement for a small city and promised big economic benefits. As Ngo et al. (2017) note, this arrangement—like the Hengqin New Area policy and Zhuhai’s historic SEZ status—further empowered Zhuhai’s already influential leaders, “allowing local state actors to manipulate multiscalar politics to their own advantage” (p. 70).
In sum, the case of Zhuhai illustrates how PPSC representation for wealthy cities can function as a concession, further strengthening localities in both economic and political terms. The tenures of Liang Guangda and Li Jia saw Zhuhai engage in bold efforts to promote local development. The city managed to raise its national profile and capture major economic benefits during these years, sometimes to the chagrin of a provincial government with other priorities. These periods contrast with the relative decline Zhuhai experienced in economic terms and in its public profile during the 2000s, when the city lacked a PPSC seat.

Concurrent Appointment as Compromise: Ganzhou

If the case of Zhuhai illustrates concession, the case of Ganzhou resembles what we call compromise, whereby concurrent appointments enhance local autonomy but do not yield clear economic benefits. Until 2002, Ganzhou lacked representation in Jiangxi’s PPSC. After 2003, however, Ganzhou’s leaders—first Pan Yiyang (2003–2010) and then Shi Wenqing (2011–2015)—held PPSC seats. Under both Pan and Shi, Ganzhou launched major policy initiatives to put a historically important region back on the map. However, greater local autonomy complicated relations with provincial authorities, limiting economic benefits.
Ganzhou is a mountainous prefectural-level city in southern Jiangxi. Due to its rugged topography and distinctive Hakka sub-culture, Ganzhou has never been tightly integrated with the wealthier northern half of Jiangxi. The region is Jiangxi’s largest in both geographic and population terms, and has historical significance as the location of the Jiangxi Soviet, a key revolutionary base area (Looney 2012, pp. 286–87). Despite its Communist legacy, Ganzhou remained predominantly rural and underdeveloped as it entered the twenty-first century.
During the early 2000s, Ganzhou’s economic development strategy took cues from the outward-oriented, industry-first development approach of Jiangxi’s provincial party secretary Meng Jianzhu, who had arrived in 2001. When Ganzhou was tasked by the province with building a new Ganzhou-Dingnan Expressway to link Jiangxi with Guangdong, for example, the municipal leadership gave high priority to this task (Jingji ribao 2002). More broadly, the city leadership emphasized building up its urban-industrial economy. An early 2003 newspaper article by Ganzhou’s mayor listed industry growth as the region’s top priority (Zhongguo xinxibao 2003).
If Ganzhou followed provincial development priorities between 2001 and 2003, the region’s development strategy changed sharply after Pan Yiyang became top leader. A Guangdong native, Pan had served in Jiangxi’s provincial establishment for just under 2 years when he was appointed as Ganzhou’s leader. Under Pan, Ganzhou reoriented its development approach to become a national frontrunner in “Socialist New Countryside Construction.” As detailed by Looney (2012, 2015), this initiative was identified with Pan himself, who already had a reputation as a rural development advocate. Pan spearheaded a large-scale campaign to rebuild rural settlements and restructure rural governance, drawing attention from national-level leaders and media in the process. This rural development campaign differed in tone from the pro-urban, pro-industrial strategy of the provincial leadership. While Pan did not necessarily defy provincial leaders, his initiative in some ways upstaged them (Jaros 2019).
Pan Yiyang’s successor, Shi Wenqing, also used his high political status to promote the visibility of Ganzhou. Shi became Ganzhou’s party secretary in late 2010, and took a seat on Jiangxi’s PPSC in early 2011. Like Pan, Shi lacked deep roots in Jiangxi, having served in the province for 2 years. After his arrival in Ganzhou, Shi launched a publicity blitz to highlight rural poverty in Ganzhou, and appealed for greater central funding to support development in the former Jiangxi Soviet area (Ibid.). Shi’s public appeals and personal outreach to China’s national leadership mobilized new support from the center. The 2012 Central Policy Document No. 21, which called for “revival and development” of the old Jiangxi Soviet and other base areas, promised new forms of aid to Ganzhou, including special tax policies, large-scale investment projects, and new state-level development zones (Renmin ribao 2014a; 2014b). According to a local journalist familiar with the origins of this initiative, the provincial level played at most a secondary role in lobbying for these special policies for Ganzhou (Interview NC011501b 2015; Jaros 2019).
In short, the case of Ganzhou reflects the dynamic we call compromise. Ganzhou’s experience shows the capacity of sub-provincial leaders to leverage their high status as PPSC members and promote locally oriented policy initiatives. After 2003, Ganzhou displayed a high degree of policymaking activism under concurrently appointed leaders Pan and Shi. Despite locally driven policy initiatives that attracted national attention, however, Ganzhou did not achieve above-average economic performance as compared with Jiangxi more broadly (see Fig. 3). This may be because local activism complicated relations between Ganzhou and provincial leaders, limiting the amount of support from the provincial level.

Concurrent Appointment as Co-optation: Xiangyang

In contrast with the experiences of Zhuhai and Ganzhou, the case of Xiangyang in Hubei province illustrates what we call co-optation, whereby a represented locality gains material benefits but is expected to follow higher-level priorities. For much of the period we examine, Xiangyang lacked PPSC representation. After 2011, however, the city’s fortunes changed. A provincial-level strategy aimed at grooming Xiangyang as one of Hubei’s two economic “sub-centers” brought new attention to the city. Xiangyang’s top leaders henceforth had PPSC appointments, and the city enjoyed growing economic support.
Xiangyang, called Xiangfan prior to 2011, is a medium-sized industrial city in northwest Hubei. During the Maoist period and early reform era, Xiangyang was a moderately important state-owned industry base, but the city’s livelihood declined after the 1990s amid liberalization. In recent decades, Xiangyang has lagged increasingly far behind Wuhan, the provincial capital, in population and economic size. Wuhan accounts for nearly a third of total provincial economic output, while the combined output of Hubei’s next two largest cities, Yichang and Xiangyang, is just over a fifth of provincial GDP (CDO; authors’ calculations). This regional imbalance within Hubei became a growing concern for policymakers after the mid-2000s, prompting new development approaches.
After 2003, Hubei pursued a “One Main Center, Two Secondary Centers” regional development strategy (21 shiji jingji baodao 2012). While promoting economic upgrading in Wuhan, the strategy also named Yichang and Xiangyang as growth poles for the less-developed western part of the province. Despite the rollout of the “One Main, Two Secondary” strategy, however, Wuhan’s economic dominance further increased during the 2000s. Redoubling efforts at regional coordination, Hubei’s 2011 government work report called for “grasping tightly research and formulation of the ‘One Main, Two Secondary’ policy, accelerating economic development policy measures, and giving play to Wuhan, Xiangyang, and Yichang’s core growth pole function” (Ibid.).
In addition to policy measures to stimulate growth in Xiangyang and Yichang, Hubei also used political mechanisms. After 2011, Hubei began allotting PPSC seats to the leaders of Xiangyang and Yichang (21 shiji jingji baodao 2013). In the case of Xiangyang, three successive city party secretaries held PPSC seats—Fan Ruiping (2011–2013), Wang Junzheng (2013–2016), and Ren Zhenhe (2016–2017). The decision to assign PPSC members to lead Hubei’s secondary cities from 2011 on reflected the province’s effort to “deepen” its support for the economic development of Xiangyang and Yichang. Assigning PPSC members to city-level posts was viewed as “an extremely important policy”—a kind of political capital at its most literal—that would complement other preferential policies for the city such as expanded project approval powers, fiscal benefits, and expanded land powers. As an official media report from 2017 noted, “under the political system of our country, this [appointment of city-level leaders to PPSC seats] implies that both cities will have the opportunity to garner more support, and this will therefore influence each city’s economic development, urban scale, and external linkages” (Hubei ribao 2017).
While it promised local economic benefits, however, Hubei’s decision to grant PPSC representation to city leaders was closely linked with a provincial-level development strategy. According to one report, the idea of providing Xiangyang and Yichang with PPSC seats had originated in 2007 with the Deputy Director of Hubei’s Provincial Academy of Social Sciences, Qin Zunwen. As Qin explained, “the administrative approach of having deputy provincial-level officials take responsibility for leadership of sub-center cities would not only make for more convenient coordination of relations with provincial departments, but would also facilitate cooperation with neighboring cities…” (21 shiji jingji baodao 2013). That is, concurrent appointment of Xiangyang’s and Yichang’s leaders was intended both to bolster the cities economically and to harmonize their development with that of other localities.
The representation of Xiangyang on Hubei’s PPSC thus illustrates a dynamic of co-optation, whereby economic benefits are exchanged for close local adherence to provincial priorities. Indeed, this interpretation is borne out by patterns of economic development and media coverage in Xiangyang. Although the city’s share of Hubei’s GDP climbed after the introduction of concurrent appointments, the city’s reform-related media profile (our proxy for local policy activism) actually fell (see Fig. 3).

