Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Social Choice and Welfare 3/2022

Open Access 20-09-2021 | Original Paper

Lower and upper bound estimates of inequality of opportunity for emerging economies

Authors: Paul Hufe, Andreas Peichl, Daniel Weishaar

Published in: Social Choice and Welfare | Issue 3/2022

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
download
DOWNLOAD
print
PRINT
insite
SEARCH
loading …

Abstract

Equality of opportunity is an important normative ideal of distributive justice. In spite of its wide acceptance and economic relevance, standard estimation approaches suffer from data limitations that can lead to both downward and upward biased estimates of inequality of opportunity. These shortcomings may be particularly pronounced for emerging economies in which comprehensive household survey data of sufficient sample size is often unavailable. In this paper, we assess the extent of upward and downward bias in inequality of opportunity estimates for a set of twelve emerging economies. Our findings suggest strongly downward biased estimates of inequality of opportunity in these countries. To the contrary, there is little scope for upward bias. By bounding inequality of opportunity from above, we address recent critiques that worry about the prevalence of downward biased estimates and the ensuing possibility to downplay the normative significance of inequality.
Notes
We thank John E. Roemer (editor) and two anonymous referees for many insightful comments on earlier drafts. This paper benefited from discussions with Paolo Brunori, Daniel Mahler, and Valentin Lang. Furthermore, we are grateful to seminar and conference audiences in Canazei, Luxembourg and Munich. We gratefully acknowledge funding from Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft (DFG) through NORFACE project “IMCHILD: The impact of childhood circumstances on individual outcomes over the life-course” (PE 1675/5-1).

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

1 Introduction

Equality of opportunity (EOp) is an ideal of distributive justice that garners wide-spread public support and is plausibly related to macro-economic indicators of development (Marrero and Rodríguez 2013; Ferreira et al. 2018; Aiyar and Ebeke 2019; Cappelen et al. 2007; Alesina et al. 2018). However, limitations in the underlying data sources lead to both upward and downward biased estimates of inequality of opportunity (IOp). Both biases are potentially large in emerging countries where the data quality is arguably worse than in industrialized economies. However, it is not clear ex ante which of the two biases prevails and whether IOp estimates rather tend to be downward or upward biased. In this paper, we address this uncertainty by constructing lower bound (LB) and upper bound (UB) estimates of IOp for twelve emerging economies and compare them to estimates from the conventional approach.
EOp distinguishes ethically justifiable (fair) inequalities from unjustifiable (unfair) inequalities using the concepts of circumstances and effort.1 Circumstances are defined as all factors that are not under the control of the individual—for instance, the biological sex, the parental background and the birthplace. To the contrary, working hours and educational decisions are under the (partial) control of individuals and are therefore characterized as efforts. Opportunity egalitarians consider inequalities based on exogenous circumstances as unfair, while inequalities resulting from effort exertion are deemed fair sources of inequality (among others Cohen 1989; Arneson 1989).
This distinction is not only relevant from a normative perspective but provides important insights for the patterns and drivers of economic development (Marrero and Rodríguez 2013; Peragine et al. 2014; Ferreira et al. 2018; Neidhöfer et al. 2018). For instance, a leveled playing field fosters human capital accumulation by providing incentives for skill acquisition (Mejía and St-Pierre 2008). Furthermore, circumstance-based variation in life outcomes reflects horizontal inequality and segregation, both of which are important drivers of social tensions and conflict (Rohner 2011).
What we call the “standard approach” (S) towards IOp estimation in this paper, constructs a counterfactual distribution of life outcomes from a linear prediction using all circumstance information observable by the econometrician. In line with the opportunity-egalitarian doctrine, inequality in this counterfactual distribution is considered “unfair” since it only varies with immutable circumstance characteristics. Due to limitations in the underlying data sources, this conventional method can lead to both upward and downward biased empirical measurements of IOp. First, due to the partial observability of circumstances, standard IOp estimates tend to be downward biased (Balcázar 2015; Hufe et al. 2017). The downward bias may be particularly pronounced in countries that lack household surveys combining information on the outcome of interest with rich information on individual characteristics. Most emerging economies fall into this category. Second, if the ratio between the number of parameters to be estimated and the available degrees of freedom is large, the ensuing noise in the parameter estimates will artificially inflate the measured impact of observed circumstances on individual life outcomes (Brunori et al. 2019b). Emerging economies may again be particularly susceptible to such upward bias in standard IOp estimates since the sample sizes of available household surveys tend to be comparatively small. Ex ante it is unclear which of the two biases prevails for the group of emerging economies. As a consequence, policy makers that rely on standard estimates may over- or underestimate the true degree of IOp and enact policy measures without considering the uncertainty around such estimates (Kanbur and Wagstaff 2016).
In this paper, we address the uncertainty around empirical IOp estimates by drawing on longitudinal household surveys from twelve emerging economies which enable us to estimate both LB and UB measures of IOp. First, we calculate LB measures of IOp by estimating the impact of observable circumstances on incomes with a cross-validated lasso procedure. Assessing statistical models by out-of-sample cross-validation disciplines the process of model selection and therefore prevents overfitting the circumstance parameters to the estimation sample. As a consequence, the relevant circumstance parameters are estimated with less noise which in turn cushions upward biases in IOp measures.
Second, we leverage the panel dimension of the data to calculate UB estimates based on the individual fixed effect (FE) estimator proposed in Niehues and Peichl (2014). By their most common definition, circumstance characteristics are time-constant but partly unobservable by the econometrician. Individual FEs capture the full set of unobservable circumstances and therefore yield the maximum amount of outcome variation that can be explained by circumstances. However, individual FEs also capture time-constant effort variables and therefore may overstate the extent of unequal opportunities. Hence, they yield an upper bound of the true IOp estimate.
Our results can be summarized as follows. In emerging economies the standard approach of estimating inequality of opportunity produces results that closely align with the lower bound. In theory, the restricted data infrastructures of many emerging economies could lead to either upward biased (small sample sizes) or downward biased (little circumstance information) estimates. In practice, the latter concern clearly dominates the former in our sample. With respect to individual (equivalized household) incomes, the average difference between the standard estimate and the lower bound estimate is 5.7 (5.0) percentage points (pp). To the contrary, the average distance between the standard estimate and the upper bound estimate is 22.8 pp (28.5 pp).
These results from emerging economies contrast recent evidence for European countries. For example, Brunori et al. (2018) show for a set of European countries that standard estimates may be upward biased by up to 300%. This contrast emphasizes that the particularities of data environments are crucial for an assessment of the relative importance of upward and downward biases. Second, the large distance between the standard estimate and the upper bound estimate in emerging economies emphasizes the concern of providing misleading reference points to policymakers who could use downward-biased estimates of IOp to downplay the moral significance of inequality (Kanbur and Wagstaff 2016). In the absence of data innovations, providing reasonable bounds on inequality of opportunity may be the only way to address such concerns. Our paper is the first to conduct such a bounding exercise for a set of emerging economies with broad geographical coverage and thereby contributes to the growing literature on EOp in these countries.2
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. In Sect. 2 we formalize the EOp concept and outline the corresponding estimation strategies for its LB and UB measures. After introducing the data sources in Sect. 3, we present results and robustness analyses for both LB and UB estimates in Sect. 4. Section 5 concludes the paper.

