Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Journal of Business Ethics 3/2022

Open Access 19-03-2021 | Original Paper

Power Imbalance and the Dark Side of the Captive Agri-food Supplier–Buyer Relationship

Authors: Richard Glavee-Geo, Per Engelseth, Arnt Buvik

Published in: Journal of Business Ethics | Issue 3/2022

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This paper highlights the dark side of power imbalance regarding its consequences in agri-food supplier–buyer relationships. We report on findings from two studies. The first study is based on a sample of 105 key informants, while study 2 is based on a sample of 444 key informants, all from the cocoa agri-food supply market of Ghana. While the first study focuses on the antecedents of power imbalance and its consequences, the second study explores the role of cooperatives/collective action in minimizing supplier exploitation. Data from these studies were analysed using the partial least squares technique (SmartPLS). Analysis of these findings shows switching costs’ impact on power imbalance to be curvilinear, while power imbalance has a curvilinear relationship with opportunism. The negative consequences of power imbalance are further exacerbated by dependency and the lack of joint action. Furthermore, we found the negative impact of power imbalance on financial performance to be stronger for non-cooperative members than for cooperative members, while, counterintuitively, we found the positive impact of economic satisfaction on financial performance to be stronger for non-cooperative members than for cooperative members.
Notes

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Introduction

Most agri-food systems in emerging and developing economies are characterized by small suppliers, which are highly dependent on much larger buyers and lead firms. These suppliers have high switching costs and are therefore described as ‘‘captive’’ (Cox et al., 2000). While it is generally known and assumed that power can be misused and can lead to exploitation, the topic of unscrupulous and ethically unprincipled buying behaviour has been ignored in academic research in general (Schleper et al., 2017). Cases of supplier exploitation by firms or their agents have been popular in the media. Power imbalance and dependence have been cited as causing and fostering supplier exploitative and negative behaviours (Abosag et al., 2016; Hingley, 2005b; Schleper et al., 2017). The power concept is critical in understanding buyer–supplier relationships (Gaski, 1984). In supply chain relationships, power is useful for effective coordination, integration, and goal attainment, such that weaker participants in the chain may be predisposed to endure imbalanced relations so long as there are ample rewards (Hingley, 2005a; Maglaras et al., 2015; Nyga et al., 2013). Asymmetries in power affect the distribution of outcomes (Hingley, 2005a).
Grandinetti (2017) identified two different types of dark sides to business relationships, termed “trap” and “secret”. In the first case, the partner who is at a disadvantage is aware of what is going on but nevertheless remains trapped in the relationship because of a power imbalance and a strong dependence. In the second case, one partner exploits an information asymmetry (a secret) to his own advantage and to the other partner’s disadvantage. Our study is focused on the first scenario, where the supplier is aware of what is going on but nevertheless remains trapped in the relationship because of a power imbalance and a strong dependence. In addition, despite the recent widespread use of the term ‘dark side’ in business relationships, little critique of the literature and empirical research has been offered (Abosag et al., 2016, p. 5). In response to the above, and to fill the knowledge gap, the empirical focus is notions of power imbalance in a developing country, looking at the cocoa raw material market, comprising an upstream supply chain marketplace of growers with customers who eventually are tiered within developed marketplaces. Our goal is to highlight the impact of power in business relationships regarding the ‘dark side’ phenomenon and how it erodes the gains of suppliers in agri-food supply chains. The research objectives of this study are several. We seek to examine: (1) how dependency and high switching costs in agri-food supplier–buyer exchanges influence perceptions of power imbalance; (2) the conditions under which power imbalance provide ideal situations for unethical behaviours; (3) the consequences of power imbalance, opportunistic behaviour and decision control; and (4) to provide theoretical contributions, managerial insights and implications.
The Ghanaian cocoa supply market is the empirical context. The paper concerns the relationship between buying agents, who are intermediaries between cocoa growers and the buying firms. Several events have been reported of unscrupulous conduct by various buying agents who undervalue sales from cocoa growers (Dadzie et al., 2018). The financial loss caused by inaccurate weighing of produce can be a source of cognitive distrust (Dadzie et al., 2018). The global cocoa-chocolate market is estimated to reach $140 billion by 2024. Ghana is the second leading exporter of cocoa globally (Dadzie et al., 2018; Oomes et al., 2016). The national supply market has strong interconnections to the global cocoa-chocolate market. The power relations in the Ghanaian context are similar to several cocoa-producing countries, which strengthens the generalizability of our results. The global cocoa-chocolate supply chain is a complex network of cocoa growers, traders, exporters, converters/grinders, chocolate manufacturers, and retail chains. Based on our findings from a quantitative study administered in this industry, we argue that the investment in positive elements by businesses alone is not adequate, as business partners must protect suppliers against detrimental actions and behaviours.
The rest of the article is organized as follows: in the next section, we review the literature and present the research hypotheses. This is followed by the research methods, results, and the discussion. We conclude with the limitations and suggestions for further research.