Conclusion

The concurrent appointments of a subset of local leaders to higher-level political bodies in Leninist systems like China raise fundamental questions about the extent of top-down political control and bottom-up interest articulation in such systems. In this paper, we have attempted to clarify the function of concurrent leadership appointments in China by applying a novel conceptual framework and exploiting rich evidence from the subnational level. Our quantitative analysis and case studies both show that concurrent appointments of city-level leaders to China’s PPSCs are not simply—or principally—a form of top-down control. Rather, concurrent appointments benefit local interests at least as much as provincial-level interests. While empirical evidence suggests that different intergovernmental dynamics apply to different types of cities, the patterns we document resemble what we call co-optation, compromise, and concession rather than control.
Quantitative analysis of how concurrent appointments affect local policy autonomy and economic outcomes indicates that represented localities enjoy benefits. Cities with concurrently appointed leaders have higher profiles in national media coverage relative to other localities, which we interpret as a sign of heightened local policy activism and/or autonomy. They also display higher rates of GDP growth and higher levels of investment, suggesting that PPSC representation helps localities capture more economic opportunities. However, the consequences of concurrent appointments vary for different types of cities. “Rich” cities with concurrent appointments tend to enjoy enhanced policy autonomy and economic benefits, while “red” cities appear to enjoy more policy autonomy but fewer material benefits. For other cities, the effects of concurrent appointment are less consistent.
Qualitative evidence from the cases of Zhuhai, Ganzhou, and Xiangyang reinforces our quantitative findings while adding more texture to the analysis. Zhuhai, a wealthy coastal city that enjoyed heightened policy autonomy and economic benefits under concurrently appointed leaders, illustrates a concession dynamic. The case of Ganzhou, a city with a renowned revolutionary legacy, reflects a compromise dynamic whereby concurrent appointments bring more local autonomy but less-obvious economic benefits. For Xiangyang, a medium-sized industrial city, concurrent appointments were a form of co-optation, bringing economic benefits but also pressure to execute higher-level policy priorities. While the timing and consequences of concurrent appointments differed widely across the three cases, however, each city appears to have gained more than it lost, whether in the form of expanded policymaking autonomy or additional economic opportunities. Although our case studies and quantitative analysis do not fully resolve the question of whether it is the institutional arrangements or individual leaders put in place through concurrent appointments that drive city-level outcomes, there is preliminary support for an institutional interpretation.
These subnational findings from China imply that concurrent leadership appointments may benefit rather than constrain local interests at other levels of politics in China and in other Leninist systems. When local leaders concurrently sit on higher-level political bodies, their jurisdictions have a greater voice in higher-level deliberations and may benefit in more tangible ways as well. At the national level in China, the examples of Chen Liangyu and Bo Xilai, provincial leaders who held concurrent Politburo seats, show that even actors integrated into the elite level of national politics may prioritize local interests or personal ambitions over higher-level agendas. Outside China, Malesky’s (2008) analysis of Vietnam finds that provinces with “compatriots” serving in the central cabinet enjoy more rather than less policymaking autonomy. From the standpoint of localities, then, the benefits of access to the central leadership often outweigh the closer oversight that comes with such ties.
Beyond showing how concurrent appointments confer advantages on represented localities, this study adds to understanding of China’s contemporary central-local relations. The analysis here provides further evidence of the dynamics of bargaining, reciprocity, and mutual dependency in intergovernmental relations highlighted in previous work by Li (1997), Zheng (2007), Chung (2016), and others. As such work notes, China’s party-state is neither a top-down nor bottom-up political system but instead an elaborate machine for reconciling centralizing and decentralizing impulses. A key attribute of this system, noted by various generations of past scholarship, from Lieberthal and Oksenberg (1988) and Shirk (1993) to Lam (2010) and Heilmann and Perry (2011), is higher-level authorities’ ability to tailor governance practices to varying contexts and to strike “particularistic bargains” with different locales. As we show here, not only are some cities singled out for concurrent leaderships appointments; the implicit privileges and obligations that accompany PPSC representation also vary by city type. Our analysis also adds to scholars’ picture of the interest articulation and representation mechanisms operating in China’s Leninist hierarchy. Whereas Truex (2016) writes of “representation within bounds” in China’s legislatures, cities’ access to party leadership bodies brings the pursuit of local interests to an even more rarefied level of politics.

Acknowledgements

This article benefited from the constructive criticism of several colleagues and the helpful feedback of anonymous reviewers. We would especially like to recognize suggestions and input of Daniel Koss, Alisha Holland, Brian Palmer-Rubin, Yanilda Gonzalez, and Emily Clough. We would also like to recognize the excellent research assistant work of Gary Wang and Shijia Yao. All mistakes are our own.
Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Appendix

Appendix: Statistical Appendix for “Leninism and Local Interests”

1.
Data: sources and summary statistics
 
2.
Constructing and validating the policy autonomy proxy
 
3.
Which cities get selected to have concurrent appointments?
 
4.
Robustness checks for baseline results (Table 2)
 
5.
Regression results by city type
 
6.
Causal mechanisms: institutions versus individuals
 
1. Data: sources and summary statistics
This paper relies on four general sets of data. First, data on which cities have concurrent appointments in any given year come a novel collection of data about the makeup of China’s provincial party standing committees (PPSCs) and the personal and career backgrounds of PPSC members, introduced in Bulman and Jaros (2018). The dataset spans the years from 1996 to 2013, and contains detailed information on 1443 unique PPSC members. Information on the composition of PPSCs was obtained from annual editions of the China Directory series published by Radiopress, Inc. To supplement these name lists, biographical and career data were gathered from Baidu Online Encyclopedia (百度百科), available at baike.​baidu.​com. Where information was unavailable on Baidu Online Encyclopedia, additional searches were conducted using (1) Xinhua Net (news.​xinhuanet.​com), (2) China Vitae (www.​chinavitae.​com), and/or (3) China Political Elite Database (http://​cped.​nccu.​edu.​tw/​). For the purposes of this paper, there are two relevant variables: the concurrent position of PPSC members (except for party secretaries and deputy party secretaries, all other PPSC members tend to have at least one other concurrent party or government position); and, when the concurrent position is a prefectural-level city party secretary post, the name of the city.
Second, to create our policy autonomy proxy, we collect data from a digital archive of content from the Peoples Daily (人民日报), available at http://​www.​oriprobe.​com/​PeoplesDaily.​shtml. As described in more depth in the next section, we use this archive to collect data on the number of Peoples Daily articles during each year between 1996 and 2013 that contain both the name of a given prefectural-level city and one or more terms related to local reforms and experimentation: reform (改革), innovation (创新), pilot experiment (试点), and model (示范). We use this measure of reform-associated news frequency as a proxy for the degree of “policy autonomy” of different Chinese cities. The subsequent section in this appendix describes in more depth the data collection process as well as the results of a data validation exercise.
The third set of data relates to the coding of city types, and in particular the identification of “border cities” and “red” (Communist revolutionary heritage) cities. For a border city dummy variable, we code as “1” all prefectures that share a land border with another country, based on Google Maps. For “red” cities, we rely on cities’ status as centers of “red tourism” (红色旅游). Since 2005, the Chinese government has officially promoted “red tourism” involving Communist Party historical sites. We code 13 cities as “red” based on the 2010 signing of a “China Red Tourism Cities Strategic Cooperation Yan’an Declaration.” The 13 signatories were Guang’an, Yan’an, Xiangtan, Jinggangshan, Ruijin, Zunyi, Baise, Shijiazhuang, Linyi, Anyang, Yulin, Qingyang, and Huining. Jinggangshan and Ruijin are county-level cities under the administration of Ji’an and Ganzhou, respectively, while Huining is a county in Baiyin (Gansu).
Finally, we draw data on prefecture-level city socioeconomic characteristics from China Data Online, including GDP, FAI, revenue, expenditure, population, FDI, land area, primary sector GDP, and tertiary sector GDP.
Table 3 below summarizes the variables we use in our analysis, including means, standard deviations, and the numbers of observations in both the complete dataset and the more limited main sample we use to conduct our analysis, which excludes certain outliers and limits analysis to a sample with full information for all independent variables. GDP and FAI data are highly variable from year to year in the CDO data, which leads to some extreme outliers when we construct annual growth measures, as well as extreme fluctuations in the independent variables which rely on GDP for their construction (fiscal shares of GDP and economic structure). So to prevent unreliable outliers from driving our analysis, we exclude observations with an absolute value of GDP growth over 50% as well as observations with an absolute value of FAI growth over 100% (approximately 2% of the sample in each case).
Table 3
Summary statistics for full sample and limited analysis sample
 
