Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Political Behavior 1/2019

18-12-2017 | Original Paper

Policy and Blame Attribution: Citizens’ Preferences, Policy Reputations, and Policy Surprises

Authors: Raanan Sulitzeanu-Kenan, Reimut Zohlnhöfer

Published in: Political Behavior | Issue 1/2019

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Negativity bias suggests that the attribution of blame to governments, for alleged or actual policy failures, is disproportionately pertinent for their popularity. However, when citizens attribute blame for adverse consequences of a policy, does it make a difference which policy was it, and who was the political agent that adopted the policy? We posit that the level of blame citizens attribute to political agents for policy failures depends on three policy-oriented considerations: (1) the distance between a citizen’s ideal policy and the agent’s established policy position; (2) the distance between a citizen’s ideal policy and the agent’s concrete policy choice; and (3) the distance between the agent’s established policy position and her concrete policy choice. The inherent relationship between these three policy-oriented considerations renders their integration in one model a theoretical and methodological imperative. The model provides novel observable predictions regarding the conditions under which each of the three policy-oriented factors will produce either pronounced or subtle observable effects on blame attribution. We test the model’s predictions in two survey experiments, in Israel and in Germany. The results of both experiments are highly consistent with the model’s predictions. These finding offer an important contribution by specifying the ways in which individual-level preferences interact with politicians’ policy reputations and policy choices to shape blame attribution. Our model entails unintuitive revisions to several strands of the literature, and in the “Discussion” section we provide tentative support for the applicability of this model to other political judgments beyond blame attribution.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
The formal structure of this policy preferences relies on its implementation in spatial models of voting (Adams et al. 2005, p. 26; Downs 1957a); but such distances were also found to account for other political evaluations (e.g., Yair and Sulitzeanu-Kenan 2015).
 
2
This expectation is consistent with the logic of spatial models in general and with several behavioral studies that have found such policy effects on positive attitudes such as support (Boudreau and MacKenzie 2014; Bullock 2011; Carsey and Layman 2006). Note, however, that all of these behavioral studies estimated the behavioral responses to concrete policy information and partisan identification, disregarding the established policy position of the political agent. Given the contribution of established policy positions of political agents (agent distance) to understanding political attitudes and behavior beyond the effect of partisan identification, we suspect that the partisan cue treatment effects estimated in these studies comprise both partisan identification and established policy position proximity.
 
3
The probability of partisan identification under proximate agent distance is higher compared to this probability under distance agent condition: \(p(pid|AD = 0) - p(pid|AD = 1) = \Delta p^{pid} ;1 > \Delta p^{pid} > 0\).
 
4
The theoretical effects of shifting from congruent to surprising policy of proximate and distant agents are as follows: for proximate agents (a move from cell (a) to (c)): \((\Delta p^{pid} \beta + \gamma + \delta ) - (\Delta p^{pid} \beta ) = \gamma + \delta\); for distant agents (a move from cell (d) to (b)): \((\alpha + \delta ) - (\alpha + \gamma ) = \delta - \gamma\). Since we do not assume to know the sizes of γ and δ, and given that γ > 0 and δ < 0, we cannot predict whether the net effect of γ + δ is positive or negative. We do know, however, that the net effect of δ − γ is negative and its absolute value is larger than the absolute value of the γ + δ effect. Therefore, we expect a larger reduction in blame for agent non-supporters by an additional 2γ.
 
5
Age, gender, country of birth, ideological self-placement, religiosity, income, vote choice in the 2009 national elections, vote intention. Religiosity plays a particularly important role in defining collective identity and political attitudes in Israeli society (Shamir and Arian 1999).
 
6
The ideological self-placement scale ranges from 1 (extreme hawk) to 5 (extreme dove). It was subsequently reversed and set to range from 0 (extreme dove) to 1 (extreme hawk).
 
7
We assessed the robustness of the results in less extreme agent and policy ideological placements. Agent and concrete policy distance effects retain a relatively stable mean effect across agent/policy extremity levels, but the variances of these effects become large at less extreme levels. These results are provided in Online Appendix 6.
 