Literature Review and Research Hypotheses

Dark Side of Business Relationships

No business relationships are absolutely light or dark, but instead embody a mix of these two (Abosag et al., 2016). Previous literature (e.g. Håkansson and Snehota, 1998) emphasizes the dark side as deriving from the value of relationships. The literature (e.g. Abosag et al., 2016) has identified various situations that constitute the dark side, such as relationship unrest (Good & Evans, 2001), relationship burdens (Håkansson and Snehota, 1998), relationship stress (Holmlund-Rytkönen & Strandvik, 2005), the adverse sides of business relationships (Strandvik & Holmlund, 2008), relational misconduct (Hawkins et al., 2008), detrimental intentions (Liu et al., 2014), and exploitative business relationships (Schleper et al., 2017).
The concept of a ‘dark side’ to business relationships suggests “‘problems’, ‘challenges’, ‘difficulties’, and ‘drawbacks’ related to structural issues … such as size differences, or the imbalance of power; processes within business relationships, including creativity issues, capability development, changes in market dynamics; and outputs, for example, performance, competitiveness and satisfaction” (Abosag et al., 2016, p. 5). The dark side relates to negative business situations (e.g. Gaski, 1984; John, 1984). Regarding collaboration in service networks, the dark side refers to those aspects of co-creation activities that are hidden and include potential risks in business interactions (Chowdhury et al., 2016). Resource integration activities lead to value co-creation; however, particular relevance is the co-destruction of value which aligns with the dark side of business relationships. This assertion comes from the recognition that engaging in value co-creation may not always lead to symmetrical value outcome or desirable outcome (Dong et al., 2008; Chowdhury et al., 2016). Value can be co-destroyed when resources are accidentally or intentionally misused (Plé & Cáceres, 2010). Moving beyond power and dependence in dyadic relationships to a focus on triads and the wider network in supply chains, we argue that cooperative and joint actions have the potential of limiting the undesirable effects of the dark side. This is because even close dyadic relationships that seem to be the most stable are vulnerable to the dark side phenomenon (Anderson & Jap, 2005). The light side implies that positive benefits and desirable outcomes are derived from the relationship; it denotes the situation in which good relationship quality yields achievable relationship functions and performance (Fang et al., 2011).

Theories of Power

Power is the ability of one channel member (A) to get another channel member (B) to do something that it otherwise would not have done (Coughlan et al., 2006; Dahl, 1957; Gaski, 1984). It refers to the capability of a partner in an exchange to induce another partner to change its behaviour in favour of the objectives of the partner exerting the influence (Wilemon, 1972). The association between power and dependence is better understood from Emerson's (1962) theory. We use ‘dependence’ and ‘dependency’ interchangeably with the same meaning and intended purpose. Dependency exists between two channel members when the benefits derived from their relationship are not available outside it. Thus, A’s power over B increases with B’s dependence on A. In imbalanced power relationships, the weaker firm is highly dependent on a more powerful firm or its agent to continue to achieve its goals. Whenever one partner (i.e. the principal) depends on another (i.e. the agent) to undertake some action on the principal’s behalf, this leads to a principal–agent relationship (Eisenhardt, 1989; Fontrodona & Sison, 2006). Power and dependence in exchange relationships lead to vulnerability, and the possibility of one partner or its agent being opportunistic and unethical. Dependence is a function of the greater utility (i.e. value, benefits, satisfaction) that B gets from A and the fewer alternative sources of that utility that B can find. It has to do with how easily B can replace A. The dependence condition creates a relational trap in which the weak partner has no choice but to endure the opportunism of the other (Grandinetti, 2017).
To varying extents, firms always depend on their trading partner. Early studies on dependence focused on the effects for the buyer of its dependence on the supplier, without considering the supplier’s dependency (e.g. El-Ansary & Stern, 1972). A few studies have incorporated dependence from the perspective of both the buyer and the supplier (Buchanan, 1992; Geyskens et al., 1996; Kumar et al., 1995). Dependence is defined, in psychology and social psychology, as a state in which assistance from others in terms of finance, emotion, protection, security or daily care, is expected or actively sought (Zhou et al., 2007). In the context of buyer–seller relationships and channel studies, dependence refers to the extent to which a trade partner provides important and critical resources for which there are few alternative sources of supply (Buchanan, 1992), or “the degree to which the target firm needs to maintain its relationship with the source in order to achieve its desired goals” (Kale, 1986, p. 390).