Full sample
Analysis sample
Mean
Standard deviation
Observations
Mean
Standard deviation
Observations
Concurrent PPSC appointment
0.116
0.321
5712
0.133
0.340
3886
News frequency
25.643
46.051
5712
28.809
48.527
3886
GDP growth %
18.482
48.712
4727
14.674
8.549
3886
FAI growth %
33.435
70.531
4103
24.179
23.986
3886
Revenue share of GDP %
5.990
3.537
4093
5.635
3.024
3386
Expenditure share of GDP %
13.361
9.349
4065
12.497
8.382
3356
Fiscal gap share of GDP %
7.462
8.183
4021
6.964
7.552
3314
Log GDP per capita (1000 RMB)
9.475
0.993
4693
9.430
0.897
3881
Population (millions)
3.994
2.330
4705
3.989
2.324
3881
Land area
1.550
2.020
4586
1.555
2.048
3851
Primary share of GDP (%)
18.260
18.047
4667
17.835
13.380
3886
Tertiary share of GDP (%)
35.992
13.095
4663
35.667
10.647
3886
FDI (million USD)
347.893
801.6504
438
304.111
679.567
3739
Autonomous city
0.211
0.408
554
40.100
0.300
3886
Border city
0.134
0.341
5712
0.069
0.254
3886
“Red” city
0.039
0.193
571
20.044
0.205
3886
Capital city
0.082
0.275
555
40.100
0.300
3886
Deputy provincial city
0.015
0.123
555
40.018
0.132
3886
For the data we collect ourselves, there is no missing data for any city-year, although there is a possibility that we have missed concurrent leadership appointments given the potential incompleteness of our online sources. However, the CDO data is less complete: as shown in Table 3, approximately one-quarter of FAI, government revenue, and government expenditure observations are missing. We have no reason to believe that these missing observations are systematically biased; rather than a bias toward missing cities, CDO has temporal gaps, and some years have very limited coverage for key variables: over half of government fiscal data is missing from 1999 to 2002, and most FAI data is missing for 2012 and 2013. Imputing values for these missing observations is difficult given that there are frequently multiple years missing in succession and the missing observations often occur at the beginning or end of the sample. However, as data for FDI (one of our IVs) is missing only for 1 year (2009), we do impute 2009 FDI values by taking the simple average of 2008 and 2010 FDI values. This allows us to keep an additional 265 observations. (Excluding 2009 from the analysis makes no difference to the baseline results.)
Given that a substantial portion of the missing CDO data occurs in our different dependent variables, for the main results we choose not to limit the sample to only those observations that have data for all dependent variables. If we limit to a sample that has a full set of observations across all DVs and IVs—thus yielding a consistent number of observations for each regression—our results do not substantively change (see Table 7).
2. Constructing and validating the policy autonomy proxy
To proxy the policy autonomy of localities vis-à-vis their political-administrative superiors, we take an approach similar to that which Malesky (2008) uses to assess regional policy autonomy in Vietnam. Malesky’s analysis tracks the relative frequency with which different Vietnamese provinces are mentioned in major national-level newspapers in association with episodes of “fence-breaking” or economic policy reform. Because reform experiments and instances of “fence-breaking” reflect local policy initiative and may run against higher-level preferences, Malesky argues that they proxy for local policymaking autonomy. In our own analysis, we also look for indications of local policy experimentation and reform activism. We do not assume that such reform policies necessarily run counter to the wishes of higher-level authorities, but we do regard them as a reflection of local policy activism and we argue that reform experiments by their nature entail an exercise of local policy autonomy.
We search a digital Peoples Daily (人民日报) archive to determine the number of Peoples Daily articles for every prefecture-level city and each year from 1996 to 2013 that contain a given city’s name and one or more terms related to local reforms and experimentation: reform (改革), innovation (创新), pilot experiment (试点), and model (示范). The inclusion of reform-related terms is meant to avoid excessive noise and mismeasurement due to collecting news stories about unrelated topics (e.g., natural disasters, corruption cases). Our method of collecting these data involved running a single search for each prefecture-year and recording the number of article hits. This exercise provided data for 6372 city-years and flagged a total of 156,753 relevant news articles, making for an average of 24.6 reform-related news mentions per city-year.
Our analysis had to address the fact that several prefectures change their names over time, and many change their administrative status (e.g., from 地区 or 盟 to 市), over the sample period. We search only for city names, not including administrative status (e.g., 苏州 and not 苏州市) to avoid the latter problem. When cities change names, we change search terms to search for the correct city name in any given year. These include:
  • 襄阳 (2011–2013), 襄樊 (1996–2010)
  • 普洱 (2004–2013), 思茅 (1996–2003)
  • 鄂尔多斯 (2001–2013), 伊克昭 (1996–2000)
  • 达州 (1999–2013), 达川 (1996–1998)
  • 通辽 (1999–2013), 哲里木 (1996–1998)
  • 宿州 (1999–2013), 宿县 (1996–1998)
  • 吴忠 (1998–2013), 哲里木 (1996–1997)
The more substantive concern is whether our relative news frequency measure is indeed a valid indicator of policy autonomy. Along these lines, we conduct a validation exercise that involves analyzing a subset of the articles identified in the original exercise and determining if they are indeed about (or whether they at least mention) government reforms/innovations/pilots/models in the specified cities. We expect that the content of many but not all of the articles identified by our searches will be related to the city in question or to reform policies (however broadly defined). We selected 157 articles for closer reading by randomizing city-years and summing the number of articles across them until we reached 0.1% of the total number of Peoples Daily articles flagged in our searches. This resulted in 12 city-years being represented in our close-reading sample. For each of the 157 articles, we collected the following information:
  • Article name: The original article name in Chinese
  • Article discusses reform: Does the article’s use of the “reform” term (改革, 创新, 试点, 示范) actually correspond to any government reform (however defined and regardless of where the reform takes place)?
  • City is main subject: Is the specified city the main subject of the article (regardless of whether the article is about a reform)?
  • City mentioned only once: Is the specified city only mentioned once in the article (regardless of whether it is mentioned in relationship to the reform)?
  • Reform in specified city: Does the article mention a reform in the specified city?
  • Reform in city is main subject: Is the reform in the specified city the main subject of the article?
  • Reform in city mentioned once: Is the reform in the specified city only mentioned one time?
  • Reform in city mentioned multiple times: Is the reform in the city mentioned multiple times, but still not the major focus of the article?
  • Reform subject: What is the subject of the reform (e.g., land, education, cadre management, etc.)?
  • Reform name: If the reform/pilot/experiment is given a name, write in the original Chinese.
  • Positive or negative story: Is the way the reform in the specified city mentioned in the article generally “positive” or “negative”?
This validation exercise confirms that our measure captures some degree of policy innovation and reform in the specified cities despite a certain amount of background noise. In 13 articles out of 157 in the sample (8%), the city in question is incorrectly specified. In all other cases, the city in question is mentioned, though not always as the location of a policy innovation or reform. Out of 157 articles, 83 (52%) are explicitly related to reforms or innovations, while 51 of the articles (32%) are clearly about reforms in the specified city. Other articles fall into a gray area: the specified city is mentioned and policy reforms are discussed, but it is not clear that these reforms and innovations are taking place in the city of interest. When reforms are discussed, in 96% of cases they are discussed with a positive valence, confirming our interpretation of the reason why national media would focus on these local innovations.
In sum, somewhere between 32 and 92% of articles in the close-reading sample fit our “policy autonomy” interpretation. While the policy autonomy proxy seems broadly valid, it also has a considerable degree of measurement error, with up to half of observations representing noise and not signal. Assuming this measurement error is uncorrelated with our independent variables, it should lead to higher standard errors in our regression coefficient estimates. Because average estimates should not differ, however, our results will not be biased.
3. Which cities get selected to have concurrent appointments?
Table 4 below lists all non-capital and non-deputy-provincial cities that have concurrent appointments over 1996–2013, including the number of years in which they hold these appointments.
Table 4
List of cities with concurrent appointments
Prefecture
Province
Number of years
Prefecture (continued)
Province
Number of years
Baise
Guangxi
1
Ningde
Fujian
1
Baoding
Hebei
2
Qiandongnan
Guizhou
1
Baotou
Neimenggu
8
Qianxinan
Guizhou
3
Beihai
Guangxi
8
Qingyang
Gansu
1
Bijie
Guizhou
1
Qinhuangdao
Hebei
1
Changdu
Xizang
2
Qinzhou
Guangxi
1
Chifeng
Neimenggu
1
Sanya
Hainan
16
Chongqing
Sichuan
1
Suqian
Jiangsu
1
Chuxiong
Yunnan
1
Suzhou
Jiangsu
13
Daqing
Heilongjiang
4
Tangshan
Hebei
6
Enshi
Hubei
1
Tongliao
Neimenggu
2
Ezhou
Hubei
2
Wenzhou
Zhejiang
5
Foshan
Guangdong
5
Wuhu
Anhui
3
Ganzhou
Jiangxi
10
Wuxi
Jiangsu
7
Guilin
Guangxi
1
Yanan
Shaanxi
12
Guyuan
Ningxia
2
Yanbian
Jilin
18
Hainan
Qinghai
1
Yantai
Shandong
3
Haixi
Qinghai
1
Yichang
Hubei
2
Jilin
Jilin
1
Yulin
Guangxi
3
Liuzhou
Guangxi
2
Yushu
Qinghai
2
Luoyang
Henan
10
Zhuhai
Guangdong
3
Nandu
Xizang
2
Zunyi
Guizhou
22
To more systematically test whether considerations of economic and political importance drive concurrent appointments for the larger set of represented cites, we run logit regressions of PPSC concurrent appointments on a set of potential explanatory factors:
$$ C{A}_{it}={\alpha}_{it}+\beta {\mathbf{X}}_{\mathbf{it}}+\gamma {\mathbf{C}}_{\mathbf{it}}+{\delta}_t+{\varphi}_i+{\varepsilon}_{it} $$
Here, our unit of observation is the city-year; i references cities and t references years. CA is a dummy variable for city-years with concurrent appointments. X is a vector of potential city-level predictors of concurrent appointments: city-level gross domestic product (GDP), population, foreign direct investment (FDI), a dummy variable for “red” cities with revolutionary histories, a dummy variable for border cities, and a dummy variable for autonomous cities. In addition, the regressions include a set of controls (C) for whether a city is a capital city or a deputy-provincial city, and include both year fixed effects (δ) and province/region fixed effects (φ). This logit regression helps to determine whether economically important cities (GDP), large cities (population), economically open cities (FDI), historically important cities (revolutionary history), and/or geopolitically important cities (border cities) are more likely to enjoy representation. Border cities are coded “1” when they share a land border with another country (13% of prefectures). Revolutionary cities are coded “1” based on their “red tourism” status (4% of prefectures).
Regression results appear in Table 5 below. The results confirm our expectations that beyond capitals and deputy-provincial cities, two types of city are most likely to gain concurrent appointments: economically important cities and historically/politically important cities. GDP and FDI are associated with a greater likelihood of representation, as might be expected, as is revolutionary status (indicated by cities’ designation as “red tourism” sites). Border cities are if anything less likely to have representation (though this is a weak and insignificant effect). Column (1) includes macro-regional dummies instead of provincial fixed effects; interestingly, there are no apparent macro-regional differences. These results dovetail with an “eyeball” test from looking at the list of represented cities in Table 4, and underscore the fact that there are multiple logics of PPSC representation for cities.
Table 5
Logit results for city PPSC representation
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
Concurrent PPSC appointment
Concurrent PPSC appointment
Concurrent PPSC appointment
Concurrent PPSC appointment
GDP (billion RMB)
0.00870* (1.69)
0.0125** (2.48)
  