2 Conceptual framework

Important life outcomes such as income and consumption are determined by an extensive vector of personal characteristics that can be subsumed by a binary classification into circumstances and efforts. Those characteristics that are completely beyond the realm of individual control are called circumstances. To the contrary, those characteristics that are at least partially controlled by individuals are called efforts. The more the distribution of outcomes depends on circumstances, the stronger the violation of the opportunity-egalitarian ideal and the higher the measure of inequality of opportunity.
Consider a finite population indexed by \(i\in \{1,\ldots ,N\}\).3 Each individual is characterized by the tuple \(\{y_{it}, \mathbf {C_i}, \mathbf {E_{it}}\}\). \(y_{it}\) constitutes the period-specific outcome of interest, \( \mathbf {C_i} \) the vector of time-invariant circumstances, and \(\mathbf {E_{it}}\) period-specific effort. Life outcomes are a function of circumstances and efforts4:
$$\begin{aligned} y_{it}=f(\mathbf {C_i},\mathbf {E_{it}}(\mathbf {C_i})). \end{aligned}$$
(1)
Note that we allow circumstances to have a direct and an indirect impact on the outcome of interest. For example, certain groups may be excluded from offices and positions based on outright discrimination (direct impact). However, such discrimination may also lead to adjustments in individual effort exertion since the imposed circumstance constraints alter the individual optimization calculus (indirect impact). Whether the correlation between circumstances and efforts contributes to the fair or the unfair part of inequality is widely debated (Jusot et al. 2013). In this paper we follow Roemer (1998) who proposes that outcome differences due to a correlation between circumstances and effort constitute a violation of EOp.5
The literature on EOp further distinguishes the ex-ante from the ex-post approach (Ramos and Van De Gaer 2016). While the ex-ante approach requires that there are no differences in life outcomes across circumstance types, the ex-post approach demands that individuals exerting the same effort enjoy the same level of advantage. In this paper we focus on the ex-ante approach. That is, we use \(\mathbf {C_i}\) to construct a partition of disjunct types \(\Pi =\{T_1,\ldots ,T_P\}\) such that all members of a type are homogeneous in circumstances. The average outcome of type k is denoted by \(\mu ^k_t\). EOp is achieved if type-means in period t are equalized across types, i.e. if \(\mu ^k_{t}=\mu ^l_{t}~\forall ~l,k~|~T_k,T_l\in \Pi \).
Computing inequality in a counterfactual distribution \(M_{t}=\left( \mu ^1_{1t},\ldots ,\mu ^k_{it},\ldots ,\mu ^P_{Nt}\right) \), in which each individual i of type k is assigned its corresponding type outcome \(\mu ^k_{t}\) yields a scalar measure of IOp. It decreases with Pigou-Dalton transfers between circumstance types but is invariant to such transfers within circumstance types. Inequality in the counterfactual distribution of type-means can thus be considered unfair as it only depends on disparities due to immutable circumstance characteristics.
Standard Estimation (S) The standard approach towards IOp measurement (Bourguignon et al. 2007; Ferreira and Gignoux 2011) constructs an estimate for the counterfactual distribution of type means in a two-step procedure. First, for the year of interest t we estimate:
$$\begin{aligned} \ln y_{it}=\alpha + {\varvec{\beta }} * \mathbf {C}_{{\mathbf{i}}} + \epsilon _{it}. \end{aligned}$$
(2)
Note that this specification accounts for both the direct and the indirect effect of circumstances since the correlation between \(\mathbf {C_i}\) and \(\mathbf {E_{it}}\) is implicitly captured by \(\varvec{\beta }\). Second, we use the vector of estimated parameters \(\varvec{\hat{\beta }}\) to parametrically construct an estimate for the distribution of type means \({\tilde{M}}^S_{t}=\left( {\tilde{\mu }}^S_{1t},\ldots ,{\tilde{\mu }}^S_{it},\ldots ,{\tilde{\mu }}^S_{Nt}\right) \)6:
$$\begin{aligned} {\tilde{\mu }}_{it}^{S} = \exp \bigg \{ \hat{\alpha } + \varvec{\hat{\beta }}*\mathbf {C_i} + \frac{\sigma ^2}{2} \bigg \}. \end{aligned}$$
(3)
Lower bound estimation (LB) Conceptually, Ferreira and Gignoux (2011) show that the outlined standard estimate of IOp is a LB of its true value if the circumstance vector \(\mathbf {C_i}\) contains only a subset of all relevant circumstances. Empirically, however, this lower bound measure may be upward biased due to sampling variance in the distribution of type means (Brunori et al. 2019b). With decreasing sample size and increasing size of the circumstance set, the available degrees of freedom to estimate \(\varvec{\beta }\) shrink. The ensuing noise in \(\varvec{\hat{\beta }}\) artificially inflates the variance in the distribution of estimated type means \({\tilde{M}}_{t}^{S}\), which in turn leads to upward biased lower bound measures of IOp.
The literature has proposed different methods to address the upward bias in IOp estimates. Using the European Union Survey on Income and Living Conditions (EU-SILC), Brunori et al. (2019b) select models by 5-fold cross validation. Thereby, the authors pre-specify a large variety of potential models which differ in circumstance characteristics and their interactions. After estimating these models on random folds of the data, the algorithm chooses the model which minimizes the average out of sample mean squared error.7 An alternative approach to model selection are conditional inference trees and forests (Brunori et al. 2018). The regression tree method recursively splits the data according to the circumstance variables which have the strongest association with the outcome of interest while regression forest provide average estimates over multiple regression trees applied to random subsets of the data.
In this work we calculate lower bound estimates based on two different cross-validated lasso estimations that select the relevant circumstances to maximize the out-of-sample prediction accuracy of the model. Lasso estimations have two advantages in comparison to previous methods. First, one does not have to pre-specify the models to be evaluated by cross-validation—the preferred method in Brunori et al. (2019b). Second, they are less computationally expensive than random forests—the preferred method in Brunori et al. (2018). In Fig. 4, we use EU-SILC data to validate the lasso methodology against the findings of Brunori et al. (2018, 2019b). Both lasso estimates align very closely with the alternative estimation procedures. The implied Pearson correlation coefficients are 0.90/0.87 in comparison to the findings of Brunori et al. (2019b), and 0.91/0.89 in comparison to the findings of Brunori et al. (2018). All correlation coefficients are not statistically different from one at the 5% significance level.
In both estimation approaches, we first estimate
$$\begin{aligned} \underset{\varvec{\beta }}{\mathrm {argmin}}\sum _{i}\underbrace{\left( \ln y_{it}-\alpha ^{lasso} - \sum _{j}\beta _j^{lasso} * C_{ij}\right) ^2}_{(1)} + \underbrace{\sum _{j}\lambda \left| \beta _j^{lasso}\right| }_{(2)}. \end{aligned}$$
(4)
Part (1) of Eq. 4 is a perfect mirror of the OLS algorithm used to estimate Eq. 2. Part (2) however introduces a penalization term that varies with the absolute value of the estimated coefficient \(\hat{\beta _j}^{lasso}\). The larger (smaller) the penalization term \(\lambda \), the more (less) parsimonious the model and the lower the variance (bias) in the predictions based on the parameter vector \(\hat{\varvec{\beta }}^{lasso}\). We choose the optimal parameterization of \(\lambda \) by means of 5-fold cross validation.8
The first lower bound estimate (LB1) uses the resulting vector \(\hat{\varvec{\beta }}^{lasso}\) to construct the counterfactual distribution \({\tilde{M}}_{t}^{LB1}=({\tilde{\mu }}^{LB 1}_{1t},\ldots ,{\tilde{\mu }}^{LB 1}_{it},\ldots ,{\tilde{\mu }}^{LB 1}_{Nt})\):
$$\begin{aligned} {\tilde{\mu }}_{it}^{LB 1} = \exp \bigg \{ \hat{\alpha }^{lasso} + \varvec{\hat{\beta }}^{lasso}*\mathbf {C_i} + \frac{\sigma ^2}{2} \bigg \}. \end{aligned}$$
(5)
The second lower bound estimate (LB2) implements a post-OLS lasso estimation (Hastie et al. 2013). We only retain the subset \(\mathbf {C^r}\subseteq {\mathbf {C}}\), i.e. those circumstances whose coefficients were not shrunk to zero in Eq. 4. Then, we estimate \(\hat{\varvec{\beta }}^{Post-lasso}\) by running an OLS regression on the restricted set of circumstances:
$$\begin{aligned} \ln y_{it}=\alpha ^{Post-lasso} + \varvec{\beta }^{Post-lasso} * \mathbf {C^r_i} + \epsilon _{it}. \end{aligned}$$
(6)
We use \(\hat{\varvec{\beta }}^{Post-lasso}\) to construct the counterfactual distribution \({\tilde{M}}_{t}^{LB2}=\left( {\tilde{\mu }}^{LB 2}_{1t},\ldots ,{\tilde{\mu }}^{LB 2}_{it},\ldots ,{\tilde{\mu }}^{LB 2}_{Nt}\right) \):
$$\begin{aligned} {\tilde{\mu }}_{it}^{LB2} = \exp \bigg \{ \hat{\alpha }^{Post-lasso} + \varvec{\hat{\beta }}^{Post-lasso}*\mathbf {C^r_i} + \frac{\sigma ^2}{2} \bigg \}. \end{aligned}$$
(7)
Note that LB1 and LB2 are just different estimates of the same parameter vector. The choice between these two estimation methods is not straightforward. On the one hand, Belloni and Chernozhukov (2013) argue that the post-lasso may have a superior prediction accuracy than the standard lasso approach. On the other hand, the methodological validation based on EU-SILC reveals that the standard lasso approach tends to align more closely with the results in Brunori et al. (2018, 2019b) (Fig. 4). In our empirical application, we refer to standard lasso as our baseline LB estimate. However, we show that our main conclusions are insensitive to this choice.9
Upper bound estimation (UB) Since S and LB are based on the subset of observable circumstances only, the resulting IOp estimates may be downward biased. Following Niehues and Peichl (2014) we therefore construct UBs of IOp using an individual fixed effects (FE) estimator. Assuming circumstances to be time-invariant, individual FEs capture the full set of \(\mathbf {C_i}\) even though not all circumstances are observable by the econometrician. A counterfactual distribution of type means constructed from individual FEs thus captures the upper ceiling of outcome variation that can be attributed to the impact of circumstances. In particular, the smoothed distribution of the UB is constructed as follows.
First, using observations from all periods \(v\ne t\), we estimate the individual FE \(c_i\) while accounting for common year-specific shocks \(u_v\):10
$$\begin{aligned} \text {ln }y_{iv}=c_i + u_v + \epsilon _{iv}. \end{aligned}$$
(8)
Second, we regress the individual outcome in period t on the estimated individual FE:
$$\begin{aligned} \text {ln } y_{it} = {\Psi }*{\hat{c}}_i + \epsilon _{it}. \end{aligned}$$
(9)
Third, we use the vector of parameters \(\hat{\Psi }\) to construct the counterfactual distribution \({\tilde{M}}_{t}^{UB}=\left( {\tilde{\mu }}^{UB}_{1t},\ldots ,{\tilde{\mu }}^{UB}_{it}, \ldots ,{\tilde{\mu }}^{UB}_{Nt}\right) \):
$$\begin{aligned} {\tilde{\mu }}_{it}^{UB} = \exp \bigg \{ \hat{\Psi }*{\hat{c}}_i + \frac{\sigma ^2}{2} \bigg \}. \end{aligned}$$
(10)
Note that this estimator would yield the true estimate of IOp if \(c_i\) captured time-invariant circumstances only. However, the individual FE may also absorb time-invariant effort exertion (e.g. long-term motivation, ambition) leading to an UB interpretation of this IOp estimate.
Inequality measurement We follow existing IOp literature and summarize the information in counterfactual distributions \({\tilde{M}}_{t}^{S}\), \({\tilde{M}}_{t}^{LB1}\), \({\tilde{M}}_{t}^{LB2}\), and \({\tilde{M}}_{t}^{UB}\) by the mean log deviation (MLD) and the Gini coefficient. The MLD is part of the generalized entropy class of inequality measures satisfying symmetry, the Pigou–Dalton transfer principle, scale invariance, population replication, as well as additive and path-independent subgroup decomposability (Shorrocks 1980; Foster and Shneyerov 2000). However, the MLD is very sensitive to low incomes many of which are smoothed out when constructing counterfactual distributions. Therefore, Brunori et al. (2019a) argue in favor of using the Gini index in spite of its imperfect subgroup decomposability.11 For both inequality measures, we provide relative measures of IOp that relate the MLD (Gini) of the counterfactual distributions \({\tilde{M}}_{t}^{S}\), \({\tilde{M}}_{t}^{LB1}\), \({\tilde{M}}_{t}^{LB2}\) and \({\tilde{M}}_{t}^{UB}\) to the actual outcome distribution \(Y_t\). The latter measures can be interpreted as the share of total inequality that is explained by circumstances and thus violates the opportunity-egalitarian ideal.