Research Hypotheses

Dependence, Power Imbalance and Financial Performance

In asymmetric relationships, the more independent partner dominates the exchange. Balanced relationships refer to domination by neither party (Buchanan, 1992). Kumar et al. (1995) use the term ‘interdependence asymmetry’, defined as the difference between the two partners’ levels of dependence. Symmetrical interdependence exists when parties are equally dependent on one another. In asymmetric interdependence, the independent partner experiences high power and might be attempted to exploit it (Geyskens et al., 1996). Therefore, power imbalances within a buyer–supplier relationship can lead to unproductive partnerships (McDonald, 1999) and hence low economic benefits. In most buyer–seller relationships, disparities in turnover or values of sales and the size of the supplier compared to the buying company place the supplier in a less powerful exchange position. The buying companies are more powerful and have the leading role in respect of relationship administration and allocation of rewards (Griffith et al., 2006). Furthermore, the annual value of total sales from a supplier to a buyer is an indication of the economic rewards that the supplier receives for the sacrifice of forgoing alternative exchange relationships. Based on the theory review and reasoning proffered here, we posit that:
H1a
The effect of supplier dependency on power imbalance is moderated by transaction/sales volume.
H1b
The effect of power imbalance on financial performance is moderated by supplier dependency.

Effect of Switching Costs on Power Imbalance

An imbalance of power within the buyer–supplier relationship may lead not only to dissension by the offended partner but to a low performance by the aggrieved partner. In such situations, the social capital built up within the relationship may deteriorate. Switching costs, defined as the need to maintain a relationship due to latent costs that would be incurred if that relationship were to end (Scheer et al., 2015), is a key variable impacting on dependency and hence performance. Partners’ investment in terms of time, effort, and money, along with perceived costs of switching, can contribute to dependency (Emerson, 1962; Scheer et al., 2015) and hence high perceptions of power imbalance. Supplier-perceived relationship value had been found to be negatively related to intention to switch, while support for the negative association between switching costs and switching intention has been supported (Geiger et al., 2012). Dabholkar et al. (1994) paper on the dynamics of long-term business-to-business exchange relationships suggests that exchange relationships are formed by achieving mutually beneficial outcomes from a series of exchange transactions. The authors propose a curvilinear relationship between relative power and gains (relationship outcomes) at high switching costs levels. Many micro and small businesses dealing with the more powerful large firms lack the resources to seek alternative business relationships. The more difficult it is for, the weaker partner to switch, the more vulnerable partner perceives the power differential. The more powerful and dominant firm begins the exchange relationship from a power advantage; however, as the exchange relationship develops from transactional to closer and long-term mutual relationship, power imbalance impact diminishes. However, as it becomes more difficult for the weaker partner to switch due to high dependency on the more powerful partner, the two partner's power differential becomes more obvious temporally. Therefore, we expect a U-shaped relationship between switching costs and power imbalance. Based on the above argument, we hypothesize that in a captive supplier–buyer relationship:
H2a
Switching costs are associated with increased power imbalance.
H2b
The association between switching costs and power imbalance could be curvilinear.

Effect of Power Imbalance on Opportunism

The risk of opportunistic behaviour creates uncertainty, thereby requiring some level of cooperative effort to ensure a successful relationship (Rokkan & Buvik, 2003). Opportunism refers to a self-seeking phenomenon characterized by exploitation (John, 1984; Williamson, 1985). Numerous examples of opportunistic behaviour have been documented. A few examples include salespeople exaggerating expenditure reports (Philips, 1982); resellers violating explicit resale agreements (Dutta et al., 1994); physicians prescribing excessive quantities of expensive drugs to patients (The Economist, 1996); and inaccurate weighing of produce by buying agents (Dadzie et al., 2018). It is logical to assume that the power differential between trading partners could provide a conducive environment for opportunistic and unethical behaviour (Ireland and Webb, 2007). A dependence power advantage is one of the most cited antecedents of opportunism in the inter-firm relationship literature (Grandinetti, 2017; Hawkins et al., 2008; Tangpong et al., 2015; Wang & Yang, 2013). Previous studies had shown that opportunism’s association with other variables could be curvilinear, for example, opportunism and performance (Lado et al., 2008), opportunism and goal exceedance (El Meladi et al., 2018), opportunism and punishment severity (Xiao et al., 2019), and opportunism and guanxi (Shen et al., 2019). Drawing on the long-term perspective of Dabholkar et al. (1994) and the relationship development cycle (Dwyer et al., 1987), opportunism is expected to be low at the relationship initiation stage but, as the relationship develops and power relations become obvious, the partner or its agent with the higher power could easily use the power advantage to exploit the weaker partner. Consequently, we expect an inverted U-shaped relationship between power imbalance and opportunism. In view of the above deliberations, we hypothesize that:
H3a
Power imbalance is associated with increased opportunism.
H3b
The association between power imbalance and opportunism could be curvilinear.