8
Successful manipulation of policy in/congruence was verified (for details see Online Appendix 5).
 
9
Age, gender, education, ideological self-placement, intention to vote, vote choice, political interest, political knowledge.
 
10
The ideological self-placement scale was based on a slider which respondents were able to locate on a line between “left” and “right”. The position of the slider was recorded as a figure between 1 (left) and 33 (right). For the purpose of the analyses, it was set to range from 0 (left) to 1 (right).
 
11
As in the Israeli experiment, we assessed the robustness of the results in less extreme agent and policy ideological placements. Agent and concrete policy distance effects retain a relatively stable mean effect across agent/policy extremity levels, except from the very moderate level (0.4/0.6). These results are provided in Online Appendix 6.
 
12
Given that both experiments were conducted in multi-party systems, partisanship and agent-distance were not expected to be overly correlated. Indeed multicollinearity is not an issue in both of the experiments (Israel: agent-distance VIF = 1.42, partisanship VIF = 1.15, mean VIF = 1.33; Germany: agent-distance VIF = 1.26, partisanship VIF = 1.11, mean VIF = 1.10).
 
13
In the Israeli experiments respondents were coded as evaluating an ideologically distant agent (AD = 1) if they identified as “extreme hawk” or “hawk” and the political agent was Livni, or if they identified as “center”, “dove” or “extreme dove” and the policy agent was Netanyahu or Liberman. They were coded as evaluating an ideologically proximate agent (AD = 0) otherwise. Respondents were coded as evaluating a large policy-distance (CPD = 1) if they identified as “extreme hawk” or “hawk” and the policy was dovish, or if they identified as “center”, “dove” or “extreme dove” and the policy was hawkish. They were coded as evaluating an ideologically proximate policy (CPD = 0) otherwise (the results also hold when coding those identified as “center” as “hawks”). In the German experiment respondents were coded as evaluating an ideologically distant agent (AD = 1) if their ideological measure was less than 15 (median) and the political agent was a CDU/CSU and FDP coalition, or if their ideological measure was 15 or higher and the political agent was a SPD and Greens coalition. They were coded as evaluating an ideologically proximate agent (AD = 0) otherwise. Respondents were coded as evaluating an ideologically distant policy (CPD = 1) if their ideological measure was less than 15 and the policy was labor-market liberalization; or if their ideological measure was 15 or higher and the policy was minimum wage. They were coded as evaluating a proximate policy (CPD = 0) otherwise.
 