Population (million)
− 0.0235 (− 0.22)
− 0.0654 (− 0.55)
0.0301 (0.28)
0.0147 (0.15)
Revenue (billion RMB)
− 0.0380 (− 0.62)
− 0.0797 (− 1.23)
0.0549 (1.17)
0.0535 (1.08)
FDI (million USD)
0.000802 (1.44)
0.00132** (2.07)
0.000919* (1.68)
0.00160*** (2.67)
“Red” city
2.062** (2.49)
2.045** (2.51)
1.963** (2.38)
1.849** (2.37)
Border city
− 0.315 (− 0.28)
− 0.861 (− 0.83)
− 0.238 (− 0.21)
− 0.710 (− 0.65)
Capital city
6.397*** (12.75)
7.962*** (9.36)
6.329*** (12.79)
7.810*** (9.52)
Deputy-provincial city
6.109*** (5.99)
8.138*** (8.52)
5.756*** (5.40)
7.503*** (8.24)
Autonomous city
0.894 (1.03)
− 0.558 (− 0.62)
0.878 (1.02)
− 0.945 (− 1.11)
Northeast region
− 0.0588 (− 0.10)
 
0.0457 (0.07)
 
Coastal region
− 0.463 (− 0.59)
 
− 0.261 (− 0.36)
 
Western region
− 0.0413 (− 0.07)
 
− 0.0370 (− 0.07)
 