Effects of Power Imbalance and Opportunism on Financial Performance

Power plays an important role in the supply chain, judicious use of power may serve to benefit the power holder (Benton & Maloni, 2005). Lavan (2007) suggests that cocoa farmers in Ghana do not benefit much economically from their farm businesses because of their inability to organize themselves. The suppliers lack a strong voice with the requisite bargaining power to negotiate with the state regulator and the buying firms they deal with. Hence, it is expected that cooperative marketing membership could increase the bargaining power of suppliers to counteract the disadvantages associated with a power imbalance. We define a cooperative as the use of collective action through participation in a voluntary venture by a group of individuals or independent enterprises with the aim of achieving benefits through the coordination of activities such as logistics, purchasing, and marketing. In supplier–buyer relationships, gains accruing to exchange partners reflect how profitable the exchange process has been regarding performance. Exploitation of the relative power of the buying company or its personnel/agent is therefore expected to lead to dissatisfaction and reduce financial gains for the weaker partner. Small-scale farm businesses can collaborate to diminish the influence or unscrupulousness of intermediaries and businesses. Meier zu Selhausen (2016) suggests that active involvement in agricultural marketing and collaborative efforts help less dominant suppliers to overcome exploitation. In line with the above reasoning, we hypothesize that in a captive supplier–buyer relationship:
H4a
Power imbalance is associated with reduced financial performance.
H4b
The effect of power imbalance on reducing financial performance is stronger for non-cooperative members than for cooperative members.
H4c
Buyer/agent opportunism is associated with reduced supplier financial performance.

Effects of Buyer Control of Price and Quality on Financial Performance

Decision control in terms of buyer control has been conceptualized as the extent to which the buyer has authority and control over supplier decision-making (Buvik & Andersen, 2015). It refers to centralization of the decision-making authority. In this study, buyer control refers to the ability of one partner to influence and control the other in relation to channel activities. Control as a governance mechanism is used to regulate trading and overcome performance measurement complexities linked to mutual dependence (Williamson, 1985). Supplier dependency on the buyer creates power imbalance situations where the shift in power favours the buyer. The power differential augments the buyer’s ability to control the decisions of the supplier (Anderson & Weitz, 1989; Emerson, 1962; Joshi, 1998). Price control by the power source could lead to low gains for weaker channel members (Belaya & Hanf, 2009; Hingley, 2005a; Maglaras et al., 2015). However, control of quality through standardization could lead to beneficial outcomes. The Japanese are known for their emphasis on quality, such that suppliers of large manufacturers such as Toyota must meet stringent quality standards to improve performance. In demanding quality improvements from vendors, in many cases companies will use only suppliers that have passed the expensive and time-consuming ISO 9000 certification (Krause et al., 2007). Based on the above reasoning, we hypothesize that in a captive supplier–buyer relationship:
H5a
Buyer control of price is associated with reduced financial performance.
H5b
Quality standardization is associated with increased financial performance.
H5c
The effect of power imbalance on financial performance is moderated by quality standardization.

Effect of Economic Satisfaction on Financial Performance

Supplier satisfaction is defined as a supplier’s cognitive and affective state of feeling sufficiently rewarded economically and psychosocially for the sacrifices undergone in facilitating the exchange relationship, no matter what power imbalance may exist between the supplier and the buyer (Benton & Maloni, 2005). In this study, we consider satisfaction as a two-dimensional construct consisting of economic and non-economic or social satisfaction (Ferro et al., 2016; Geyskens & Steenkamp, 2000; Rodriguez et al., 2006). Economic satisfaction refers to a channel member’s evaluation of the economic outcomes that result from the relationship, while non-economic or social satisfaction refers to the psychosocial, non-economic aspects of the relationship, in that interaction with the exchange partner is fulfilling, gratifying, and characterized by tranquillity (Geyskens et al., 1999). Social exchange theory posits that exchange may involve both economic and social outcomes. The need for “consistent delivery of economic and psychosocial benefits in each transaction” within the exchange process is critical for the sustenance of relational exchanges (Dwyer et al., 1987, p. 25). A supplier that is satisfied economically evaluates the relationship as being successful in terms of goal attainment, relationship effectiveness and productivity (Geyskens et al., 1999), including financial results. An exchange partner’s perception of being sufficiently rewarded economically is key in imbalanced business relationships. The use of collective action through participation in marketing cooperatives is expected to offset asymmetrical power relations and to improve the welfare of its members. We hypothesize that in a captive supplier–buyer relationship:
H6a
Economic satisfaction is associated with increased financial performance.
H6b
The effect of economic satisfaction on financial performance is stronger for cooperative members than for non-cooperative members.