Literature
go back to reference Adams, J. F., Merrill, S., III, & Grofman, B. (2005). A unified theory of party competition: A cross-national analysis integrating spatial and behavioral factors. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Adams, J. F., Merrill, S., III, & Grofman, B. (2005). A unified theory of party competition: A cross-national analysis integrating spatial and behavioral factors. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Anderson, C. (1995). Blaming the government: Citizens and the economy in five European democracies. New York: M.E. Sharpe. Anderson, C. (1995). Blaming the government: Citizens and the economy in five European democracies. New York: M.E. Sharpe.
go back to reference Anderson, C. J. (2000). Economic voting and political context: A comparative perspective. Electoral Studies, 19(2–3), 151–170.CrossRef Anderson, C. J. (2000). Economic voting and political context: A comparative perspective. Electoral Studies, 19(2–3), 151–170.CrossRef
go back to reference Anderson, C. J., Mendes, S. M., & Tverdova, Y. V. (2004). Endogenous economic voting: Evidence from the 1997 British election. Electoral Studies, 23(4), 683–708.CrossRef Anderson, C. J., Mendes, S. M., & Tverdova, Y. V. (2004). Endogenous economic voting: Evidence from the 1997 British election. Electoral Studies, 23(4), 683–708.CrossRef
go back to reference Bartling, B., & Fischbacher, U. (2012). Shifting the blame: On delegation and responsibility. The Review of Economic Studies, 79(1), 67–87.CrossRef Bartling, B., & Fischbacher, U. (2012). Shifting the blame: On delegation and responsibility. The Review of Economic Studies, 79(1), 67–87.CrossRef
go back to reference Benoit, K., & Laver, M. (2006). Party policy in modern democracies. London: Routledge.CrossRef Benoit, K., & Laver, M. (2006). Party policy in modern democracies. London: Routledge.CrossRef
go back to reference Boudreau, C., & MacKenzie, S. A. (2014). Informing the electorate? How party cues and policy information affect public opinion about initiatives. American Journal of Political Science, 58(1), 48–62.CrossRef Boudreau, C., & MacKenzie, S. A. (2014). Informing the electorate? How party cues and policy information affect public opinion about initiatives. American Journal of Political Science, 58(1), 48–62.CrossRef
go back to reference Bullock, J. G. (2011). Elite influence on public opinion in an informed electorate. American Political Science Review, 105(3), 496–515.CrossRef Bullock, J. G. (2011). Elite influence on public opinion in an informed electorate. American Political Science Review, 105(3), 496–515.CrossRef
go back to reference Carsey, T. M., & Layman, G. C. (2006). Changing sides or changing minds? Party identification and policy preferences in the American electorate. American Journal of Political Science, 50(2), 464–477.CrossRef Carsey, T. M., & Layman, G. C. (2006). Changing sides or changing minds? Party identification and policy preferences in the American electorate. American Journal of Political Science, 50(2), 464–477.CrossRef
go back to reference Cowen, T., & Sutter, D. (1998). Why only Nixon could go to China. Public Choice, 97(4), 605–615.CrossRef Cowen, T., & Sutter, D. (1998). Why only Nixon could go to China. Public Choice, 97(4), 605–615.CrossRef
go back to reference Cukierman, A., & Tommasi, M. (1998). When does it take a Nixon to go to China? The American Economic Review, 88(1), 180–197. Cukierman, A., & Tommasi, M. (1998). When does it take a Nixon to go to China? The American Economic Review, 88(1), 180–197.
go back to reference Ditto, P. H., & Mastronarde, A. J. (2009). The paradox of the political maverick. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 45, 295–298.CrossRef Ditto, P. H., & Mastronarde, A. J. (2009). The paradox of the political maverick. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 45, 295–298.CrossRef
go back to reference Downs, A. (1957a). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper. Downs, A. (1957a). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper.
go back to reference Downs, A. (1957b). An economic theory of political action in a democracy. Journal of Political Economy, 65(2), 135–150.CrossRef Downs, A. (1957b). An economic theory of political action in a democracy. Journal of Political Economy, 65(2), 135–150.CrossRef