Constant
− 3.604*** (− 2.82)
− 5.766*** (− 3.12)
− 3.423*** (− 3.01)
− 5.420*** (− 2.93)
Observations
3242
3242
3242
3242
Year fixed effects
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Province fixed effects
No
Yes
No
Yes
Standard errors clustered by prefecture. t statistics in parentheses. *p < 0.10; **p < 0.05; ***p < 0.01
4. Robustness checks for baseline results (Table 2)
Here, we provide additional robustness checks for the baseline results in Table 2. In Table 6, we include provincial fixed effects rather than prefecture fixed effects, and cluster standard errors by province. This allows us to more explicitly identify whether outcomes for cities with concurrent appointments differ from other cities within the same province, rather than in comparison to all cities across China. Greater news frequency or GDP growth that occurred across all cities in a province relative to the national average would yield significant effects when including prefecture fixed effects, but this effect would be blunted by including province fixed effects. Given that we are trying to identify policy autonomy from the province itself and distributive outcomes as they relate to provincial authorities, this is an important robustness check. The results confirm the baseline Table 2 findings.
Table 6
Provincial fixed effects with standard errors clustered by prefecture
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
News frequency
GDP growth
FAI growth
Revenue share of GDP
Expenditure share of GDP
Fiscal gap share of GDP
Concurrent PPSC appointment
14.98** (2.31)
0.665* (1.75)
1.181 (1.37)
0.326 (0.15)
1.134** (2.31)
1.957*** (2.85)
Log GDP per capita (1000 RMB)
16.21*** (3.05)
− 6.429*** (− 9.15)
0.745 (1.31)
1.956 (1.49)
− 1.366** (− 2.42)
− 7.849*** (− 7.28)
Population (millions)
2.520*** (2.99)
− 0.479*** (− 6.37)
− 0.161** (− 2.58)
− 0.0833 (− 0.53)
− 0.243*** (− 5.46)
− 0.711*** (− 7.84)
Land area
1.282** (1.97)
0.210** (2.13)
0.0662 (1.09)
0.301 (1.42)
− 0.0202 (− 0.40)
0.186 (1.51)
Primary share of GDP (%)
0.0311 (0.17)
− 0.0166 (− 0.55)
− 0.0581 (− 1.51)
0.0991 (1.26)
− 0.0771** (− 2.23)
− 0.0955* (− 1.95)
Tertiary share of GDP (%)
0.612** (2.01)
0.0602*** (2.86)
− 0.129*** (− 3.86)
− 0.100 (− 1.57)
0.0474** (2.06)
0.106*** (3.40)
FDI (million USD)
0.0232*** (3.50)
0.000102 (0.34)
− 0.000400* (− 1.70)
− 0.00175** (− 2.57)
0.000818*** (3.45)
0.000874* (1.88)
Autonomous city
27.91** (2.03)
− 2.714* (− 1.74)
− 3.752 (− 1.63)
− 0.617 (− 0.14)
0.302 (0.14)
2.708 (0.96)
Border city
− 5.357 (− 0.87)
1.356* (1.89)
− 0.0193 (− 0.03)
− 0.260 (− 0.18)
0.392 (1.03)
1.777** (2.24)
“Red” city
7.837 (1.18)
0.112 (0.22)
0.790 (1.02)
− 0.527 (− 0.39)
1.002 (1.59)
1.083 (1.13)
Capital city
49.26*** (4.25)
− 0.462 (− 0.72)
1.186 (1.17)
2.777 (1.16)
− 0.267 (− 0.51)
− 0.787 (− 0.92)
Deputy provincial city
36.26 (1.52)
4.438*** (2.98)
1.463 (1.45)
− 0.714 (− 0.31)
1.393 (1.28)
5.846** (2.48)
Constant
− 220.8*** (− 3.69)
76.43*** (10.35)
13.90** (2.12)
13.272 (0.94)
4.76*** (3.52)
97.98*** (8.03)
Observations
3728
3161
3728
3728
3233
3203
All regressions include year and province fixed effects, with standard errors clustered by prefecture. t statistics in parentheses. *p < 0.10; **p < 0.05; ***p < 0.01
In addition, Table 7 repeats the baseline Table 2 regressions but uses a more limited sample of observations. In order to run regressions on a consistent sample for each dependent variable, we drop all city-year observations that have missing observations for any of the relevant dependent variables or independent variables. This results in 2788 observations (nearly 20% fewer than several regressions have in the baseline results). Using this limited sample does not significantly change the results.
Table 7
Baseline results using maximum consistent sample for all regressions
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
Relative news frequency
GDP growth
FAI growth
Revenue share of GDP
Expenditure share of GDP
Fiscal gap share of GDP
Concurrent PPSC appointment
2.039 (1.39)
2.596*** (2.65)
1.841 (0.59)
0.734*** (2.76)
1.147* (1.86)
0.413 (0.75)
Log GDP per capita (1000 RMB)
3.567*** (2.99)
2.274*** (2.85)
8.946*** (3.50)
− 5.955*** (− 27.55)
− 13.97*** (− 27.84)
− 8.012*** (− 17.80)
Population (millions)
− 0.747 (− 0.77)
− 0.182 (− 0.28)
1.500 (0.72)
− 1.145*** (− 6.53)
− 2.470*** (− 6.07)
− 1.325*** (− 3.63)
Primary share of GDP (%)
− 0.035 (− 0.74)
– 0.0356 (− 1.13)
0.460*** (4.55)
− 0.0605*** (− 7.08)
− 0.150*** (− 7.58)
− 0.0898*** (− 5.05)
Tertiary share of GDP (%)
0.148*** (3.39)
− 0.0942*** (− 3.23)
− 0.0786 (− 0.84)
0.0798*** (10.11)
0.109*** (5.96)
0.0293* (1.79)
FDI (million USD)
0.00708*** (7.19)
− 0.00205*** (− 3.11)
− 0.00761*** (− 3.61)
0.00189*** (10.62)
0.000223 (0.54)
− 0.00167*** (− 4.50)
Constant
− 23.44* (− 1.65)
− 11.44 (− 1.20)
− 80.54*** (− 2.64)
72.24*** (28.04)
172.9*** (28.92)
100.7*** (18.76)
Observations
2788
2788
2788
2788
2788
2788
All regressions include year and city fixed effects. t statistics in parentheses. *p < 0.10; **p < 0.05; ***p < 0.01
5. Regression Results by City Type
In the paper itself, Fig. 3 presents a plot of the estimated coefficients for the concurrent appointment independent variable from 16 different regressions. To create coefficient plots that are easily comparable, we run regressions using normalized z-scores for all variables. Here, we present the baseline regressions results using raw data (i.e., the identical approach to as used to generate Table 2), for the three city subsets: rich cities (Table 8), red cities (Table 9), and non-rich, non-red cities (Table 10). As in the text, we define rich cities as those with per capita income above the 75th percentile in any given year, and we define red cities based on red tourism status, as described in section 1 of this appendix.
Table 8
Baseline regression (Table 4) repeated on “rich” city sample
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
Relative news frequency
GDP growth
FAI growth
Revenue share of GDP
Expenditure share of GDP
Fiscal gap share of GDP
Concurrent PPSC appointment
3.223 (1.10)
5.369*** (4.80)
14.85*** (3.17)
0.441* (1.71)
0.740*** (4.35)
0.398 (1.60)
Log GDP per capita (1000 RMB)
14.90** (2.51)
2.252 (0.99)
− 6.665 (− 0.70)
− 1.679*** (− 2.97)
− 3.946*** (− 10.68)
− 2.142*** (− 3.93)
Population (millions)
− 0.596 (− 0.23)
0.429 (0.43)
− 1.537 (− 0.36)
− 0.612** (− 2.56)
0.109 (0.69)
0.698*** (3.02)
Primary share of GDP (%)
0.658* (1.73)
− 0.608*** (− 4.19)
− 0.628 (− 1.03)
− 0.0679** (− 1.97)
− 0.157*** (− 6.90)
− 0.0978*** (− 2.94)
Tertiary share of GDP (%)
0.0743 (0.29)
− 0.559*** (− 5.82)
− 0.650 (− 1.61)
0.0307 (1.23)
− 0.0144 (− 0.87)
− 0.0414* (− 1.72)
FDI (million USD)
0.00268 (1.42)
− 0.000265 (− 0.37)
− 0.00587* (− 1.94)
0.00107*** (6.40)
0.000311*** (2.82)
− 0.000774*** (− 4.81)
Constant
− 139.0* (− 1.89)
1.088 (0.04)
132.8 (1.13)
27.75*** (3.97)
55.96*** (12.22)
26.98*** (4.00)
Observations
664
664
664
538
561
538
Only “rich” cities (those above the 75th percentile in terms of per capita income in any given year) are included in these regressions. All regressions include year and city fixed effects. t statistics in parentheses. *p < 0.10; **p < 0.05; ***p < 0.01
Table 9
Baseline regression (Table 4) repeated on “red” city sample
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
Relative news frequency
GDP growth
FAI growth
Revenue share of GDP
Expenditure share of GDP
Fiscal gap share of GDP
Concurrent PPSC appointment
28.47*** (4.22)
− 1.480 (− 0.58)
− 21.47 (− 1.60)
1.038 (0.76)
2.372 (1.38)
1.334 (1.23)
Log GDP per capita (1000 RMB)
2.610 (0.49)
− 2.206 (− 1.09)
3.803 (0.36)
− 9.911*** (− 10.72)
− 18.14*** (− 15.74)
− 8.232*** (− 11.28)
Population (millions)
− 16.95 (− 1.51)
0.787 (0.18)
− 5.183 (− 0.23)
− 4.879** (− 2.48)
− 10.45*** (− 4.26)
− 5.575*** (− 3.59)
Primary share of GDP (%)
0.608 (1.47)
− 0.236 (− 1.50)
0.398 (0.48)
− 0.628*** (− 8.07)
− 0.826*** (− 8.50)
− 0.198*** (− 3.21)
Tertiary share of GDP (%)
0.897** (2.33)
− 0.383** (− 2.62)
− 0.607 (− 0.79)
− 0.047 (− 0.72)
70.087 (1.05)
30.135** (2.57)
FDI (million USD)
− 0.0302*** (− 2.63)
− 0.00403 (− 0.92)
0.00940 (0.41)
− 0.00283 (− 1.37)
− 0.00216 (− 0.83)
0.000672 (0.41)
Constant
93.88 (1.25)
55.76* (1.96)
13.38 (0.09)
142.9*** (10.50)
265.2*** (15.62)
122.3*** (11.39)
Observations
140
140
140
118
118
118
Only “red” cities, as defined in the text, are included in these regressions. All regressions include year and city fixed effects. t statistics in parentheses. *p < 0.10; **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01
Table 10
Baseline regression (Table 4) repeated on non-rich, non-red city sample
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
Relative news frequency
GDP growth
FAI growth
Revenue share of GDP
Expenditure share of GDP
Fiscal gap share of GDP
Concurrent PPSC appointment
− 2.060 (− 1.49)
− 0.488 (− 0.35)
− 3.736 (− 0.81)
0.294 (0.74)
− 0.0121 (− 0.01)
− 0.235 (− 0.25)
Log GDP per capita (1000 RMB)
3.022*** (3.40)
3.010*** (3.39)
10.63*** (3.59)
− 6.561*** (− 25.82)
− 15.76*** (− 24.13)
− 9.295*** (− 15.31)
Population (millions)
− 1.538* (− 1.95)
0.956 (1.21)
3.728 (1.42)
− 1.511*** (− 7.08)
− 2.950*** (− 5.32)
− 1.450*** (− 2.85)
Primary share of GDP (%)
− 0.0802*** (− 2.64)
− 0.0131 (− 0.43)
0.394*** (3.89)
− 0.0464*** (− 5.32)
− 0.131*** (− 5.79)
− 0.0859*** (− 4.12)
Tertiary share of GDP (%)
0.103*** (3.52)
− 0.0658** (− 2.25)
0.012 (0.12)
10.0708*** (8.67)
0.0979*** (4.63)
0.0279 (1.43)
FDI (million USD)
0.00159 (1.10)
− 0.0000536 (− 0.04)
− 0.00394 (− 0.82)
0.00285*** (7.25)
0.00151 (1.48)
− 0.00122 (− 1.30)
Constant
− 13.59 (− 1.29)
− 23.58** (− 2.24)
− 106.5*** (− 3.05)
78.82*** (26.52)
191.6*** (25.08)
113.8*** (16.03)
Observations
2496
2496
2496
2145
2164
2145
Only cities that are neither “rich” (above the 75th percentile of per capita income in any given year) nor “red” (as defined in the text) are included in these regressions. All regressions include year and city fixed effects. t statistics in parentheses. *p < 0.10; **p < 0.05; ***p < 0.01
6. Causal mechanisms: institutions versus individuals
Our analysis in the paper works from the idea that the institution of concurrent appointment itself causes the effects we see—that the difference in city leaders’ political status and in their relationship to superiors under concurrent appointment is responsible for outcomes that would not otherwise occur. However, this is not the only possible causal logic at work. One alternative possibility is that already high-performing or well-connected leaders are rewarded with concurrent appointments, such that we are conflating the effect of an institution with the achievement of an individual. Another, potentially related, possibility is that concurrent appointment (and the higher rank it confers on an individual) incentivizes a given city leader to behave more ambitiously by opening up previously unavailable career possibilities. In either case, observed outcomes might be driven by the characteristics of specific leaders rather than the institutional empowerment of specific cities. Although our data do not allow us to fully resolve this question of causal logic, additional evidence from the case-study cities and further quantitative analysis increase our confidence in the institutional interpretation.
One piece of evidence that would support an individual-driven as opposed to institution-driven interpretation would be if concurrently appointed leaders tended to be young “rising stars”—individuals who have been specially groomed for rapid career promotion due to either merit or patronage. In terms of ability, such individuals might be more capable or wield more political capital to begin with. In terms of incentives, rising stars might feel greater pressure to make a name for themselves.9 What we observe empirically, however, is that leaders of various ages, not simply rising stars, get concurrent appointments. We also find that the quantitative relationships between current appointments and enhanced local economic outcomes and policy activism hold across different age categories and are, if anything, driven by older cadres. The city leaders mentioned in our case-study cities were appointed at varying ages, from the relatively young 42 in the case of Pan Yiyang in Ganzhou and 45 for Fan Ruiping in Xiangyang to the more advanced 56 for Shi Wenqing in Ganzhou and 58 for Liang Guangda in Zhuhai (China Vitae; Baidu Baike). Looking more systematically at the age profile of concurrent appointees in our dataset, we find that such leaders average 51.9 years old, younger than the average for PPSC members (54.5 years for regular members), but equal to the average age of all prefecture leaders over 2000–2015.10 And beyond the case-study cities as well, the age distribution of concurrent appointees is very wide: while some are rising stars in their early 40s, many are in their late 50s and likely serving in their final post. To test whether rising star cadres drive the aggregate results, we re-run our baseline regressions using different age-based samples: rising stars (aged 49 and younger, accounting for 26% of cases), young (52 and younger, 51% of cases), old (53 and older, 49% of cases), and last post (56 and older, 25% of cases). As shown in Table 11, there is no evidence that rising stars drive our aggregate results; if anything, the results are driven by older cadres, though the signs and general results are fairly consistent throughout age groups.
Table 11
Baseline regression (Table 4) repeated on age group sub-samples
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
(9)
(10)
(11)
(12)
(13)
(14)
(15)
(16)
(17)
(18)
(19)
(20)
(21)
(22)
(23)
(24)
News frequency
News frequency
News frequency
News frequency
GDP growth
GDP growth
GDP growth
GDP growth
FAI growth
FAI growth
FAI growth
FAI growth
Revenue share of GDP
Revenue share of GDP
Revenue share of GDP
Revenue share of GDP
Expenditure share of GDP
Expenditure share of GDP
Expenditure share of GDP
Expenditure share of GDP
Fiscal gap share of GDP
Fiscal gap share of GDP
Fiscal gap share of GDP
Fiscal gap share of GDP
Concurrent PPSC appointment
Rising star (49 and younger)
0.904
   
− 2.194
   
− 3.303
   
0.273
   
0.215
   
− 0.0209
   
(0.51)
   
(− 1.38)
   
(− 0.60)
   
(0.73)
   
(0.25)
   
(− 0.03)
   
Young (52 and younger)
 
− 1.489
   
0.957
   
3.841
   
0.639**
   
0.592
   
− 0.00982
  
 
(− 1.08)
   
(0.77)
   
(0.90)
   
(2.21)
   
(0.90)
   
(− 0.02)
  
Old (53 and older)
  
6.689***
   
3.434**
   
6.641
   
0.419
   
1.290
   
0.897
 
  
(3.62)
   
(2.08)
   
(1.17)
   
(1.14)
   
(1.54)
   
(1.18)
 
Last post (56 and older)
   
0.870
   
0.879
   
26.35***
   
1.053*
   
1.955
   
0.923
   
(0.27)
   
(0.31)
   
(2.68)
   
(1.70)
   
(1.38)
   