Research Methods

Research Setting and Data Collection

The context is the cocoa industry of Ghana. Certain cocoa-producing countries have a fully liberated local market with a free-market system characterized by many private exporters. While in others (e.g. Ghana) private, former state marketing monopolies retain substantial control and play ‘coordinative’ role in chain governance (Glavee-Geo, 2019). In Ghana, the industry is partially liberated, characterized by the participation of private firms and many cocoa growers as the main suppliers. The industry regulator is the Ghana Cocoa Board (COCOBOD).
We collected primary data from the cocoa growers, who were very knowledgeable about the issues at stake. The respondents were either farm owners or farm managers serving as key informants. We based the sampling on farms located in the southern part of Ghana according to the knowledge of the industry regulator. Approval was sought from each informant before each interview. Subsequently, primary data were collected through face-to-face interviews. In most developing and some emerging countries, data collection through mail or email leads to low response rates—hence the need for some other innovative means of data collection through household interviews. The lead author conducted the interviews for study 1 over a period of two weeks and for study 2 a year later for a period of five weeks in the cocoa-growing regions of Central, Eastern, and Ashanti regions of Ghana. The respondents were mostly farm owners who were interviewed in their houses (sometimes with a farm manager providing corroborative information). Study 1 consisted of 105 respondents while study 2 consisted of 444 respondents.

Operational Measures

All constructs are based on reflective multi-item scales adapted from previously validated scales (see Tables 1 and 2). The indicators are measured on a seven-point Likert scale, with 1 representing the lowest level (strongly disagree) and 7 the highest level (strongly agree). Subjective measures of supplier financial performance are newly formulated, while the profitability measure is adapted from Haugland et al. (2007). The difficulty in accessing financial data makes the use of subjective measures of performance a better proxy to evaluate the performance of a supplying firm. The three-item scale of supplier financial performance is formulated with the anchors 1, representing worse performance, and 7, representing better performance. Single-item indicators of the relative size of the buyer, relationship duration, transaction/sales volume, supplier dependency, switching costs and buyer control of price were formulated based on the extant literature (e.g. Buvik & Andersen, 2015; Caniels & Gelderman, 2007). A single item—‘this buying company ensures that the minimum producer price does not vary’—measured buyer control of price. Supplier dependency was measured with the question ‘how large do you perceive your dependency on this particular buying company compared to other buying companies within this district?’ Switching costs were measured with ‘how much will it cost you if you want to replace this buying company with another one in a new location?’ The quality standardization item was formulated based on buyer control measures by Buvik and Andersen (2015). Power imbalance items were adapted from Joshi and Stump (1999). In study 1, power imbalance items were operationalized based on two main questions: ‘how large were your sales to this buying company?’ and ‘how large do you perceive the cash bonuses paid by this buying company to your farm business?’ However, in study 2, we sought to improve measurement of the power imbalance through reformulation of the two additional questions from study 1. Reliability results of studies 1 and 2 show the power imbalance scales had high internal consistency and extracted more than 50% of the variance in each instance (see Tables 1 and 2). Membership of cooperatives in study 2 was measured with the question ‘are you a member of any cooperative farmers association?’ with responses coded as a dummy, 1 for ‘yes’ and 0 for ‘no’. Opportunism items were adapted from John (1984) and Skarmeas et al. (2002). Five items were used in study 1, while seven items were used in study 2 with the same intended purpose of achieving good internal consistency. Economic satisfaction items were adapted from Geyskens and Steenkamp (2000) and Skinner et al. (1992), social satisfaction items from Benton and Maloni (2005) and Crosby et al. (1990).
Table 1
Construct, reliability, average variance extracted, descriptive statistics, loadings, t-values (n = 105)
Construct
Indicators
M
SD
Loadings
t-value #
Power imbalance
CR = 0.90
α = 0.78
AVE = 0.82
With respect to sales volume during the last twelve months…
    
How large were your sales to this buying company?
5.67
1.58
0.938
23.840***
How large do you perceive cash bonuses paid by this buying company to your farm business?
5.58
1.26
0.870
19.163***
Buyer/agent opportunism
CR = 0.84
α = 0.77
AVE = 0.52
The buying company often undervalues my cocoa beans
4.24
2.13
0.507
2.962**
The buying company often underrates the quality of my cocoa beans
4.29
2.11
0.842
5.939***
The buying company often neglects to correct sales’ errors in my transactions
4.47
2.13
0.801
5.645***
The buying company often weighs my cocoa beans as less than their actual weight.
3.78
1.92
0.777
5.786***
The buying company often pays less cash bonus than I deserve
3.43
2.26
0.627
4.180***
Supplier financial performance
CR = 0.90
α = 0.83
AVE = 0.75
Compared to other farm businesses, my farm business has performed relatively well during the last six months in the following respects
    