go back to reference Druckman, J. N., Green, D. P., Kuklinski, J. H., & Lupia, A. (2011). Experiment: An introduction to core concepts. In J. N. Druckman, D. P. Green, J. H. Kuklinski, & A. Lupia (Eds.), Cambridge handbook of experimental political science. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Druckman, J. N., Green, D. P., Kuklinski, J. H., & Lupia, A. (2011). Experiment: An introduction to core concepts. In J. N. Druckman, D. P. Green, J. H. Kuklinski, & A. Lupia (Eds.), Cambridge handbook of experimental political science. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Duch, R. M., May, J., & Armstrong, D., II. (2010). Coalition-directed voting in multiparty democracies. American Political Science Review, 104(4), 698–719.CrossRef Duch, R. M., May, J., & Armstrong, D., II. (2010). Coalition-directed voting in multiparty democracies. American Political Science Review, 104(4), 698–719.CrossRef
go back to reference Duch, R. M., & Stevenson, R. T. (2008). The economic vote: How political and economic institutions condition election results. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Duch, R. M., & Stevenson, R. T. (2008). The economic vote: How political and economic institutions condition election results. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Federico, C. M. (2007). Expertise, evaluative motivation, and the structure of citizens’ ideological commitments. Political Psychology, 28(5), 535–561.CrossRef Federico, C. M. (2007). Expertise, evaluative motivation, and the structure of citizens’ ideological commitments. Political Psychology, 28(5), 535–561.CrossRef
go back to reference Fiorina, M. P. (1981). Retrospective voting in American national elections. New Haven, NJ: Yale University Press. Fiorina, M. P. (1981). Retrospective voting in American national elections. New Haven, NJ: Yale University Press.
go back to reference Gerber, A., & Green, D. P. (1998). Rational learning and partisan attitudes. American Journal of Political Science, 42(3), 794–818.CrossRef Gerber, A., & Green, D. P. (1998). Rational learning and partisan attitudes. American Journal of Political Science, 42(3), 794–818.CrossRef
go back to reference Green, D. P. (1988). On the dimensionality of public sentiment toward partisan and ideological groups. American Journal of Political Science, 32(3), 758–780.CrossRef Green, D. P. (1988). On the dimensionality of public sentiment toward partisan and ideological groups. American Journal of Political Science, 32(3), 758–780.CrossRef
go back to reference Halperin, E., Porat, R., Tamir, M., & Gross, J. J. (2013). Can emotion regulation change political attitudes in intractable conflicts? From the laboratory to the field. Psychological Science, 24(1), 106–111.CrossRef Halperin, E., Porat, R., Tamir, M., & Gross, J. J. (2013). Can emotion regulation change political attitudes in intractable conflicts? From the laboratory to the field. Psychological Science, 24(1), 106–111.CrossRef
go back to reference Hellwig, T., & Samuels, D. (2008). Electoral accountability and the variety of democratic regimes. British Journal of Political Science, 38(1), 65–90.CrossRef Hellwig, T., & Samuels, D. (2008). Electoral accountability and the variety of democratic regimes. British Journal of Political Science, 38(1), 65–90.CrossRef
go back to reference Hicks, R., & Tingley, D. (2011). Causal mediation analysis. Stata Journal, 11(4), 605–619.CrossRef Hicks, R., & Tingley, D. (2011). Causal mediation analysis. Stata Journal, 11(4), 605–619.CrossRef
go back to reference Hood, C. (2010). The blame game: Spin, bureaucracy, and self-preservation in government. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRef Hood, C. (2010). The blame game: Spin, bureaucracy, and self-preservation in government. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Huckfeldt, R., Mondak, J. J., Craw, M., & Morehouse Mendez, J. (2005). Making sense of candidates: Partisanship, ideology, and issues as guides to judgment. Cognitive Brain Research, 23(1), 11–23.CrossRef Huckfeldt, R., Mondak, J. J., Craw, M., & Morehouse Mendez, J. (2005). Making sense of candidates: Partisanship, ideology, and issues as guides to judgment. Cognitive Brain Research, 23(1), 11–23.CrossRef
go back to reference Imai, K., Keele, L., Tingley, D., & Yamamoto, T. (2011). Unpacking the black box of causality: Learning about causal mechanisms from experimental and observational studies. American Political Science Review, 105(4), 765–789.CrossRef Imai, K., Keele, L., Tingley, D., & Yamamoto, T. (2011). Unpacking the black box of causality: Learning about causal mechanisms from experimental and observational studies. American Political Science Review, 105(4), 765–789.CrossRef
go back to reference Jost, J. T. (2006). The end of the end of ideology. American Psychologist, 61(7), 651–670.CrossRef Jost, J. T. (2006). The end of the end of ideology. American Psychologist, 61(7), 651–670.CrossRef