3 Data

We estimate IOp in income and consumption expenditure for twelve emerging economies in different geographical areas of the world ranging from Africa (Ethiopia, Malawi, South Africa, Tanzania), Central and South America (Argentina, Chile, Mexico, Peru), Europe and Central Asia (Russia), to East and South-East Asia (China, Indonesia, Thailand). The country selection is guided by the availability of household panel data with (1) information on relevant circumstance variables, and (2) a sufficient number of observations in the longitudinal dimension.12 Table 2 provides an overview of the underlying data sources.
We consider three outcomes of interest. First, we calculate IOp in individual income—before or after taxes and transfers depending on data availability. Second, we account for resource sharing at the household level and calculate IOp in equivalized household income. Accounting for resource sharing at the household level is particularly relevant in emerging economies since female participation in formal labor markets tends to be low (Cubas 2016). Third, to derive a more direct measure of IOp in material well-being, we also consider equivalized household consumption expenditures. Household income and consumption expenditure are deflated by the modified OECD equivalence scale.
Throughout the paper, we restrict ourselves to within-country comparisons. Table 2 documents many differences across the underlying data sources. These include differences in the reference period, the income and consumption expenditure aggregates, the detail of available circumstance characteristics, as well as the sampled populations. For example, while the data for Mexico avails net income information until 2004, the data for Thailand provides gross income figures until 2016. The Ethiopian panel provides a rather parsimonious set of circumstances for a rural fraction of the population, whereas the Russian panel provides a rich set of circumstances for a nationally representative sample of households. We therefore refrain from cross-country comparisons but focus our discussion on intra-country comparisons between the different estimation approaches.
To ensure the consistency of these intra-country comparisons, we only retain those units of observation for which we observe (1) all circumstance variables, and (2) positive outcomes in all available outcome dimensions for at least three periods of observation. We further restrict our samples to individuals aged 25–55.13
Table 1 displays relevant summary statistics for the estimation of S, LB, and UB by country.
Table 1
Circumstance Information by Country
 
Standard estimate (S) and lower bound (LB)
Upper bound (UB)
 
N
Circumstances
Parameter
N (FE)
Start
End
Min. Years
Avg. Years
Argentina
3019
Gender, year of birth, place of birth
8
6038
2013
2014
3
3.00
Chile
2808
Gender, year of birth, place of birth, education of father/mother, ethnicity, labor force status of father/mother, chronic disease
37
8424
2006
2008
4
4.00
China
243
Gender, year of birth, ethnicity, urbanity of birthplace
22
717
1988
2010
3
3.95
Ethiopia
660
Gender, year of birth, education of father/mother, ethnicity, religion
69
2433
1994
2004
3
4.69
Indonesia
786
Gender, year of birth, education of father/mother, ethnicity, religion, language
29
2036
1992
2006
3
3.59
Malawi
362
Gender, year of birth, education of father/mother, religion
16
995
2004
2008
3
3.67
Mexico
3050
Gender, year of birth, language
5
16,552
1999
2004
5
6.43
Peru
2193
Gender, year of birth, place of birth, language, chronic disease
37
5878
1998
2011
3
3.68
Russia
1181
Gender, year of birth, place of birth, urbanity of birthplace, education of father/mother, labor force status of father/mother, height
54
10,816
1994
2016
5
10.16
South Africa
670
Gender, year of birth, place of birth, education of father/mother, ethnicity
48
2331
2008
2015
4
4.48
Tanzania
221
Gender, year of birth, place of birth, ethnicity, religion
18
819
1991
2004
3
4.71
Thailand
465
Gender, year of birth, education of father/mother, wealth of parents, family plot size
15
6338
1997
2016
3
14.63
Source: Own calculations based on data described in Table 2
Column 2 displays the number of observations in the year of interest t. Column 3 lists country-specific circumstances used to estimate standard (S) and lower bound (LB) measures of inequality of opportunity. Column 4 shows the total number of parameters associated with country-specific circumstances. Columns 4-7 describe the longitudinal distribution of data points to estimate upper bound (UB) measures of inequality of opportunity. The displayed minimum and average number of years include the year of interest t plus years v that are used in the fixed effects estimation

4 Results

Figure 1 displays bounds of relative IOp, i.e. the percentage of total inequality that can be explained by exogenous circumstances.14 Standard estimates (S) indicate IOp based on all observable circumstances available in the particular country data set. Lower bound estimates (LB) also use the full set of observable circumstances but account for potential upward biases through lasso estimation in which irrelevant circumstance parameters are shrunk to zero.15 Upper bound estimates (UB) account for unobservable circumstances through the FE estimation procedure outlined in Sect. 2.
Individual income Panel (a) shows the results for individual income. The standard IOp estimate (S) for individual income ranges from 9.3% (Argentina) to 30.6% (Peru, South Africa). Accounting for sampling variation and the ensuing potential for upward biases in S provides only minor reductions in IOp. According to LB, between 6% (China) and 25.9% (Peru) of outcome inequality must be considered unfair. The average difference between S and LB estimates amounts to 5.7pp.16 When using the post-lasso OLS procedure, the average difference is even smaller and equals 0.5pp. These results suggest that the standard estimation approach (S) is largely uncompromised by overfitting circumstance parameters to the available data. Instead—and in line with the theoretical reasoning of Ferreira and Gignoux (2011)—the standard approach indeed recovers estimates close to the lower bound (LB) estimate in all countries under consideration. Note that this result stands in contrast to recent evidence for European countries suggesting that the standard approach overestimates lower bound IOp by up to 300% (Brunori et al. 2018, 2019b). This difference is reconciled by the quality of the underlying data sources. While the richness of the European data confers the opportunity to overfit the circumstance information to the data, the sparsity of circumstance information in the household surveys under consideration prevents upward biases in the standard estimate (S).
The lower bound estimator selects the circumstance parameters with the highest out-of-sample prediction accuracy. In Table 5, we show for each outcome of interest, which of the circumstance variables and categories are chosen by the lasso estimator in a particular country. Across all countries, gender plays a prominent role reflecting concerns about gender inequality in the context of emerging and developing economies (Jayachandran 2015). However, it is important to note that the selection of particular variables by lasso only indicate a predictive correlation and does not necessarily imply a causal relationship. For instance, even though both maternal and paternal education could causally affect the income of individuals, a high correlation between fathers’ and mothers’ education might lead the lasso to choose only one of the two circumstance characteristics.
While sparse circumstance information limits the scope for upward biases, it may lead to downward biases due to the neglection of circumstances that are unobserved by the econometrician. Therefore, we take account of unobservable circumstances by means of the fixed effect estimation outlined in Sect. 2. The UB estimates of IOp vary between 17.2% (Mexico) and 72.5% (South Africa). On average, UB exceeds S by 22.8pp. It therefore yields a significant upward correction of IOp in comparison to S and LB, respectively. The difference between UB and S is broadly comparable to the respective gap in developed economies (Niehues and Peichl 2014). As such, our results reflect recent concerns that downward biased IOp estimates based on observable circumstance characteristics provide misleading reference points as regards the normative significance of inequality (Kanbur and Wagstaff 2016).17
Household income Panel (b) of Fig. 1 displays analogous IOp estimates for equivalized household income. In contrast to the results on individual income, we thereby account for resource sharing at the household level and heterogeneity in household compositions. Estimates for S (LB) decrease for the vast majority of countries and now lie between 1.2% in Argentina (0%, China) and 35.9% in South Africa (24.7%, South Africa). This decrease follows from the assumption of resource sharing at the household level that largely nullifies gender-based differences in incomes. Hence, the average difference between S and LB remains at a very low level of 5.0pp. Again, using the alternative post-lasso OLS estimation strategy decreases this difference to 1.3 pp. To the contrary, the UB estimates are largely comparable to their individual income analogues. According to UB, IOp ranges between 8.6% (Mexico) and 73.9% (South Africa). As a consequence, the average difference between S and UB increases from 22.8 pp to a level of 28.5 pp when considering household instead of individual incomes. Our general conclusion, however, remains intact: In the context of the developing economies under consideration, the standard estimation approach recovers an estimate close to LB. However, its large distance to UB suggests severe underestimations due to the influence of unobservable circumstances.
Household expenditure In Panel (c), we show IOp estimates for equivalized household expenditure. There are different explanations for potential deviations of IOp in household expenditure and household income. First, if households smooth consumption its distribution is less unequal than the distribution of income. Additionally, assuming transitory fluctuations to be more strongly reflected in the outcome distribution \(Y_t\) than the smoothed distribution \({\tilde{M}}_t\), we would expect relative IOp in consumption expenditures to be higher than in income.18 In fact, this is the pattern observed by Ferreira and Gignoux (2011) when comparing IOp in income and consumption for five Latin-American countries. Second, even if households smooth consumption, expenditures for consumption items, especially durables, can be lumpy (Meyer and Sullivan 2017). This tendency is amplified by the fact that reference periods for expenditure reporting are oftentimes shorter (e.g. weekly, monthly, quarterly) in order to allow survey respondents to recall their expenditures in different categories. Again, assuming transitory fluctuations to be more strongly reflected in the outcome distribution \(Y_t\) than the smoothed distribution \({\tilde{M}}_t\), we would expect relative IOp in consumption expenditures to be lower than in income. Which of the two tendencies dominates is an empirical question and varies with the mode of data collection in the different countries. In our country sample the second channel tends to dominate. Compared to relative IOp in household income, IOp in household expenditure is on average 2.5 pp (S), 1.6 pp (LB), and 4.5 pp (UB) lower. However, there is heterogeneity across countries. According to the standard estimate, relative IOp for household expenditure is higher than IOp for income in Peru, South Africa, and Thailand. The reverse is true for China, Ethiopia, Indonesia, and Russia.
Estimates for S (LB) with respect to consumption expenditure lie between 6.3% in Tanzania (0%, China) and 40.3% in South Africa (29.5%, South Africa). According to UB, IOp ranges between 12.2% (Tanzania) and 67.6% (South Africa). As a consequence, the average difference between S and LB (UB) amounts to 5.9pp (20.2 pp). These findings support our conclusion that the standard estimation approach recovers an estimate close to LB.
Sensitivity analysis We conduct four sensitivity checks in which we probe the robustness of our conclusions to alternative specification choices.
MLD vs. Gini coefficient The majority of empirical IOp estimations draw on the MLD due to its path-independent decomposability property. In the context of IOp measurment, this property allows for a perfect decomposition into circumstance-based unfair inequality and effort-based fair inequality. However, as noted by Brunori et al. (2019a) the MLD’s senstivity to low income values leads to low relative measures of IOp.
Hence, we replicate our analysis based on the Gini coefficient and show the results in Fig. 2. Indeed, relative IOp based on the Gini is larger than suggested by the MLD. For individual incomes, the standard estimate on average increases by 30 pp and now lies between 34.1% (Argentina) and 68.1% (Peru). The corresponding UB on average increases by 26pp and ranges from 43.5% (Mexico) to 89.8% (South Africa). The LB on average increases by 27.8 pp and lies between 28.7% (China) and 62.3% (Peru). The pattern is very similar for equivalized household income and expenditure (see Table 3).
These results indicate that the attenuating effect implied by the tail sensitivity of the MLD largely outweighs the attenuating effect implied by the imperfect decomposability of the Gini coefficient. Furthermore, although using the Gini coefficient widens the gap between S and LB, the difference between UB and S is still larger for the majority of outcomes and countries in our sample. This observation confirms that independent of the inequality measure, the potential for downward biased IOp estimates is much larger than the potential to overestimate IOp in emerging economies.
Circumstance availability The differences between S and LB (UB) may vary with the size of the invoked circumstance set. To test the relevance of this concern in our sample, we re-estimate S and LB while restricting ourselves to a harmonized set of circumstances that is available in all countries under consideration. The internationally comparable circumstance set includes gender and year of birth. In Panel (a) of Fig. 3 we plot the difference between S and UB (LB) according to the harmonized circumstance specification (y-axis) against the analogous differences in our baseline estimates (x-axis). The closer data points align with the 45 degree line, the more similar the results between the baseline and the alternative specification.
Restricting the circumstance set mechanically attenuates S but leaves UB unaltered. It is therefore unsurprising that the difference between S and UB increases for all countries under consideration. The reverse holds true for the difference between S and LB. In fact, the restriction of the circumstance set leads to a zero difference between S and LB for the majority of the country cases. These results therefore confirm our main conclusion: The more parsimonious the circumstance set, the stronger the correspondence between S and LB and the higher the downward bias. Unfortunately, we cannot run the reverse test by increasing the number of circumstances. Therefore, we cannot provide a direct assessment of the precise conditions under which S and LB come adrift.
Number of periods The difference between S and UB may differ with the number of periods used to construct the individual FEs. In the baseline we set a minimum threshold for the number of periods used to calculate the fixed effect. However, in spite of implementing this minimum threshold the de facto number of observations used for the construction of the individual FEs is not bounded from above and therefore varies across countries (Table 1). To test the relevance of this concern, we construct UB estimates in which we restrict the sample to the three most recent observations for each individual in each country. In Panel (b) of Fig. 3 we plot the differences between S and UB according to this harmonized specification (y-axis) against the analogous differences according to our baseline estimates (x-axis). The closer data points align with the 45 degree line, the more similar the results between the baseline and the alternative specification.
We find that all data points with respect to the difference between S and UB closely align to the 45 degree line. This pattern suggest that even short panels deliver reliable indicators for UB inequality of opportunity. Note that the panel length impinges upon the UB estimate only. Therefore, all differences between S and LB remain unaffected by this harmonization.
Year of interest Our results may be sensitive to alternations in the time period of interest. In our baseline analysis we focus on the most recent available data years covering a range from 2009 to 2017. Therefore, we replicate our analysis for the country-specific wave in closest proximity to 2009.19 In Panel (c) of Fig. 3 we plot the differences between S and UB (LB) according to this harmonized specification (y-axis) against the analogous differences according to our baseline estimates (x-axis). The closer the data points align with the 45 degree line, the more similar the results between the baseline and the alternative specification.
Given that a society’s opportunity structure is shaped by long-run institutional features, one would expect these differences to be small. Indeed, we find that the data points for the difference between S and UB closely group around the 45 degree line. A similar conclusion holds for the difference between S and LB although the dispersion around the 45 degree line is somewhat larger.