Profitability
5.86
1.32
0.881
30.787***
Return on investment
5.88
1.26
0.909
37.774***
Debt repayment
5.77
1.14
0.798
17.773***
Quality standardization
CR = 0.88
α = 0.83
AVE = 0.65
This buyer makes sure the quality of the cocoa I sell is okay before taking possession
5.99
1.05
0.919
8.569***
This buyer takes control of the product for quality inspection
5.96
1.20
0.733
6.629***
This buyer ensures that the quality test is passed
5.93
1.03
0.773
4.865***
This buyer always rejects poor quality cocoa sold to their company
5.89
1.31
0.798
4.458***
Economic satisfaction
CR = 0.86
α = 0.76
AVE = 0.67
My relationship with this buying company is very attractive with respect to prompt payment of cash bonuses
5.49
1.65
0.824
14.788***
I am very pleased with my decision to sell to this buyer due to the financial benefits the company provides my farm business
5.88
1.22
0.837
18.205***
I am very satisfied with the price at which I sell my cocoa to this buying company
5.50
1.54
0.802
12.971***
Social satisfaction
CR = 0.91
α = 0.86
AVE = 0.77
I am satisfied with dealing with this buying company
5.73
1.57
0.909
11.636***
I would always continue selling to this buying company because of the good personal relationship I have with the staff
5.87
1.59
0.810
7.131***
I am always pleased to deal with this buying company
6.10
1.28
0.919
13.212***
CR composite reliability, α Cronbach’s alpha, AVE average variance extracted, M mean, SD standard deviation
#Based on 5000 bootstrapping samples: ***significant at p < 0.001, **significant at p < 0.01 (two-tailed test)
Table 2
Construct, reliability, average variance extracted, descriptive statistics, loadings, t-values (n = 444)
Construct
Indicators
M
SD
Loadings
t-value #
Power imbalance
CR = 0.90
α = 0.86
AVE = 0.70
The buying company enjoys more power in our relationship owing to my small sales volume
5.38
1.43
0.816
28.385***
The buying company enjoys more power in our relationship because the volume percentage supplied is small
5.50
1.36
0.903
68.690***
The buying company enjoys more power in our relationship because my cash bonus percentage is small
5.47
1.44
0.816
31.346***
Overall, this buying firm has more power than my farm business
5.60
1.44
0.806
27.437***
Buyer/agent opportunism
CR = 0.87
α = 0.86
AVE = 0.81
The buying company often pays less cash for the supplied cocoa beans
4.38
1.92
0.878
59.082***
The buying company often pays less cash bonus than I deserve
4.62
1.89
0.925
76.581***
The buying company often undervalues my cocoa beans
4.68
1.94
0.903
72.195***
The buying company often underrates the quality of my cocoa beans
4.31
1.93
0.904
71.480***
The buying company often neglects to correct sales’ errors in my transactions
4.41
1.86
0.912
82.731***
The buying company often weighs my cocoa beans as less than their actual weight
4.58
1.86
0.882
58.423***
Overall, the buying company often pays less cash bonus than I deserve
5.60
1.92
0.912
86.376***
Supplier financial performance CR = 0.93
α = 0.89
AVE = 0.82
Compared to other farm businesses ,my farm business has performed relatively well during the last six months in the following respects
    
Profitability
4.67
1.48
0.917
100.236***
Return on investment
4.78
1.45
0.925
105.192***
Debt repayment
4.83
1.47
0.870
43.712***
Economic satisfaction CR = 0.93 α = 0.90 AVE = 0.72
My relationship with this buying company has been very beneficial to my farm enterprise
5.39
1.32
0.783
27.365***
 
My relationship with this buying company is very attractive concerning prompt payment of cash bonuses
5.34
1.44
0.881
60.071***
 
I am very pleased with my decision to sell to this buyer due to the financial benefits in the form of soft loans
5.27
1.45
0.896
81.205***
 
I would recommend that other farmers sell their products to this buying company to benefit financially
5.13
1.46
0.886
87.448***
 
I am always very satisfied with the amount of cash bonus paid to me by this buying company
4.91
1.51
0.807
41.630***
Social satisfaction
CR = 0.96
α = 0.94
AVE = 0.81
I have a favourable relationship with this buying company’s personnel
4.76
1.49
0.849
45.231***
I am satisfied with dealing with this buying company
4.75
1.58
0.904
82.119***
I would always continue selling to this buying company because of the good personal relationship I have with the staff
4.67
1.62
0.926
127.786***
This buying company is good to do business with
4.65
1.65
0.918
109.815***
I am always pleased to deal with this buying company
4.71
1.61
0.910
100.417***
CR composite reliability, α Cronbach’s alpha, AVE average variance extracted, M mean, SD standard deviation
#Based on 10,000 bootstrapping samples: ***significant at p < 0.001 (two-tailed test)

Estimation

We conducted the estimation using the partial least squares (PLS) structural equation modelling technique SmartPLS 3.0 (Ringle et al., 2015). PLS’ strength lies in its ability to deal with complex models with a high number of constructs, indicators and relationships (Hair et al., 2017). It is less strict with assumptions about the distribution of the data and equally ideal for small sample size (Chin & Newsted, 1999; Hair et al., 2017). The use of categorical variables with unknown non-normal frequency distribution, which are usually negatively skewed, makes PLS preferable. The preceding factors make it an ideal analytical technique for the current study and hence a preferable alternative to the use of maximum likelihood methods.