go back to reference Kedar, O. (2009). Voting for policy, not parties: How voters compensate for power sharing. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Kedar, O. (2009). Voting for policy, not parties: How voters compensate for power sharing. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Krueger, A. B. (2000). From Bismarck to Maastricht: The March to European Union and the Labor Compact 1. Labour Economics, 7(2), 117–134.CrossRef Krueger, A. B. (2000). From Bismarck to Maastricht: The March to European Union and the Labor Compact 1. Labour Economics, 7(2), 117–134.CrossRef
go back to reference Lewis-Beck, M. S., Nadeau, R., & Elias, A. (2008). Economics, party, and the vote: Causality issues and panel data. American Journal of Political Science, 52(1), 84–95.CrossRef Lewis-Beck, M. S., Nadeau, R., & Elias, A. (2008). Economics, party, and the vote: Causality issues and panel data. American Journal of Political Science, 52(1), 84–95.CrossRef
go back to reference Lewis-Beck, M. S., & Stegmaier, M. (2000). Economic determinants of electoral outcomes. Annual Review of Political Science, 3(1), 183–219.CrossRef Lewis-Beck, M. S., & Stegmaier, M. (2000). Economic determinants of electoral outcomes. Annual Review of Political Science, 3(1), 183–219.CrossRef
go back to reference Manin, B. (1997). The principles of representative government. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Manin, B. (1997). The principles of representative government. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Nannestad, P., & Paldam, M. (1994). The VP-function: A survey of the literature on vote and popularity functions after 25 years. Public Choice, 79(3–4), 213–245.CrossRef Nannestad, P., & Paldam, M. (1994). The VP-function: A survey of the literature on vote and popularity functions after 25 years. Public Choice, 79(3–4), 213–245.CrossRef
go back to reference Nicholson, S. P., & Segura, G. M. (2012). Who’s the party of the people? Economic populism and the U.S. public’s beliefs about political parties. Political Behavior, 34(2), 369–389.CrossRef Nicholson, S. P., & Segura, G. M. (2012). Who’s the party of the people? Economic populism and the U.S. public’s beliefs about political parties. Political Behavior, 34(2), 369–389.CrossRef
go back to reference Oppenheimer, D. M., Meyvis, T., & Davidenko, N. (2009). Instructional manipulation checks: Detecting satisficing to increase statistical power. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 45(4), 867–872.CrossRef Oppenheimer, D. M., Meyvis, T., & Davidenko, N. (2009). Instructional manipulation checks: Detecting satisficing to increase statistical power. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 45(4), 867–872.CrossRef
go back to reference Pettigrew, T. F. (1979). The ultimate attribution error: Extending Allport’s cognitive analysis of prejudice. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 5(4), 461–476.CrossRef Pettigrew, T. F. (1979). The ultimate attribution error: Extending Allport’s cognitive analysis of prejudice. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 5(4), 461–476.CrossRef
go back to reference Powell, G. B. (2000). Elections as instruments of democracy: Majoritarian and proportional visions. New Haven, NJ: Yale University Press. Powell, G. B. (2000). Elections as instruments of democracy: Majoritarian and proportional visions. New Haven, NJ: Yale University Press.
go back to reference Powell, G. B., & Whitten, G. D. (1993). A cross-national analysis of economic voting: Taking account of the political context. American Journal of Political Science, 37(2), 391–414.CrossRef Powell, G. B., & Whitten, G. D. (1993). A cross-national analysis of economic voting: Taking account of the political context. American Journal of Political Science, 37(2), 391–414.CrossRef
go back to reference Rahat, G., & Sheafer, T. (2007). The personalization(s) of politics: Israel, 1949–2003. Political Communication, 24(1), 65–80.CrossRef Rahat, G., & Sheafer, T. (2007). The personalization(s) of politics: Israel, 1949–2003. Political Communication, 24(1), 65–80.CrossRef
go back to reference Rudolph, T. J. (2003a). Institutional context and the assignment of political responsibility. Journal of Politics, 65(1), 190–215.CrossRef Rudolph, T. J. (2003a). Institutional context and the assignment of political responsibility. Journal of Politics, 65(1), 190–215.CrossRef