5 Conclusion

Measures of IOp are of considerable policy relevance since they reflect widely-held principles of distributive justice and plausibly correlate with measures of economic development. In spite of their interest, point estimates of IOp are surrounded by severe uncertainty since they can be both upward and downward biased. Due to poorer data infrastructures with smaller sample sizes and less information on circumstance characteristics, IOp estimates in emerging economies may be particularly susceptible to both biases and it is unclear which of the two biases prevails.
We show that downward bias clearly dominates in the context of emerging economies. On the one hand, sparsely populated circumstance sets restrict the scope for overfitting circumstance information to the data. As a consequence, standard estimates of IOp strongly correspond to their lower bound analogues. This result stands in contrast to recent evidence from countries with richer data environments. On the other hand, the sparsity of observable circumstance information leads to large differences between standard estimates of IOp and their upper bound analogues. The extent of these differences is largely comparable to more developed countries and ranges between 20 pp and 30 pp.
While we provide reasonable bounds for IOp in these countries, substantial differences between lower and upper bound IOp remain. Our results therefore tie in with recent concerns that downward biased IOp estimates could misguide judgments on the normative significance of inequality. In the future, such gaps may be closed as better data sets become available. However, until such innovations materialize, bounding the range of potential estimates remains a viable way to limit the scope for downplaying the normative significance of inequality in the countries of interest.
Open AccessThis article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://​creativecommons.​org/​licenses/​by/​4.​0/​.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Appendix

Additional tables

See Tables 2, 3, 4, 5 and 6
Table 2
Data overview
Country
Country Abbr.
Panel period
Waves
Data
Source
Individual
Household
Sample weights available
Income
Income
Expenditure
Argentina
AG
2003–2015
12
Encuesta Permanente de Hogares
Instituto Nacional de Estadística y Censos (INDEC)
Net
Net
Yes
Chile
CL
2006–2009
4
Encuesta Panel CASEN
Ministerio de Desarrollo Social, Chile
Net
Net
Yes
China
CN
1988–2014
10
China Health and Nutrition Survey
Carolina Population Center at the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill and National Institute for Nutrition and Health (NINH) at the Chinese Center for Disease Control and Prevention (CCDC)
Net (Labor)
Net (Labor)
Yes
No
Ethiopia
EP
1994–2009
6
Ethiopia Rural Household Survey
International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI), Washington DC
Net
Net
Yes
No
Indonesia
ID
1992–2013
5
Indonesian Family Life Survey (IFLS)
RAND Social and Economic Well-Being
Net (Labor)
Net (Labor)
Yes
No
Malawi
MW
1998–2010
4
Malawi Longitudinal Study of Family and Health
Population Studies Center at the University of Pennsylvania and College of Medicine at the University of Malawi and Invest in Knowledge (IKI) in Zomba, Malawi
Yes
No
Mexico
MX
1999–2009
7
Encuesta Evaluation de los Hogares (ENCEL)
International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI), Washington DC
Net
Net
No
Peru
PR
1998–2011
14
Encuesta Nacional de Hogares, Condiciones de Vida y Pobreza
Instituto Nacional de Estadíística e Informatica
Gross
Gross
Yes
Yes
Russia
RSA
1994–2017
22
Russia Longitudinal Monitoring Survey (RLMS)
National Research University “Higher School of Economics”, OOO “Demoscope”, Carolina Population Center, University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill and the Institute of Sociology of the Federal Center of Theoretical and Applied Sociology of the Russian Academy of Sciences
Net (Labor)
Net (Labor)
Yes
Yes
South Africa
SAF
2008–2017
5
National Income Dynamics Study (NIDS)
Southern Africa Labour and Development Research Unit (SALDRU), University of Cape Town
Net (Labor)
Net (Labor)
Yes
Yes
Tanzania
TAZ
1991–2010
6
Kagera Health and Development Survey
Economic Development Initiatives
Yes
No
Thailand
THA
1997–2017
21
Townsend Thai Data
The Townsend Thai Project
Gross
Yes
No
Table 3
Absolute and relative inequality of opportunity, baseline specification
 