Results

Descriptive Statistics, Measurement Reliability and Validity

The descriptive statistics of the variables (mean and standard deviation), factor loadings, reliability, and average variance extracted (AVE) of the constructs for study 1 and 2 are presented in Tables 1 and 2.
The standardized loadings for the indicators and bootstrap t-values for all the items used in both study 1 and study 2 (see Tables 1 and 2) were all significant at 0.001 in the two-tailed test, except the item ‘The buying company often undervalues my cocoa beans’, which is significant at p < 0.01 (Table 1). All Cronbach’s alphas exceed the 0.7 threshold (Nunnally, 1978), while composite reliabilities (Fornell & Larcker, 1981) are higher than 0.8, showing high internal consistency. The average variance extracted (AVE) (Fornell & Larcker, 1981) exceeds 0.50, the lowest being 0.52 for the construct buyer/agent opportunism in study 1 and the highest 0.82 for the constructs supplier financial performance (study 2) and power imbalance (study 1) (see Tables 1 and 2). A higher AVE indicates that the variance captured by each latent variable is significantly larger than the variance due to measurement error, demonstrating unidimensionality and high convergent validity of the constructs.
We assessed discriminant validity (Chin, 1998; Fornell & Larcker, 1981) by comparing the square root of the AVE for each construct with the correlations of all other constructs in the model (see Tables 3 and 4). A correlation between constructs exceeding the square roots of their AVE indicates that they may not be sufficiently discriminable (Coelho & Henseler, 2012; Hair et al., 2017). A comparison of the square root of the AVE (bold face diagonal values) and the correlations among the constructs shows that the square roots of AVE are always higher than the absolute correlations between the constructs. We also checked the heterotrait–monotrait ratio of correlations and found all the values were under 0.85, demonstrating high discriminant validity (Henseler et al., 2015). We conclude that the measurement models for study 1 and study 2 show evidence of acceptable validity.
Table 3
Discriminant validity coefficients (n = 105)
 
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
Buyer control of price (1)
1.00
           
Quality standardization (2)
0.00
0.81
          
Economic satisfaction (3)
0.16
0.28
0.82
         
Power imbalance (4)
0.19
− 0.06
− 0.19
0.91
        
Relationship duration (5)
− 0.16
0.14
0.06
− 0.02
1.00
       
Social satisfaction (6)
0.11
0.30
0.65
0.02
0.11
0.88
      
Supplier financial performance (7)
− 0.16
0.39
0.46
− 0.31
0.04
0.21
0.86
     
Switching costs (8)
0.04
− 0.40
− 0.22
0.21
− 0.08
− 0.18
− 0.33
1.00
    
Relative size of buyer (9)
0.08
− 0.15
− 0.15
0.16
− 0.10
− 0.21
− 0.22
0.30
1.00
   
Sales volume (10)
− 0.07
0.51
0.06
− 0.04
0.23
− 0.02
0.23
− 0.12
0.05
1.00
  
Supplier dependency (11)
− 0.13
− 0.15
− 0.02
0.19
0.10
− 0.06
− 0.21
0.38
0.25
0.01
1.00
 
Buyer/agent opportunism (12)
− 0.04
− 0.16
0.32
0.16
0.01
0.27
0.22
0.09
− 0.11
− 0.21
0.04
0.72
Bold numbers on the diagonals shows the square root of the AVE; numbers below the diagonal represent construct correlations. Single measure constructs have an average variance extracted of one, with the assumption that they fully measure the latent variable
Table 4
Discriminant validity coefficients (n = 444)
 
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
Economic satisfaction (1)
0.85
      
Power imbalance (2)
0.02
0.83
     
Relationship duration (3)
0.17
− 0.02
1.00
    
Social satisfaction (4)
0.61
− 0.11
0.09
0.90
   
Supplier financial performance (5)
0.36
− 0.31
0.30
0.33
0.90
  
Sales volume (6)
0.20
− 0.04
0.30
0.27
0.64
1.00
 
Buyer/agent opportunism (7)
0.27
0.18
0.02
0.29
0.04
0.05
0.90
Bold numbers on the diagonals shows the square root of the AVE; numbers below the diagonal represent construct correlations. Single measure constructs have an average variance extracted of one, with the assumption that they fully measure the latent variable

Common Method Variance

Common method bias (CMV) is variance attributable to the measurement method rather than to the constructs, this is because the data for all the model variables came from the same respondents at the same time. CMV might influence some of the hypothesized relations in the structural model (Podsakoff et al., 2003; Podsakoff & Organ, 1986). To avoid bias from CMV, we applied an a priori method (Hulland et al., 2018). This was done by careful design of the questionnaire and formulation of the question instruments. During the data collection, we conducted the interviews for both studies by asking the questions in a random order: this ensured that the dependent and independent variables in the survey were separated. Before the administration of both surveys, we pre-tested the questionnaire. The pre-test helped us avoid ambiguous question items that could be difficult to understand or interpret. Taking these steps prior to administering the survey helped to limit the potential for CMV.