(0.72)
Log GDP per capita (1000 RMB)
3.852***
3.840***
3.635***
3.834***
7.160***
7.179***
7.069***
7.165***
11.66***
11.69***
11.47***
11.35***
− 6.385***
− 6.382***
− 6.398***
− 6.400***
− 14.25***
− 14.25***
− 14.29***
− 14.28***
− 7.901***
− 7.901***
− 7.928***
− 7.914***
(3.95)
(3.94)
(3.73)
(3.93)
(8.23)
(8.25)
(8.12)
(8.23)
(3.90)
(3.91)
(3.83)
(3.80)
(− 31.14)
(− 31.16)
(− 31.17)
(− 31.21)
(− 30.76)
(− 30.75)
(− 30.81)
(− 30.80)
(− 18.61)
(− 18.61)
(− 18.65)
(− 18.62)
Population (millions)
− 0.987
− 0.961
− 0.890
− 0.975
1.733**
1.696**
1.750**
1.706**
1.296
1.217
1.340
1.259
− 1.377***
− 1.379***
− 1.368***
− 1.373***
− 2.669***
− 2.671***
− 2.649***
− 2.666***
− 1.270***
− 1.270***
− 1.258***
− 1.270***
(− 1.13)
(− 1.10)
(− 1.02)
(− 1.12)
(2.23)
(2.18)
(2.25)
(2.19)
(0.48)
(0.46)
(0.50)
(0.47)
(− 7.88)
(− 7.90)
(− 7.83)
(− 7.87)
(− 6.73)
(− 6.74)
(− 6.68)
(− 6.73)
(− 3.51)
(− 3.51)
(− 3.48)
(− 3.51)
Primary share of GDP (%)
− 0.0672*
− 0.0647*
− 0.0648*
− 0.0662*
0.120***
0.117***
0.119***
0.118***
0.721***
0.714***
0.720***
0.722***
− 0.0778***
− 0.0782***
− 0.0775***
− 0.0774***
− 0.166***
− 0.166***
− 0.165***
− 0.165***
− 0.0896***
− 0.0896***
− 0.0894***
− 0.0894***
(− 1.85)
(− 1.78)
(− 1.78)
(− 1.82)
(3.70)
(3.60)
(3.67)
(3.64)
(6.46)
(6.40)
(6.46)
(6.48)
(− 10.25)
(− 10.31)
(− 10.22)
(− 10.21)
(− 9.60)
(− 9.62)
(− 9.58)
(− 9.57)
(− 5.70)
(− 5.70)
(− 5.69)
(− 5.69)
Tertiary share of GDP (%)
0.153***
0.150***
0.150***
0.152***
− 0.119***
− 0.116***
− 0.118***
− 0.117***
− 0.106
− 0.098
– 0.105
− 0.105
0.0942***
0.0945***
0.0938***
0.0939***
0.126***
0.126***
0.125***
0.126***
0.0329**
0.0329**
0.0325**
0.0328**
(4.30)
(4.23)
(4.23)
(4.28)
(− 3.76)
(− 3.65)
(− 3.73)
(− 3.69)
(− 0.97)
(− 0.90)
(− 0.96)
(− 0.96)
(12.87)
(12.94)
(12.83)
(12.85)
(7.56)
(7.59)
(7.53)
(7.55)
(2.17)
(2.17)
(2.15)
(2.17)
FDI (million USD)
0.00766***
0.00781***
0.00775***
0.00773***
− 0.00254***
− 0.00274***
− 0.00265***
− 0.00266***
− 0.0122***
− 0.0127***
− 0.0124***
− 0.0120***
0.00201***
0.00198***
0.00203***
0.00204***
0.000235
0.000207
0.000263
0.000284
− 0.00173***
− 0.00173***
− 0.00172***
− 0.00172***
(8.93)
(9.13)
(9.13)
(9.06)
(− 3.33)
(− 3.59)
(− 3.50)
(− 3.50)
(− 4.65)
(− 4.83)
(− 4.74)
(− 4.60)
(11.48)
(11.36)
(11.70)
(11.76)
(0.59)
(0.52)
(0.67)
(0.72)
(− 4.78)
(− 4.79)
(− 4.79)
(− 4.77)
Constant
− 25.18**
− 25.09**
− 23.70**
− 25.12**
− 71.64***
− 71.73***
− 70.93***
− 71.64***
− 108.3***
− 108.5***
− 106.9***
− 106.9***
77.58***
77.52***
77.65***
77.63***
176.7***
176.6***
176.9***
176.8***
99.29***
99.29***
99.46***
99.34***
(− 2.14)
(− 2.13)
(− 2.02)
(− 2.13)
(− 6.83)
(− 6.84)
(− 6.76)
(− 6.82)
(− 3.00)
(− 3.01)
(− 2.96)
(− 2.97)
(31.75)
(31.75)
(31.77)
(31.79)
(31.91)
(31.91)
(31.96)
(31.94)
(19.62)
(19.62)
(19.65)
(19.63)
Observations
3410
3410
3410
3410
3410
3410
3410
3410
3410
3410
3410
3410
2909
2909
2909
2909
2952
2952
2952
2952
2909
2909
2909
2909
All regressions include year and city fixed effects. t statistics in parentheses. *p < 0.10; **p < 0.05; ***p < 0.01
Although age does not appear to be a decisive factor, other underlying individual characteristics may explain both concurrent appointments and the city outcomes we observe. Perhaps high-performing leaders are selected for concurrent appointments and then continue producing the results they achieved in previous posts. Or perhaps cadres with ties to powerful party factions or well-placed patrons obtain concurrent appointments, and the outcomes we observe are driven by these political connections. The fact that we observe concurrent appointees with a range of career backgrounds and promotion trajectories seems inconsistent with the idea that either previous high achievement or factional alignment is the main factor driving both PPSC appointments and observed city outcomes.11 But we can begin to assess these possibilities more systematically by analyzing the effect of concurrent appointments for officials who already hold their city leadership posts when they are concurrently appointed to PPSCs. To do so, we track the background of the 69 leaders of non-capital, non-deputy-provincial cities and find that 20 of them (almost 30%) already led their respective cities prior to PPSC elevation, serving nearly 2 years on average. By analyzing the outcomes of these individuals before their PPSC appointment, we can control for individual characteristics—either factional ties or innate ability—while analyzing the effects of institutional arrangements.12 To check the city-level impacts of these leaders prior to PPSC elevation, we repeat our baseline regression and also include a “pre-PPSC” dummy to check whether the main results hold when controlling for previous city appointment, and also whether the same results hold for these individuals prior to elevation. Table 12 demonstrates that the main results continue to hold for the concurrent appointment dummy, but no results are significant for the pre-PPSC dummy (and some have opposite signs), implying that these individuals on the whole are not exceptional prior to their PPSC elevation. This provides further support for our institutional interpretation, though the small sample limits the power of this analysis.13
Table 12
Baseline results controlling for pre-PPSC city appointments
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
News frequency
GDP growth
FAI growth
Revenue share of GDP
Expenditure share of GDP
Fiscal gap share of GDP
Pre-PPSC city appointment
− 0.844 (− 0.48)
− 0.611 (− 0.39)
7.642 (1.41)
0.532 (1.34)
0.769 (0.85)
0.323 (0.39)
Concurrent PPSC appointment
1.515 (1.21)
2.336** (2.09)
9.949*** (2.59)
0.798*** (3.04)
1.220** (2.05)
0.501 (0.92)
Log GDP per capita (1000 RMB)
3.796*** (3.89)
7.105*** (8.17)
11.43*** (3.82)
− 6.405*** (− 31.28)
− 14.28*** (− 30.82)
− 7.913*** (− 18.63)
Population (millions)
− 0.967 (− 1.11)
1.721** (2.21)
1.351 (0.51)
− 1.363*** (− 7.82)
− 2.651*** (− 6.69)
− 1.264*** (− 3.49)
Primary share of GDP (%)
− 0.0678* (− 1.86)
0.116*** (3.57)
0.710*** (6.37)
− 0.0783*** (− 10.33)
− 0.167*** (− 9.65)
− 0.0900*** (− 5.73)
Tertiary share of GDP (%)
0.153*** (4.32)
− 0.115*** (− 3.63)
− 0.0958 (− 0.88)
0.0944*** (12.93)
0.126*** (7.60)
0.0332** (2.19)
FDI (million USD)
0.00760*** (8.90)
− 0.00283*** (− 3.71)
− 0.0129*** (− 4.92)
0.00199*** (11.44)
0.000189 (0.48)
− 0.00175***(− 4.87)
Constant
− 24.86** (− 2.11)
− 71.26 (− 6.79)
− 107.2*** (− 2.97)
77.65*** (31.83)
176.8*** (31.95)
99.34*** (19.63)
Observations
3410
3410
3410
2909
2952
2909
All regressions include year and province fixed effects, with standard errors clustered by prefecture. t statistics in parentheses. *p < 0.10; **p < 0.05; ***p < 0.01
In sum, although we cannot entirely rule out the possibility that unobserved individual characteristics drive our results, the evidence we have presented suggests that the institutional arrangements that come with concurrent appointments are themselves important. Future research, drawing on larger datasets, may be able to further tease apart the effects of institutions and individuals. But it is worth noting that even if the observed effects of concurrent appointments are a function of installing leaders who are more talented, powerful, or incentivized powerful than average leaders, this would remain consistent with the paper’s larger argument that concurrent appointments empower rather than constrain cities.
Footnotes
1
All of China’s provincial-level units are represented in the Central Committee of the Communist Party, but the Central Committee is not a standing leadership body with real control over personnel and policy decisions.
 
2
Because the leaders of such cities are typically deputy-provincial cadres by default, concurrent appointment to PPSCs does not require a change of rank.
 
3
Since 2005, the Chinese government has actively promoted tourism in revolutionary base areas. As discussed in the appendix, we code 13 cities as “red” based on official “red tourism” status. Although we use red tourism status as a proxy for political importance, we do not see tourism itself as what makes these cities important.
 
4
This assumes that the error is not correlated with any of the independent variables, which we think is a valid assumption based on the data validation exercise.
 