go back to reference Rudolph, T. J. (2003b). Who’s responsible for the economy? The formation and consequences of responsibility attributions. American Journal of Political Science, 47(4), 698–713.CrossRef Rudolph, T. J. (2003b). Who’s responsible for the economy? The formation and consequences of responsibility attributions. American Journal of Political Science, 47(4), 698–713.CrossRef
go back to reference Rudolph, T. J. (2006). Triangulating political responsibility: The motivated formation of responsibility judgments. Political Psychology, 27(1), 99–122.CrossRef Rudolph, T. J. (2006). Triangulating political responsibility: The motivated formation of responsibility judgments. Political Psychology, 27(1), 99–122.CrossRef
go back to reference Rudolph, T. J., & Grant, J. T. (2002). An attributional model of economic voting: Evidence from the 2000 presidential election. Political Research Quarterly, 55(4), 805–823.CrossRef Rudolph, T. J., & Grant, J. T. (2002). An attributional model of economic voting: Evidence from the 2000 presidential election. Political Research Quarterly, 55(4), 805–823.CrossRef
go back to reference Schlenker, B. R., Britt, T. W., Pennington, J., Murphy, R., & Doherty, K. (1994). The triangle model of responsibility. Psychological Review, 101(4), 632–652.CrossRef Schlenker, B. R., Britt, T. W., Pennington, J., Murphy, R., & Doherty, K. (1994). The triangle model of responsibility. Psychological Review, 101(4), 632–652.CrossRef
go back to reference Shamir, M., & Arian, A. (1999). Collective identity and electoral competition in Israel. American Political Science Review, 93(2), 265–277.CrossRef Shamir, M., & Arian, A. (1999). Collective identity and electoral competition in Israel. American Political Science Review, 93(2), 265–277.CrossRef
go back to reference Soroka, S. N. (2006). Good news and bad news: Asymmetric responses to economic information. Journal of Politics, 68(2), 372–385.CrossRef Soroka, S. N. (2006). Good news and bad news: Asymmetric responses to economic information. Journal of Politics, 68(2), 372–385.CrossRef
go back to reference Soroka, S. N. (2014). Negativity in democratic politics: Causes and consequences. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Soroka, S. N. (2014). Negativity in democratic politics: Causes and consequences. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Sulitzeanu-Kenan, R. (2006). If they get it right: An experimental test of the effects of the appointment and reports of UK public inquiries. Public Administration, 84(3), 623–653.CrossRef Sulitzeanu-Kenan, R. (2006). If they get it right: An experimental test of the effects of the appointment and reports of UK public inquiries. Public Administration, 84(3), 623–653.CrossRef
go back to reference Tilley, J., & Hobolt, S. B. (2011). Is the government to blame? An experimental test of how partisanship shapes perceptions of performance and responsibility. The Journal of Politics, 73(2), 316–330.CrossRef Tilley, J., & Hobolt, S. B. (2011). Is the government to blame? An experimental test of how partisanship shapes perceptions of performance and responsibility. The Journal of Politics, 73(2), 316–330.CrossRef
go back to reference Weaver, R. K. (1986). The politics of blame avoidance. Journal of Public Policy, 6(4), 371–398.CrossRef Weaver, R. K. (1986). The politics of blame avoidance. Journal of Public Policy, 6(4), 371–398.CrossRef
go back to reference Yair, O., & Sulitzeanu-Kenan, R. (2015). Biased judgment of political bias: Perceived ideological distance increases perceptions of political bias. Political Behavior, 37(2), 487–507.CrossRef Yair, O., & Sulitzeanu-Kenan, R. (2015). Biased judgment of political bias: Perceived ideological distance increases perceptions of political bias. Political Behavior, 37(2), 487–507.CrossRef
go back to reference Zohlnhöfer, R. (2014). Economic policy. In S. Padgett, W. E. Paterson, & R. Zohlnhöfer (Eds.), Developments in German politics 4 (pp. 149–165). Basingstoke: Palgrave.CrossRef Zohlnhöfer, R. (2014). Economic policy. In S. Padgett, W. E. Paterson, & R. Zohlnhöfer (Eds.), Developments in German politics 4 (pp. 149–165). Basingstoke: Palgrave.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Policy and Blame Attribution: Citizens’ Preferences, Policy Reputations, and Policy Surprises
Authors
Raanan Sulitzeanu-Kenan
Reimut Zohlnhöfer
Publication date
18-12-2017
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Political Behavior / Issue 1/2019
Print ISSN: 0190-9320
Electronic ISSN: 1573-6687
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11109-017-9441-5

Other articles of this Issue 1/2019

Political Behavior 1/2019 Go to the issue