Country
Year
N
N (FE)
Parameters
Inequality
MLD, absolute
MLD, relative (%)
Gini, absolute
Gini, Relative (%)
P
\(P^S\)
\(N/P^S\)
\(P^{LB}\)
\(\lambda ^*\)
MLD
Gini
S
LB 1
LB 2
UB
S
LB 1
LB 2
UB
S
LB 1
LB 2
UB
S
LB 1
LB 2
UB
Individual Income
Argentina
2015
3019
6038
8
7
431.29
7
0.003
0.285
0.386
0.027
0.026
0.027
0.159
9.33
8.99
9.33
55.70
0.132
0.129
0.132
0.297
34.13
33.50
34.13
76.97
Chile
2009
2808
8424
37
26
108.00
16
0.015
0.395
0.430
0.078
0.064
0.078
0.190
19.79
16.24
19.74
48.16
0.220
0.200
0.220
0.319
51.25
46.58
51.17
74.36
China
2014
243
717
22
14
17.36
7
0.070
0.530
0.471
0.084
0.032
0.080
0.114
15.91
5.95
15.05
21.54
0.217
0.135
0.213
0.245
46.01
28.73
45.25
52.03
Ethiopia
2009
660
2433
69
33
20.00
12
0.056
0.873
0.622
0.214
0.143
0.201
0.262
24.54
16.42
23.04
29.97
0.349
0.286
0.331
0.371
56.08
45.95
53.33
59.64
Indonesia
2013
786
2036
29
20
39.30
9
0.036
0.533
0.478
0.096
0.064
0.093
0.238
18.04
12.04
17.41
44.65
0.249
0.204
0.244
0.345
52.07
42.75
51.13
72.20
Mexico
2009
3050
16552
5
4
762.50
4
0.001
0.186
0.311
0.025
0.025
0.025
0.032
13.42
13.28
13.42
17.18
0.110
0.109
0.110
0.135
35.33
35.09
35.33
43.54
Peru
2010
2193
5878
37
33
66.45
26
0.017
0.695
0.489
0.213
0.180
0.213
0.279
30.64
25.85
30.59
40.10
0.333
0.305
0.333
0.361
68.11
62.31
68.01
73.66
Russia
2017
1181
10816
54
46
25.67
14
0.033
0.234
0.358
0.049
0.027
0.046
0.137
20.85
11.47
19.52
58.27
0.177
0.132
0.171
0.287
49.52
36.89
47.84
80.30
South Africa
2017
670
2331
48
34
19.71
20
0.025
0.418
0.471
0.128
0.091
0.126
0.303
30.62
21.68
30.24
72.46
0.286
0.239
0.284
0.423
60.62
50.71
60.22
89.78
Household income
Argentina
2015
3019
6038
8
7
431.29
6
0.007
0.236
0.365
0.003
0.002
0.003
0.147
1.17
0.79
1.16
62.42
0.042
0.035
0.042
0.296
11.55
9.51
11.49
81.01
Chile
2009
2808
8424
37
26
108.00
18
0.009
0.261
0.385
0.038
0.031
0.038
0.133
14.45
12.03
14.41
50.88
0.154
0.140
0.153
0.285
39.88
36.42
39.83
74.11
China
2014
243
717
22
14
17.36
1
0.185
0.517
0.480
0.047
0.000
0.000
0.079
9.14
0.00
0.00
15.36
0.146
0.000
0.000
0.208
30.36
0.00
0.00
43.21
Ethiopia
2009
660
2433
69
33
20.00
13
0.050
0.953
0.640
0.250
0.178
0.240
0.308
26.26
18.73
25.14
32.36
0.370
0.316
0.355
0.401
57.92
49.43
55.56
62.67
Indonesia
2013
786
2036
29
20
39.30
12
0.022
0.482
0.473
0.117
0.092
0.116
0.226
24.23
19.08
24.09
47.00
0.273
0.243
0.272
0.346
57.61
51.32
57.48
73.24
Mexico
2009
3050
16552
5
4
762.50
4
0.000
0.198
0.331
0.006
0.006
0.006
0.017
3.07
3.03
3.07
8.56
0.062
0.061
0.062
0.102
18.59
18.46
18.59
30.81
Peru
2010
2193
5878
37
33
66.45
25
0.015
0.561
0.470
0.134
0.111
0.134
0.238
23.91
19.74
23.86
42.45
0.265
0.237
0.264
0.348
56.32
50.31
56.21
74.09
Russia
2017
1181
10816
54
46
25.67
11
0.031
0.194
0.330
0.019
0.006
0.015
0.105
10.02
3.12
7.96
54.10
0.112
0.063
0.100
0.251
33.85
19.00
30.27
75.96
South Africa
2017
670
2331
48
34
19.71
20
0.033
0.475
0.495
0.170
0.117
0.167
0.351
35.85
24.65
35.26
73.94
0.329
0.271
0.326
0.447
66.53
54.74
65.92
90.42
Thailand
2017
465
6338
15
12
38.75
5
0.034
0.289
0.419
0.021
0.011
0.021
0.154
7.43
3.94
7.32
53.22
0.113
0.083
0.112
0.311
27.05
19.75
26.62
74.12
Household expenditure
China
2014
243
717
22
14
17.36
1
0.255
1.427
0.766
0.091
0.000
0.000
0.270
6.38
0.00
0.00
18.95
0.222
0.000
0.000
0.387
28.96
0.00
0.00
50.50
Ethiopia
2009
660
2433
69
33
20.00
14
0.029
0.613
0.557
0.092
0.061
0.088
0.104
15.02
9.91
14.35
16.90
0.196
0.150
0.190
0.247
35.20
26.90
34.03
44.39
Indonesia
2013
786
2036
29
20
39.30
12
0.028
0.398
0.480
0.069
0.046
0.068
0.143
17.33
11.45
17.21
35.81
0.211
0.172
0.210
0.295
43.93
35.78
43.75
61.47
Malawi
2010
362
965
16
12
30.17
7
0.101
1.213
0.720
0.139
0.067
0.133
0.238
11.47
5.56
10.99
19.60
0.285
0.198
0.276
0.371
39.65
27.54
38.41
51.55
Peru
2010
2193
5878
37
33
66.45
27
0.007
0.187
0.331
0.045
0.038
0.045
0.106
24.13
20.43
24.12
56.88
0.166
0.151
0.166
0.254
49.96
45.62
49.94
76.75
Russia
2017
1181
10816
54
46
25.67
16
0.033
0.472
0.518
0.039
0.015
0.034
0.151
8.22
3.21
7.28
32.00
0.156
0.097
0.146
0.303
30.13
18.78
28.27
58.48
South Africa
2017
670
2331
48
34
19.71
21
0.030
0.503
0.531
0.203
0.148
0.200
0.340
40.26
29.46
39.66
67.57
0.357
0.303
0.354
0.452
67.18
57.11
66.69
85.01
Tanzania
2010
221
819
18
15
14.73
3
0.114
0.586
0.569
0.037
0.002
0.023
0.071
6.27
0.28
4.00
12.20
0.152
0.033
0.123
0.187
26.74
5.74
21.68
32.94
Thailand
2017
465
6338
15
12
38.75
4
0.065
0.764
0.620
0.063
0.029
0.057
0.451
8.19
3.80
7.51
58.98
0.194
0.130
0.183
0.501
31.29
21.01
29.51
80.87
Source: Own calculations based on the panel survey data described in Table 2
The table shows baseline IOp estimation results for individual income, household income, and household expenditure in terms of the MLD and the Gini coefficient. Column 2 shows year t for which IOp is estimated. Column 3 (4) display the number of observations in years v for the fixed effect estimation. Columns 5–9 provide information on the total number of circumstance categories (P), the number of estimated parameters under the standard approach (\(P^S\)), the ratio between number of observations and estimated parameters, the number of parameters selected by the lasso estimation (\(P^{LB}\)), and the selected value of lambda in the cross validation (\(\lambda ^*\)). Columns 10 and 11 display total inequality in terms of the MLD and the Gini coefficient. The remaining columns display baseline absolute and relative IOp measures. Standard estimates (S) use the full set of country-specific circumstances disclosed in Table 1. Lower bound (LB) estimates use the full set of country-specific circumstances disclosed in Table 1 but estimate the relevant parameters by means of a (post-OLS) lasso estimation to account for sampling variance. Upper bound (UB) estimates are based on predictions from individual fixed effects. LB 1 refers to the standard lasso. LB 2 refers to the post-OLS lasso
Table 4
Sample selection
Country
Outcome
Full sample
+Age 25–55
+Circumstance availability
+Outcome availability (Recent Year)
+Outcome availability (Longitudinal)
Argentina
Equiv. HH Income
N = 93,473
N = 37,190
N = 37,181
N = 31,577
N = 3019
ARP 73,704
ARP 80,235
ARP 80,240
ARP 83,832
ARP 78,103
Chile
Equiv. HH Income
N = 21,087
N = 8483
N = 6307
N = 4918
N = 2808
CLP 2,632,864
CLP 2,736,782
CLP 2,782,129
CLP 2,925,172
CLP 3,093,657
China
Equiv. HH Income
N = 10,434
N = 5579
N = 5047
N = 1118
N = 243
CNY 34,858
CNY 40,624
CNY 40,573
CNY 32,430
CNY 35,796
Ethiopia
Equiv. HH Income
N = 6982
N = 2117
N = 764
N = 742
N = 660
ETB 18,253
ETB 18,465
ETB 17,169
ETB 17,645
ETB 18,570
Indonesia
Equiv. HH Income
N = 31,035
N = 14,382
N = 5426
N = 3620
N = 786
IDR 13,231,805
IDR 14,516,044
IDR 18,097,790
IDR 20,517,590
IDR 26,036,236
Malawi
Equiv. HH Expenditure
N = 3,397
N = 2243
N = 440
N = 440
N = 362
MWK 23,053
MWK 24,301
MWK 27,512
MWK 27,512
MWK 30,052
Mexico
Equiv. HH Income
N = 30,789
N = 11,075
N = 9443
N = 6047
N = 3050
MXP 21,039
MXP 20,169
MXP 20,279
MXP 22,390
MXP 21,123
Peru
Equiv. HH Income
N = 71,758
N = 26,710
N = 26,095
N = 15,280
N = 2193
PEN 6189
PEN 7314
PEN 7375
PEN 9075
PEN 9013
Russia
Equiv. HH Income
N = 15,201
N = 7597
N = 1738
N = 1383
N = 1181
RUB 287,663
RUB 309,332
RUB 309,794
RUB 328,866
RUB 323,750
South Africa
Equiv. HH Income
N = 21,306
N = 8602
N = 3187
N = 2402
N = 670
ZAR 40,550
ZAR 49,357
ZAR 65,522
ZAR 74,904
ZAR 71,921
Tanzania