5
Correlations between revenue as a share of GDP, GDP levels, per capita GDP levels, and GDP growth are all very weak, indicating the importance of extraction effort in determining this variable, rather than just increases in economic output.
 
6
These cities have concurrent leadership appointments as a rule, and thus offer no variation over time.
 
7
This approach also controls for the possibility that the included control variables have disparate effects in different city types.
 
8
Note that although we use red tourism as a proxy for political importance, we do not see tourism itself as important. Indeed, most red cities are not among China’s top tourism destinations, and if we substitute a generic tourism proxy into our regressions instead of red city status, the effect on news frequency is significantly negative.
 
9
We thank an anonymous reviewer for raising this concern. Theoretically, however, it is also possible that while many leaders hope to distinguish themselves through achievements on the job and thereby improve their chances of promotion, many are not prepared to accept the political risks that accompany high-profile gambits. Young leaders on the fast-track might have less incentive than others to innovate if they are already advancing through the ranks.
 
10
Biographical data for all prefecture-level leaders over this time period, including 1567 unique prefecture-level leaders, comes from Blum, Jurgen, David Bulman, Xun Yan, and Qiong Zhang. 2018. “Political Incentives, Firm Support, and Productivity: Evidence from Chinese Cities.” Working Paper.
 
11
Based on a preliminary analysis using the case-study localities, we find a range of career backgrounds and promotion trajectories for concurrently appointed city leaders. Although some concurrent appointees, such as Pan Yiyang and Li Jia, have career backgrounds in the Communist Youth League (regarded by some analysts as the base of a large elite political faction), most city-level leaders have no readily discernable factional alignment. Although future work may be able to systematically examine how the factional positioning of city-level leaders affect city performance, data limitations and underdeveloped theory on subnational factionalism make this task difficult. Meanwhile, concurrent appointees in the case-study cities have widely varying career trajectories. Some leaders, such as Shi Wenqing, have risen slowly and steadily through the ranks, while other leaders, such as Fan Ruiping, have progressed more quickly to higher official posts. Some, like Ren Zhenhe, have worked in a single province their whole career; others, like Wang Junzheng, have rotated across provincial lines (China Vitae; Baidu Baike).
 
12
Factional ties and innate ability may be indistinguishable as either would be expected to produce the identified city outcomes for the leaders in question prior to PPSC elevation. In other words, if leaders out-performed in their previous posts, this could be due to either patronage or ability—either way, it might imply that individual characteristics are more important than institutional arrangements if these effects persist when these individuals are concurrently appointed to PPSCs.
 
13
The small sample also makes difficult a simple dummy variable approach, whereby one could analyze the sample of cities with leaders who rise to the PPSC while in office and regress outcomes on the treatment dummy (PPSC appointment) while controlling for city and year fixed effects. Using our small sample we find no significant results.
 