Equiv. HH Expenditure
N = 4289
N = 2681
N = 936
N = 936
N = 221
TZS 486,370
TZS 504,302
TZS 532,841
TZS 532,841
TZS 464,709
Thailand
Equiv. HH Income
N = 3649
N = 1439
N = 473
N = 473
N = 465
THB 156,869
THB 180,727
THB 150,957
THB 150,957
THB 150,089
Source: Own calculations based on the panel survey data described in Table 2
The table shows how the step-wise sample selection procedure changes the number of observations and the mean outcome variable denoted in local currency. The sequence is as follows: full sample (column 3), age restriction (column 4), full circumstance availability (column 5), observability of outcome variables in the year of interest (column 6), observability of outcome variables in longitudinal dimension (column 7)
Table 5
All (Lasso-Selected) parameter categories
Country
Parameters selected by lasso: Individual Income (), Household Income (), and Household Expenditure ()
Argentina
gender●◆, birthyear●◆, birthplace (current place of residence, different place than current residence●◆, other province●◆, neighboring country, other country●◆)
Chile
gender, birthyear●◆ , father education (no schooling●◆, primary, secondary●◆, tertiary●◆), mother education (no schooling●◆, primary, secondary●◆, tertiary●◆), birthplace (national, foreign), ethnicity (not member of any indigeneous population●◆, Aymara, Rapa Nui, Quechua, Mapuche, Atacameno●◆, Coya, Kawaskar, Yagan, Diaguita●◆), chronic disease●◆ (yes/no), labor force status of father (not working, employer, self-employed, employed, domestic worker, armed forces), labor force status of mother (not working, employer, self-employed, employed, domestic worker, armed forces)
China
gender, birthyear, ethnicity (Han, Mongolian, Hui, Tibetan, Vaguer, Miao, Yi, Zhuang, Buyi, Korean, Man, Dong, Yao, Tujia, other), birthplace urbanity (city, suburban, county capital city, village)
Ethiopia
gender, birthyear, father education (no schooling●◆, some nursery school, 1st grade, 2nd grade, 3rd grade, 4th grade, 5th grade, 6th grade, 7th grade, 8th grade, 9th grade, 10th grade, 11th grade, 12th grade, uncompleted non-university higher education, completed non university higher education, university education, adult literacy program, other literacy program, parochia education, koranic education, other), mother education (no schooling, some nursery school●◆, 1st grade, 2nd grade, 3rd grade, 4th grade, 5th grade, 6th grade, 7th grade, 8th grade, 9th grade, 10th grade, 11th grade, 12th grade, uncompleted non-university higher education, completed non university higher education, university education, adult literacy program, other literacy program, parochia education, koranic education, other), ethnicity (Amhara●▲, Oromo●◆▲, Tigrai●◆▲, Adere, Afar, Gurage●◆, Somali, other, Gedeo●◆▲, Gamo, Kembata, Wolaita●◆▲, Hadiya, Saho●◆▲), religion (None, Orthodox, Catholic, Muslim, Other Christian, Protestant, Traditional●◆▲, other)
Indonesia
gender◆▲, birthyear●◆▲, father education (no schooling, elementary schooling●◆▲, junior high, senior high●◆, junior college/college/university, other) mother education (no schooling, elementary schooling, junior high, senior high●◆▲, junior college/college/university, other), ethnicity (Jawa●◆▲, Sunda●◆, Bali●◆▲, Minang, Betawi, other), religion (Islam, Catholic◆▲, Protestant, Hindu, Buddha, Konghucu), foreign language●◆▲
Malawi
gender, birthyear, father education (no schooling, primary schooling, more than primary schooling, other), mother education (no schooling , primary schooling , more than primary schooling, other), religion (Catholic, Protestant , Revival, Moslem, Traditional, other)
Mexico
gender●◆ , birthyear●◆ , indigeneous●◆
Peru
gender●◆▲, birthyear●◆▲, birthplace (Amazonas●◆▲, Áncash●◆, Apurímac●◆, Arequipa●◆▲, Ayacucho●◆▲, Cajamarca●◆▲, Callao●◆▲, Cusco, Huancavelica●◆, Huánuco●◆▲, Ica●◆, Junín●▲, La Libertad●◆▲, Lambayeque●◆▲, Lima●◆▲, Loreto●◆▲, Madre de Dios●◆▲, Moquegua◆▲, Pasco, Piura●◆▲, Puno, San Martin, Tacna, Tumbes, Ucayali●▲, Other county), chronic disease●◆▲, language (Quechua●◆▲, Aymara, other native language●◆▲, Spanish●◆▲, foreign language, deaf-dumb●◆▲)
Russia
gender, birthyear, father education (without education/illiterate, elementary school/incomplete secondary school●▲, professional courses, vocational training without secondary education, vocational training with secondary education, secondary education, technical community college●▲, institute/university/academy◆▲, post-graduate course, academic degree), mother education (without education/illiterate, elementary school/incomplete secondary school●◆▲, professional courses, vocational training without secondary education, vocational training with secondary education, secondary education, technical community college, institute/university/academy●◆▲, post-graduate course, academic degree), birthplace (Russia, Ukraine, Belorussia●▲, Azerbaizhan, Kazakhstan, Uzbekistan, other country), father occupation (armed forces, legislators/senior officials/managers, professionals, technicians/associate professionals, clerks, service workers/shop market sales work, skilled agricultural and fishery worker, craft and related trade workers, plant and machine operators/assemblers, elementary occupations), mother occupation (armed forces●▲, legislators/senior officials/managers, professionals, technicians/associate professionals◆▲, clerks, service workers/shop market sales work, skilled agricultural and fishery worker, craft and related trade workers, plant and machine operators/assemblers, elementary occupations●◆), birthplace urbanity (city●◆▲, urban-type settlement, village/Derevnia/Kishlak/Aul●◆▲), height●◆
South Africa
gender● ◆▲, birthyear●◆▲ , father education (Grade R/0, Grade 1●◆▲, Grade 2, Grade 3●◆▲, Grade 4, Grade 5, Grade 6, Grade 7, Grade 8◆▲, Grade 9●◆, Grade 10◆▲, Grade 11●▲, Grade 12●◆▲, other, no schooling●◆▲, National Certificate Vocational 2, National Certificate Vocational 4, NTC 1, NTC 2, NTC 3), mother education (Grade R/0, Grade 1, Grade 2, Grade 3●◆, Grade 4, Grade 5●◆▲, Grade 6, Grade 7, Grade 8●◆▲, Grade 9, Grade 10●◆▲, Grade 11, Grade 12●◆▲, other, no schooling●◆▲, National Certificate Vocational 2, National Certificate Vocational 4, NTC 3), foreign birthplace, ethnicity (African, Coloured●◆, Asian/Indian●◆▲, White●◆▲, other)
Tanzania
gender, birthyear, birthplace (non-foreign/foreign), ethnicity (Mhaya, Mnyambo, Mhangaza, Msubi, Kishubi, Mzinza, other), religion (Musilim, Catholic, Protestant, Other Christian, Traditional, other)
Thailand
gender, birthyear, father education (no education, less than P4, P4, more than P4), mother education (no education◆▲, less than P4, P4, more than P4), wealth of parents (among the poorest households in the village, around the middle in terms of wealth◆▲, among the rich households in the village), land size of parents◆▲
Source: Own calculations based on data described in Table 1
The table shows the circumstance categories used to calculate standard estimates (S). Circumstance variables are denoted in boldface; their respective categories are listed in parentheses. Superscripts indicate variables chosen by the lasso procedure for the lower bounds (LB) of three different outcome variables: individual income (), household income (), household consumption expenditure ()
Table 6
Year of interest, baseline and harmonized
 
Year baseline
Year harmonized
Difference in years
Argentina
2015
2009
6
Chile
2009
2009
0
China
2014
2010
4
Ethiopia
2009
2009
0
Indonesia
2013
2006
7
Malawi
2010
2010
0
Mexico
2009
2009
0
Peru
2010
2009
1
Russia
2017
2009
8
South Africa
2017
2008
9
Tanzania
2010
2010
0
Thailand
2017
2009
8
Source: Own calculations based on data described in Table 2
The table shows the country-specific baseline year, the harmonized year, and their difference for the sensitivity check concerning the year of interest t. See Sect. 4 for details

Additional figures

See Fig. 4.

Existing studies

See Table 7.
Table 7
Overview existing studies
Country
Year
Study/source
Data source
Sample size
Sample restrictions
Circumstances
Outcome
Method
Index
Abs.
Rel. (%)
Argentina
2014
EqualChances.org
Encuesta Nacional sobre la Estructura Social
N.A.
Working age respondents
Education of Parents, Occupation of Parents, Origin (Race, Ethnic Origin, Area of Birth)
Equivalized Household Disposable Income
Parametric
Gini
0.159
41.99
Chile
2005
Ferreira et al. (2018)
Socio-Economic Database for Latin America and the Caribbean
N.A.
N.A.
Gender, Ethnicity, language, region of residence
Net Household Income
Parametric
MLD
0.460
5.30
Chile
2009
EqualChances.org
Encuesta de Caracterización Socioeconómica Nacional
N.A.
Working age respondents
Education of Parents, Occupation of Parents, Origin (Race, Ethnic Origin, Area of Birth)
Equivalized Household Disposable Income
Parametric
Gini
0.230
49.94
China
2010
Golley et al. (2019)
Survey of Women’s Social Status in China
15,974
Age 24-65
Gender, Education of Father, Occupation of Father, Hukou status at birth, Region, Age
Indididual Labor Earnings
Parametric
MLD
0.140
25.00
China
2010–2014
Song and Zhou (2019)
China Family Panel Studies
5,892
Households with children at school or positive education expenditures
Gender, Education of Father/Mother, Hukou Status at 3 years old
Individual Income
Parametric
Theil
0.069
21.70
China
1989-2006
Zhang and Eriksson (2010)
China Health and Nutrition Survey
1287
Age 20–50, parental background information through longitudinal matching available
Gender, Age, Birthplace, Education of Parents, Employment of Parents, Income of Parents
Individual Income
Parametric
Gini
N.A.
63.00
Ethiopia
2005
Ferreira et al. (2018)
Demographic and Health Survey
N.A.
N.A.
Region of birth, Religion, Mother tongue
Wealth Index
Parametric
Variance
6.160
7.70
Indonesia
2005
Ferreira et al. (2018)
Demographic and Health Survey
N.A.
N.A.
Religion
Wealth Index
Parametric
Variance
2.450
2.10
Malawi
2010–2011
Brunori et al. (2019a)
Third Integrated Household Survey
30,137
N.A.
Sex, Birthplace, Parental Education
Household Income
Tree
Gini
0.235
49.64
Mexico
2006
Juárez Wendelspiess Chávez (2015)
Mexican Social Mobility Survey
5277
Age 25–64
Gender, Education of Father/Mother, Parents owned House, Socio-Economic Situation at age 14, Indigeneous Group
Individual Income
Parametric
Variance
N.A.
18.30
Mexico
2009
EqualChances.org
Mexican Family Life Survey
N.A.
Working age respondents
Education of Parents, Occupation of Parents, Origin (Race, Ethnic Origin, Area of Birth)
Equivalized Household Disposable Income
Parametric
Gini
0.135
23.80
Peru
2001
Ferreira and Gignoux (2011)
Encuesta Nacional de Hogares
13,621
Age 30–49, household heads or spouses
Education of Father/Mother, Ethnicity, Region of Birth, Gender
Household per Capita Income
Non-Parametric
MLD
0.163
29.30
Russia
2006–2016
Brock et al. (2016)
Life in Transition Survey
N.A.
N.A.
Gender, Birthplace Urbanity, Ethnicity, Education of Father/Mother, Membership of Communist Party
Self-Reported Income over the last twelve months
Parametric
Gini
0.130
34.50
South Africa
2008–2012
Piraino (2015)
National Income Dynamics Study
2587
Age 20–44, only male respondents
Race, Education of Father
Individual Gross Income
Non-Parametric
MLD
N.A.
23.70
South Africa
2014
EqualChances.org
National Income Dynamics Study
N.A.
Working age respondents
Education of Parents, Occupation of Parents, Origin (Race, Ethnic Origin, Area of Birth)
Equivalized Household Disposable Income
Parametric
Gini
0.337
57.66
Tanzania
2010–2011
Brunori et al. (2019a)
World Bank, National Panel Survey
20,569
N.A.
Sex, Birthplace, Parental Education
Household Income
Tree
Gini
0.177
44.71
The table provides information on previous published IOp studies covering the countries in our sample. Information about methodological details and IOp estimates always refer to the preferred estimate in the respective study
Footnotes
1
Among others, this dichotomy is formalized in Roemer (1998) and Fleurbaey (1995).
 
2
See Brunori et al. (2019a) and Alesina et al. (2019) for work on Africa, Ferreira and Gignoux (2011) for work on Latin America, as well as Andreoli and Fusco (2019) and Brock et al. (2016) for comparative work including Eastern Europe and Central Asia.
 
3
We follow the notational conventions established in Ferreira and Gignoux (2011).
 
4
Note that the current literature largely abstracts from time-variant circumstance characteristics. This abstraction can be rationalized by the blurry distinction between time-variant factors beyond individual control and individual efforts. For example, consider local economic shocks or local outburst of conflict as potential embodiments of time-variant circumstances. Their effect could be confounded by individual migration decisions which are at least partially under individual control. However, as we outline below, our normative framework accounts for the effect of such factors to the extent that they are correlated with time-constant factors such as the region of birth.
 
5
This normative assumption is adopted by much of the empirical literature on IOp but can be easily relaxed, see Niehues and Peichl (2014) and Jusot et al. (2013). We refrain from doing so in our empirical application since restricting samples on availability of effort information would further reduce the number of observations.
 
6
\(\frac{\sigma ^2}{2}\) represents the residual variance that corrects for differences in the marginal impact of circumstances due to the log-transformation (Blackburn 2007).
 
7
Intuitively, k-fold cross-validation works as follows. The sample is divided into k-folds. Under each specification, the model parameters are estimated on \(k-1\) folds and the ensuing predictions are benchmarked against the data points in the \(k{th}\) fold. Repeating this procedure k times, one chooses the model that delivers the lowest average mean-squared prediction error across the k iterations.
 
8
The general idea of cross-validation is explained in footnote 7. In the case of lasso estimations, its implementation is as follows: We re-estimate Eq. 4 for different values of \(\lambda \) on each of the five folds. Ultimately, we choose \(\lambda \) that on average minimizes the mean-squared prediction error across the five folds. The mean-squared prediction error is a standard measure of prediction accuracy (Hastie et al. 2013) and the appropriate target statistic to trade-off upward and downward bias in inequality of opportunity estimates (Brunori et al. 2019b). In Table 3 we show the chosen values of \(\lambda \) for each country in our sample.
 
9
The post-lasso approach will yield results that are more in line with standard estimations based on OLS. This is the case since standard lasso retains parameter estimates that are shrunk by penalization. To the contrary—and analogous to OLS—post-lasso re-estimates these parameters without penalization.
 
10
Accounting for year-specific shocks is necessary since the panel data used to estimate the fixed effect are unbalanced. In case of a balanced panel, the individual fixed effect would be completely orthogonal to the year-specific shock, i.e. one could abstract from \(u_v\).
 
11
Technically, the Gini coefficient nevertheless yields conservative IOp estimates as the residual in the Gini decomposition does contain elements of between-group inequality (Brunori et al. 2019a).
 
12
For countries, in which multiple panel data sets are available, we use the data set with the highest number of waves.
 
13
In Table 4 we show how samples change as we sequentially impose these data restrictions.
 
14
Point estimates for absolute IOp, relative IOp, as well as total inequality are disclosed in Table 3.
 
15
As highlighted above: Unless otherwise indicated the LB estimate refers to the standard lasso estimation.
 
16
This cross-country average conceals heterogeneity. In particular, the lower the sample size relative to the number of estimated circumstance parameters, the larger the difference between S and LB. See Table 3 where we list the ratio of sample size and estimated parameters by country.
 
17
Due to differences in the underlying data, we refrain from comparing our results to other IOp estimates in the relevant countries: See for example, Brock et al. (2016), Brunori et al. (2019a) Ferreira and Gignoux (2011), Ferreira et al. (2018), Golley et al. (2019), Piraino (2015), Song and Zhou (2019), Juárez Wendelspiess Chávez (2015), Zhang and Eriksson (2010). These differences pertain to reference periods, the considered outcomes of interest, the detail of available circumstance characteristics, sample selection criteria, estimation methods, as well as inequality indices. However, we provide detailed information on these studies in Table 7.
 
18
A similar line of thought can be found in Bourguignon et al. (2007) who argue that the presence of transitory fluctuations in the residual tends to bias IOp estimates downward.
 