Literature
go back to reference 21 shiji jingji baodao (21 世纪经济报道). 湖北三市‘一把手’高配 (Three Hubei Cities’ Top Leaders Are Concurrently Appointed at Higher Level). 2012. July 13. www.cnki.com.cn. 21 shiji jingji baodao (21 世纪经济报道). 湖北三市‘一把手’高配 (Three Hubei Cities’ Top Leaders Are Concurrently Appointed at Higher Level). 2012. July 13. www.​cnki.​com.​cn.
go back to reference 21 shiji jingji baodao (21 世纪经济报道). 湖北区域协调策:副省级官员主政襄阳宜昌 (Hubei Regional Coordination Strategy: Deputy-Provincial-Level Officials Take Charge of Xiangyang, Yichang). 2013. May 17. www.cnki.com.cn. 21 shiji jingji baodao (21 世纪经济报道). 湖北区域协调策:副省级官员主政襄阳宜昌 (Hubei Regional Coordination Strategy: Deputy-Provincial-Level Officials Take Charge of Xiangyang, Yichang). 2013. May 17. www.​cnki.​com.​cn.
go back to reference Berry CR, Fowler A. Cardinals or clerics? Congressional committees and the distribution of pork. Am J Polit Sci. 2016;60(3):692–708.CrossRef Berry CR, Fowler A. Cardinals or clerics? Congressional committees and the distribution of pork. Am J Polit Sci. 2016;60(3):692–708.CrossRef
go back to reference Bulman DJ. Incentivized development in China: leaders, governance, and growth in China’s counties. In: Cambridge. New York: Cambridge University Press; 2016. Bulman DJ. Incentivized development in China: leaders, governance, and growth in China’s counties. In: Cambridge. New York: Cambridge University Press; 2016.
go back to reference Bulman DJ, Jaros K. Loyalists, Localists, and Legibility: The Calibrated Control of China’s Provincial Leadership Teams. 2018. Working Paper. Bulman DJ, Jaros K. Loyalists, Localists, and Legibility: The Calibrated Control of China’s Provincial Leadership Teams. 2018. Working Paper.
go back to reference Carsey TM, Rundquist B. Party and Committee in Distributive Politics: evidence from defense spending. The Journal of Politics. 1999;61(4):1156–69.CrossRef Carsey TM, Rundquist B. Party and Committee in Distributive Politics: evidence from defense spending. The Journal of Politics. 1999;61(4):1156–69.CrossRef
go back to reference Chung JH. China’s local governance in perspective: instruments of central control. China J. 2016;75:38–60.CrossRef Chung JH. China’s local governance in perspective: instruments of central control. China J. 2016;75:38–60.CrossRef
go back to reference Diyi caijing ribao (第一财经日报). 省级常委兼任 54 城市‘一把手’ (Provincial Party Standing Committee Members Concurrently Appointed as 54 Cities ‘First in Command’). 2014. June 30. www.cnki.com.cn Diyi caijing ribao (第一财经日报). 省级常委兼任 54 城市‘一把手’ (Provincial Party Standing Committee Members Concurrently Appointed as 54 Cities ‘First in Command’). 2014. June 30. www.​cnki.​com.​cn
go back to reference Falleti T. A sequential theory of decentralization: Latin American cases in comparative perspective. Am Polit Sci Rev. 2005;99(3):327–46.CrossRef Falleti T. A sequential theory of decentralization: Latin American cases in comparative perspective. Am Polit Sci Rev. 2005;99(3):327–46.CrossRef
go back to reference Heilmann S. From local experiments to National Policy: the origins of China’s distinctive policy process. China J. 2008;59:1–30.CrossRef Heilmann S. From local experiments to National Policy: the origins of China’s distinctive policy process. China J. 2008;59:1–30.CrossRef
go back to reference Heilmann S, Perry EJ. Embracing uncertainty: guerrilla policy style and adaptive governance in China. In: Heilmann, Perry, editors. Mao’s invisible hand: the political foundations of adaptive governance in China. Cambridge: Harvard University Asia Center; 2011. p. 1–29. Heilmann S, Perry EJ. Embracing uncertainty: guerrilla policy style and adaptive governance in China. In: Heilmann, Perry, editors. Mao’s invisible hand: the political foundations of adaptive governance in China. Cambridge: Harvard University Asia Center; 2011. p. 1–29.
go back to reference Helmke G, Levitsky S. Informal institutions and comparative politics: a research agenda. Perspect Polit. 2004;2(4):725–40.CrossRef Helmke G, Levitsky S. Informal institutions and comparative politics: a research agenda. Perspect Polit. 2004;2(4):725–40.CrossRef
go back to reference Hooghe L, Marks G. Beyond federalism: estimating and explaining the territorial structure of government. Publius: J Federalism. 2013;43(2):179–204.CrossRef Hooghe L, Marks G. Beyond federalism: estimating and explaining the territorial structure of government. Publius: J Federalism. 2013;43(2):179–204.CrossRef
go back to reference Huang Y. Inflation and investment controls in China : the political economy of central-local relations during the reform era. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 1996. Huang Y. Inflation and investment controls in China : the political economy of central-local relations during the reform era. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 1996.
go back to reference Huang Y, Sheng Y. Political decentralization and inflation: sub-National Evidence from China. Br J Polit Sci. 2009;39(2):389–412.CrossRef Huang Y, Sheng Y. Political decentralization and inflation: sub-National Evidence from China. Br J Polit Sci. 2009;39(2):389–412.CrossRef
go back to reference Hutchcroft PD. Centralization and decentralization in administration and politics: assessing territorial dimensions of authority and power. Governance. 2001;14(1):23–53.CrossRef Hutchcroft PD. Centralization and decentralization in administration and politics: assessing territorial dimensions of authority and power. Governance. 2001;14(1):23–53.CrossRef
go back to reference Interview NC011501b. Author’s interview conducted in Nanchang, Jiangxi; 2015. Interview NC011501b. Author’s interview conducted in Nanchang, Jiangxi; 2015.
go back to reference Jaros KA. China’s urban champions: the politics of spatial development. Princeton: Princeton University Press; 2019. Jaros KA. China’s urban champions: the politics of spatial development. Princeton: Princeton University Press; 2019.
go back to reference Jingji ribao (经济日报). Unlock the ‘Magic Cube’ of Marketized Infrastructure Operation (寻找基础设施市场化运作的 ‘魔方’)’. 2002. September 13. www.cnki.com.cn. Jingji ribao (经济日报). Unlock the ‘Magic Cube’ of Marketized Infrastructure Operation (寻找基础设施市场化运作的 ‘魔方’)’. 2002. September 13. www.​cnki.​com.​cn.
go back to reference Lam T-c. Institutional constraints, leadership, and development strategies: Panyu and Nanhai under reform. In: Chung, editor. Cities in post-Mao China: recipes of economic development in the reform era. London: Routledge; 1999. p. 256–95. Lam T-c. Institutional constraints, leadership, and development strategies: Panyu and Nanhai under reform. In: Chung, editor. Cities in post-Mao China: recipes of economic development in the reform era. London: Routledge; 1999. p. 256–95.
go back to reference Lam T-c. Central-provincial relations amid greater centralization in China. China Information. 2010;24:339–63.CrossRef Lam T-c. Central-provincial relations amid greater centralization in China. China Information. 2010;24:339–63.CrossRef
go back to reference Landry PF. Decentralized authoritarianism in China: the Communist Party’s control of local elites in the post-Mao era. New York: Cambridge University Press; 2008.CrossRef Landry PF. Decentralized authoritarianism in China: the Communist Party’s control of local elites in the post-Mao era. New York: Cambridge University Press; 2008.CrossRef
go back to reference Landry PF, Lv X, Duan H. Does performance matter? Evaluating political selection along the Chinese administrative ladder. Comp Pol Stud. 2018;51(8):1074–105.CrossRef Landry PF, Lv X, Duan H. Does performance matter? Evaluating political selection along the Chinese administrative ladder. Comp Pol Stud. 2018;51(8):1074–105.CrossRef
go back to reference Lane D. State and politics in the USSR. Oxford: Basil Blackwell; 1985. Lane D. State and politics in the USSR. Oxford: Basil Blackwell; 1985.
go back to reference Lieberthal K, Oksenberg M. Policy making in China: leaders, structures, and processes. Princeton: Princeton University Press; 1988. Lieberthal K, Oksenberg M. Policy making in China: leaders, structures, and processes. Princeton: Princeton University Press; 1988.
go back to reference Li C. The leadership of China’s four major cities: a study of municipal party standing committees. China Leadership Monitor. 2007; 31. www.hoover.org. Li C. The leadership of China’s four major cities: a study of municipal party standing committees. China Leadership Monitor. 2007; 31. www.​hoover.​org.
go back to reference Li C. Chinese Leadership in the Xi Jinping Era: Reassessing Collective Leadership. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press; 2016. Li C. Chinese Leadership in the Xi Jinping Era: Reassessing Collective Leadership. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press; 2016.
go back to reference Li LC. Provincial discretion and national power: investment policy in Guangdong and Shanghai, 1978-93. China Q. 1997;152:778–804.CrossRef Li LC. Provincial discretion and national power: investment policy in Guangdong and Shanghai, 1978-93. China Q. 1997;152:778–804.CrossRef
go back to reference Looney K. The Rural Developmental State: Modernization Campaigns and Peasant Politics in China, Taiwan, and South Korea. Doctoral dissertation, Harvard University; 2012. Looney K. The Rural Developmental State: Modernization Campaigns and Peasant Politics in China, Taiwan, and South Korea. Doctoral dissertation, Harvard University; 2012.
go back to reference Looney K. China’s campaign to build a new socialist countryside: village modernization, peasant councils, and the Ganzhou model of rural development. China Q. 2015;224:909–32.CrossRef Looney K. China’s campaign to build a new socialist countryside: village modernization, peasant councils, and the Ganzhou model of rural development. China Q. 2015;224:909–32.CrossRef
go back to reference Ma X. Guardians and Gridlock: Bureaucracy, Bargaining, and Authoritarian Policymaking. Doctoral dissertation, Department of Political Science, University of Washington; 2017. Ma X. Guardians and Gridlock: Bureaucracy, Bargaining, and Authoritarian Policymaking. Doctoral dissertation, Department of Political Science, University of Washington; 2017.
go back to reference Malesky EJ. Straight ahead on red: how foreign direct investment empowers subnational leaders. J Polit. 2008;70(1):97–119.CrossRef Malesky EJ. Straight ahead on red: how foreign direct investment empowers subnational leaders. J Polit. 2008;70(1):97–119.CrossRef
go back to reference Nanfang ribao (南方日报). The Time Has Come for Zhuhai’s Development (珠海发展正当时 回国创业促腾飞). 2015. September 21. www.cnki.com.cn. Nanfang ribao (南方日报). The Time Has Come for Zhuhai’s Development (珠海发展正当时 回国创业促腾飞). 2015. September 21. www.​cnki.​com.​cn.
go back to reference Ngo T-W, Cunyi Y, Zhilin T. Scalar restructuring of the Chinese state: the subnational politics of development zones. Econ Plan C: Polit Space. 2017;35(1):57–75. Ngo T-W, Cunyi Y, Zhilin T. Scalar restructuring of the Chinese state: the subnational politics of development zones. Econ Plan C: Polit Space. 2017;35(1):57–75.
go back to reference Sheng Y. Authoritarian co-optation, the territorial dimension: provincial political representation in post-Mao China.(report). Stud Comp Int Dev (SCID). 2009;44(1):71–93.CrossRef Sheng Y. Authoritarian co-optation, the territorial dimension: provincial political representation in post-Mao China.(report). Stud Comp Int Dev (SCID). 2009;44(1):71–93.CrossRef
go back to reference Sheng Y. Economic openness and territorial politics in China. New York: Cambridge University Press; 2010.CrossRef Sheng Y. Economic openness and territorial politics in China. New York: Cambridge University Press; 2010.CrossRef
go back to reference Shih VC. Factions and finance in China: elite conflict and inflation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2008. Shih VC. Factions and finance in China: elite conflict and inflation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2008.
go back to reference Shi Y. The impact of urban administrative institution reforms and division adjustments on urbanization in China. In: Challenges in the Process of China’s Urbanization, 75–90. Stanford: Shorenstein Asia-Pacific Research Center Books; 2017. Shi Y. The impact of urban administrative institution reforms and division adjustments on urbanization in China. In: Challenges in the Process of China’s Urbanization, 75–90. Stanford: Shorenstein Asia-Pacific Research Center Books; 2017.
go back to reference Shirk SL. The political logic of economic reform in China. Berkeley: University of California Press; 1993. Shirk SL. The political logic of economic reform in China. Berkeley: University of California Press; 1993.
go back to reference Tan, Qingshan. China’s Provincial Party Secretaries. EAI Background Brief, No. 195–196. Singapore: East Asian Institute, National University of Singapore; 2004. Tan, Qingshan. China’s Provincial Party Secretaries. EAI Background Brief, No. 195–196. Singapore: East Asian Institute, National University of Singapore; 2004.
go back to reference Tarrow S. Introduction. In: Territorial Politics in Industrial Nations, 1–27. New York: Praeger Publishers; 1978. Tarrow S. Introduction. In: Territorial Politics in Industrial Nations, 1–27. New York: Praeger Publishers; 1978.
go back to reference Truex R. Making autocracy work: representation and responsiveness in modern China. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2016.CrossRef Truex R. Making autocracy work: representation and responsiveness in modern China. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2016.CrossRef
go back to reference Wang Y, Minzner C. The rise of the Chinese security state. China Q. 2015;222:339–59.CrossRef Wang Y, Minzner C. The rise of the Chinese security state. China Q. 2015;222:339–59.CrossRef
go back to reference Xu, Jiang, and Anthony G. O. Yeh. “Interjurisdictional Cooperation through Bargaining: The Case of the Guangzhou–Zhuhai Railway in the Pearl River Delta, China. 2013; 213: 130–51. Xu, Jiang, and Anthony G. O. Yeh. “Interjurisdictional Cooperation through Bargaining: The Case of the Guangzhou–Zhuhai Railway in the Pearl River Delta, China. 2013; 213: 130–51.
go back to reference Zheng Y. De facto federalism in China : reforms and dynamics of central-local relations. Hackensack: World Scientific; 2007.CrossRef Zheng Y. De facto federalism in China : reforms and dynamics of central-local relations. Hackensack: World Scientific; 2007.CrossRef
go back to reference Zhongguo haiyang bao (中国海洋报). Coastal city development should achieve an ecological economy Win-Win (沿海城市发展应实现生态经济双赢). 2014. September 5. www.cnki.com.cn. Zhongguo haiyang bao (中国海洋报). Coastal city development should achieve an ecological economy Win-Win (沿海城市发展应实现生态经济双赢). 2014. September 5. www.​cnki.​com.​cn.
go back to reference Zhongguo xinxi bao (中国信息报). Ganzhou uses its full strength to build a new economic strong city (赣州全力打造新经济强市). 2003. March 15. www.cnki.com.cn. Zhongguo xinxi bao (中国信息报). Ganzhou uses its full strength to build a new economic strong city (赣州全力打造新经济强市). 2003. March 15. www.​cnki.​com.​cn.
go back to reference Zhuhai tequ bao (珠海特区报). ‘Zhuhai will create a Chinese Yacht capital 珠海将打造中国游艇之都. 2013. June 17. www.cnki.com.cn. Zhuhai tequ bao (珠海特区报). ‘Zhuhai will create a Chinese Yacht capital 珠海将打造中国游艇之都. 2013. June 17. www.​cnki.​com.​cn.
go back to reference Zhuhai tequ bao (珠海特区报). Zhuhai will build a maritime economy ecological demonstration city (珠海将建海洋经济生态示范市). 2015. November 16. www.cnki.com.cn. Zhuhai tequ bao (珠海特区报). Zhuhai will build a maritime economy ecological demonstration city (珠海将建海洋经济生态示范市). 2015. November 16. www.​cnki.​com.​cn.
Metadata
Title
Leninism and Local Interests: How Cities in China Benefit from Concurrent Leadership Appointments
Authors
David J. Bulman
Kyle A. Jaros
Publication date
01-05-2019
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Studies in Comparative International Development / Issue 2/2019
Print ISSN: 0039-3606
Electronic ISSN: 1936-6167
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-019-09279-0

Other articles of this Issue 2/2019

Studies in Comparative International Development 2/2019 Go to the issue