19
Table 6 shows the country-specific year chosen for this sensitivity check.
 
Literature
go back to reference Aiyar S, Ebeke C (2019) Inequality of opportunity, inequality of income and economic growth. Imf Working Paper Ser 19:34 Aiyar S, Ebeke C (2019) Inequality of opportunity, inequality of income and economic growth. Imf Working Paper Ser 19:34
go back to reference Alesina A, Hohmann S, Michalopoulos S, Papaioannou E (2019) Intergenerational mobility in Africa. Econometrica 89(1):1–35CrossRef Alesina A, Hohmann S, Michalopoulos S, Papaioannou E (2019) Intergenerational mobility in Africa. Econometrica 89(1):1–35CrossRef
go back to reference Alesina A, Stantcheva S, Teso E (2018) Intergenerational mobility and preferences for redistribution. Am Econ Rev 108(2):521–554CrossRef Alesina A, Stantcheva S, Teso E (2018) Intergenerational mobility and preferences for redistribution. Am Econ Rev 108(2):521–554CrossRef
go back to reference Andreoli F, Fusco A (2019) Robust cross-country analysis of inequality of opportunity. Econ Lett 182:86–89CrossRef Andreoli F, Fusco A (2019) Robust cross-country analysis of inequality of opportunity. Econ Lett 182:86–89CrossRef
go back to reference Arneson R (1989) Equality and equal opportunity for welfare. Philos Stud 56(1):77–93CrossRef Arneson R (1989) Equality and equal opportunity for welfare. Philos Stud 56(1):77–93CrossRef
go back to reference Balcázar C (2015) Lower bounds on inequality of opportunity and measurement error. Econ Lett 137:102–105CrossRef Balcázar C (2015) Lower bounds on inequality of opportunity and measurement error. Econ Lett 137:102–105CrossRef
go back to reference Belloni A, Chernozhukov V (2013) Least squares after model selection in high-dimensional sparse models. Bernoulli 19(2):521–547CrossRef Belloni A, Chernozhukov V (2013) Least squares after model selection in high-dimensional sparse models. Bernoulli 19(2):521–547CrossRef
go back to reference Blackburn M (2007) Estimating wage differentials without logarithms. Labour Econ 14(1):73–98CrossRef Blackburn M (2007) Estimating wage differentials without logarithms. Labour Econ 14(1):73–98CrossRef
go back to reference Bourguignon F, Ferreira FHG, Menéndez M (2007) Inequality of opportunity in Brazil. Rev Income Wealth 53(4):585–618CrossRef Bourguignon F, Ferreira FHG, Menéndez M (2007) Inequality of opportunity in Brazil. Rev Income Wealth 53(4):585–618CrossRef
go back to reference Brock J, Peragine V, Tonini S (2016) Inequality of opportunity. transition for all: equal opportunities in an unequal world. Ebrd Chap 3:81–98 Brock J, Peragine V, Tonini S (2016) Inequality of opportunity. transition for all: equal opportunities in an unequal world. Ebrd Chap 3:81–98
go back to reference Brunori P, Hufe P, Mahler D (2018) The roots of inequality: estimating inequality of opportunity from regression trees. Ifo Work Pap 2018:252 Brunori P, Hufe P, Mahler D (2018) The roots of inequality: estimating inequality of opportunity from regression trees. Ifo Work Pap 2018:252
go back to reference Brunori P, Palmisano F, Peragine V (2019a) Inequality of opportunity in sub-saharan Africa. Appl Econ 51(60):6428–6458CrossRef Brunori P, Palmisano F, Peragine V (2019a) Inequality of opportunity in sub-saharan Africa. Appl Econ 51(60):6428–6458CrossRef
go back to reference Brunori P, Peragine V, Serlenga L (2019b) Upward and downward bias when measuring inequality of opportunity. Soc Choice Welf 52(4):635–661CrossRef Brunori P, Peragine V, Serlenga L (2019b) Upward and downward bias when measuring inequality of opportunity. Soc Choice Welf 52(4):635–661CrossRef
go back to reference Cappelen AW, Hole AD, Sørensen EØ, Tungodden B (2007) The pluralism of fairness ideals: an experimental approach. Am Econ Rev 97(3):818–827CrossRef Cappelen AW, Hole AD, Sørensen EØ, Tungodden B (2007) The pluralism of fairness ideals: an experimental approach. Am Econ Rev 97(3):818–827CrossRef
go back to reference Cohen G (1989) On the currency of Egalitarian justice. Ethics 99(4):906–944CrossRef Cohen G (1989) On the currency of Egalitarian justice. Ethics 99(4):906–944CrossRef
go back to reference Cubas G (2016) Distortions, infrastructure, and female labor supply in developing countries. Eur Econ Rev 87:194–215CrossRef Cubas G (2016) Distortions, infrastructure, and female labor supply in developing countries. Eur Econ Rev 87:194–215CrossRef
go back to reference Ferreira F, Gignoux J (2011) The measurement of inequality of opportunity: theory and an application to Latin America. Rev Income Wealth 57(4):622–657CrossRef Ferreira F, Gignoux J (2011) The measurement of inequality of opportunity: theory and an application to Latin America. Rev Income Wealth 57(4):622–657CrossRef
go back to reference Ferreira F, Lakner C, Lugo M, Özler B (2018) Inequality of opportunity and economic growth: how much can cross-country regressions really tell us? Rev Income Wealth 64(4):800–827CrossRef Ferreira F, Lakner C, Lugo M, Özler B (2018) Inequality of opportunity and economic growth: how much can cross-country regressions really tell us? Rev Income Wealth 64(4):800–827CrossRef
go back to reference Fleurbaey M (1995) Three solutions for the compensation problem. J Econ Theory 65(2):505–521CrossRef Fleurbaey M (1995) Three solutions for the compensation problem. J Econ Theory 65(2):505–521CrossRef
go back to reference Foster J, Aa S (2000) Path independent inequality measures. J Econ Theory 91(2):199–222CrossRef Foster J, Aa S (2000) Path independent inequality measures. J Econ Theory 91(2):199–222CrossRef
go back to reference Golley J, Zhou Y, Wang M (2019) Inequality of opportunity in China’s labor earnings: the gender dimension. China World Econ 27(1):28–50CrossRef Golley J, Zhou Y, Wang M (2019) Inequality of opportunity in China’s labor earnings: the gender dimension. China World Econ 27(1):28–50CrossRef
go back to reference Hastie T, Tibshirani R, Friedman J (2013) The elements of statistical learning: data mining, inference, and prediction. Springer, Heidelberg Hastie T, Tibshirani R, Friedman J (2013) The elements of statistical learning: data mining, inference, and prediction. Springer, Heidelberg
go back to reference Hufe P, Peichl A, Je R, Ungerer M (2017) Inequality of income acquisition: the role of childhood circumstances. Soc Choice Welf 143(3–4):499–544CrossRef Hufe P, Peichl A, Je R, Ungerer M (2017) Inequality of income acquisition: the role of childhood circumstances. Soc Choice Welf 143(3–4):499–544CrossRef
go back to reference Jayachandran S (2015) The roots of gender inequality in developing countries. Annu Rev Econ 7(1):63–88CrossRef Jayachandran S (2015) The roots of gender inequality in developing countries. Annu Rev Econ 7(1):63–88CrossRef
go back to reference Jusot F, Tubeuf S, Trannoy A (2013) Circumstances and efforts: how important is their correlation for the measurement of inequality of opportunity in health? Health Econ 22(12):1470–1495CrossRef Jusot F, Tubeuf S, Trannoy A (2013) Circumstances and efforts: how important is their correlation for the measurement of inequality of opportunity in health? Health Econ 22(12):1470–1495CrossRef
go back to reference Kanbur R, Wagstaff A (2016) How useful is inequality of opportunity as a policy construct? inequality and growth: patterns and policy. In: Basu K, Stiglitz JE (eds), vol 1. Palgrave Macmillan, London, pp 131–150 Kanbur R, Wagstaff A (2016) How useful is inequality of opportunity as a policy construct? inequality and growth: patterns and policy. In: Basu K, Stiglitz JE (eds), vol 1. Palgrave Macmillan, London, pp 131–150
go back to reference Marrero G, Rodríguez J (2013) Inequality of opportunity and growth. J Dev Econ 104:107–122CrossRef Marrero G, Rodríguez J (2013) Inequality of opportunity and growth. J Dev Econ 104:107–122CrossRef
go back to reference MejíA D, St-Pierre M (2008) Unequal opportunities and human capital formation. J Dev Econ 86(2):395–413CrossRef MejíA D, St-Pierre M (2008) Unequal opportunities and human capital formation. J Dev Econ 86(2):395–413CrossRef
go back to reference Meyer BD, Sullivan JX (2017) Consumption and income inequality in the U.S. since the 1960S. In: National Bureau Of Economic Research Working Paper Series 23655 Meyer BD, Sullivan JX (2017) Consumption and income inequality in the U.S. since the 1960S. In: National Bureau Of Economic Research Working Paper Series 23655
go back to reference Neidhöfer G, Serrano J, Gasparini L (2018) Educational inequality and intergenerational mobility in latin America: a new database. J Dev Econ 134:329–349CrossRef Neidhöfer G, Serrano J, Gasparini L (2018) Educational inequality and intergenerational mobility in latin America: a new database. J Dev Econ 134:329–349CrossRef
go back to reference Niehues J, Peichl A (2014) Upper bounds of inequality of opportunity: theory and evidence for Germany and the us. Soc Choice Welf 43(1):73–99CrossRef Niehues J, Peichl A (2014) Upper bounds of inequality of opportunity: theory and evidence for Germany and the us. Soc Choice Welf 43(1):73–99CrossRef
go back to reference Peragine V, Palmisano F, Brunori P (2014) Economic growth and equality of opportunity. World Bank Econ Rev 28(2):247–281CrossRef Peragine V, Palmisano F, Brunori P (2014) Economic growth and equality of opportunity. World Bank Econ Rev 28(2):247–281CrossRef
go back to reference Piraino P (2015) Intergenerational earnings mobility and equality of opportunity in South Africa. World Dev 67(1):396–405CrossRef Piraino P (2015) Intergenerational earnings mobility and equality of opportunity in South Africa. World Dev 67(1):396–405CrossRef
go back to reference Ramos X, Van De Gaer D (2016) Empirical approaches to inequality of opportunity: principles, measures, and evidence. J Econ Surv 30(5):855–883CrossRef Ramos X, Van De Gaer D (2016) Empirical approaches to inequality of opportunity: principles, measures, and evidence. J Econ Surv 30(5):855–883CrossRef
go back to reference Roemer J (1998) Equality of opportunity. Harvard University Press, CambridgeCrossRef Roemer J (1998) Equality of opportunity. Harvard University Press, CambridgeCrossRef
go back to reference Rohner D (2011) Reputation, group structure and social tensions. J Dev Econ 96(2):188–199CrossRef Rohner D (2011) Reputation, group structure and social tensions. J Dev Econ 96(2):188–199CrossRef
go back to reference Shorrocks A (1980) The class of additively decomposable inequality measures. Econometrica 48(3):613–625CrossRef Shorrocks A (1980) The class of additively decomposable inequality measures. Econometrica 48(3):613–625CrossRef
go back to reference Song Y, Zhou G (2019) Inequality of opportunity and household education expenditures: evidence from panel data in China. China Econ Rev 55(1):85–98CrossRef Song Y, Zhou G (2019) Inequality of opportunity and household education expenditures: evidence from panel data in China. China Econ Rev 55(1):85–98CrossRef
go back to reference Juárez Wendelspiess Chávez F (2015) Measuring inequality of opportunity with latent variables. J Hum Dev Capab 16(1):106–121CrossRef Juárez Wendelspiess Chávez F (2015) Measuring inequality of opportunity with latent variables. J Hum Dev Capab 16(1):106–121CrossRef
go back to reference Zhang Y, Eriksson T (2010) Inequality of opportunity and income inequality in nine Chinese provinces, 1989–2006. China Econ Rev 21(4):607–616CrossRef Zhang Y, Eriksson T (2010) Inequality of opportunity and income inequality in nine Chinese provinces, 1989–2006. China Econ Rev 21(4):607–616CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Lower and upper bound estimates of inequality of opportunity for emerging economies
Authors
Paul Hufe
Andreas Peichl
Daniel Weishaar
Publication date
20-09-2021
Publisher
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Published in
Social Choice and Welfare / Issue 3/2022
Print ISSN: 0176-1714
Electronic ISSN: 1432-217X
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-021-01362-7

Other articles of this Issue 3/2022

Social Choice and Welfare 3/2022 Go to the issue