Structural Model Estimation Results

The structural model results of study 1 (n = 105) and study 2 (n = 444) were estimated using SmartPLS 3 (Ringle et al., 2015). To evaluate the structural models of both studies, we first assessed the structural models for collinearity (Hair et al., 2017) by examining the variance inflation factor (VIF) values of all the predictor constructs. We found all the VIF values to be below the threshold of 3.3 (Diamantopoulos & Siguaw, 2006). We concluded that collinearity was not at critical levels (Table 5). Thereafter, we examined the significance and relevance of the path coefficients based on the results of the bootstrapping procedure with 10,000 subsamples (Franke & Sarstedt, 2019).
Table 5
Structural model results, effect sizes (f2) and collinearity (VIF) (n = 105)
Criterion
R2
Predictors
Path coefficient
t-values#
f2
VIF
Power imbalance
0.17
Switching costs
0.10
0.95
0.01
1.36
  
Supplier dependency
− 0.04
0.39
0.00
1.50
  
Relationship duration
0.09
1.13
0.01
1.22
  
Sales volume
− 0.07
0.64
0.01
1.16
  
Relative size of buyer
0.16
1.63a
0.02
1.26
  
Supplier dependency × sales volume
0.45
2.93**
0.10
1.40
  
Switching costs × switching costs
0.17
2.52*
0.06
1.50
Buyer/agent opportunism
0.17
Power imbalance
− 0.17
1.01
0.02
1.83
  
Power imbalance × power imbalance
− 0.28
3.71***
0.17
1.83
Supplier financial performance
0.54
Power imbalance
− 0.24
2.65**
0.09
1.41
 
Buyer/agent opportunism
0.07
0.75
0.01
1.62
  
Quality standardization
0.28
2.76**
0.13
1.40
  
Buyer control of price
− 0.18
2.69**
0.06
1.21
  
Economic satisfaction
0.43
3.49***
0.17
2.32
  
Social satisfaction
− 0.05
0.46
0.00
2.12
  
Supplier dependency
− 0.12
1.57a
0.02
1.40
  
Switching costs
0.08
0.92
0.01
1.69
  
Power imbalance × supplier dependency
− 0.23
2.49*
0.06
1.38
  
Power imbalance × quality standardization
0.27
3.17**
0.14
1.33
Quality standardizationc
 
Power imbalance
− 0.06
0.49
0.00
1.00
Buyer control of pricec
 
Power imbalance
0.19
2.24*
0.04
1.00
Economic satisfactionc
 
Power imbalance
− 0.18
1.92b
0.03
1.00
Social satisfactionc
 
Power imbalance
0.03
0.22
0.00
1.00
aSignificant at p < 0.10 (one-tailed test)
bSignificant at p < 0.05 (one-tailed test)
cR2 values are negligible
#Based on 5000 bootstrapping samples: ***significant at p < 0.001 level (two-tailed test); **significant at p < 0.01 (two-tailed test); *significant at p < 0.05 (two-tailed test)

Dependence, Power Imbalance, and Financial Performance

Our analysis shows support for the interaction effect between supplier dependency and sales volume (H1a: β = 0.45, t = 2.93, p < 0.01) and hence provides empirical support for the moderating effect of transaction volume between supplier dependency and power imbalance. In addition, we found support for H1b (β = − 0.23, t = 2.49, p < 0.05) and conclude that the effect of power imbalance on financial performance is moderated by supplier dependency (see Table 5).
Graphical representation of the support for H1a and H1b is shown in Figs. 1 and 2. The simple slope analysis of the effect of supplier dependency on power imbalance at various levels of transaction volume shows that for suppliers of large volumes of sales, dependency increases perceptions of power imbalance, while for suppliers of small transaction volumes, the opposite applies. Figure 2 illustrate the simple slope analysis of the effect of power imbalance on supplier financial performance at various levels of supplier dependency. Figure 2 shows that at high levels of dependency, power imbalance has a negative effect on financial performance.

Switching costs, power imbalance, and opportunism

We did not find support for H2a, which states that switching costs are associated with increased power imbalance (H2a: β = 0.10, t = 0.95, p > 0.05); however, we found support for H2b, which shows that the association between switching costs and power imbalance could be curvilinear. Figure 3 illustrates the quadratic slope analysis of the effect of switching costs on power imbalance.
Hypothesis 3a states that power imbalance is associated with increased opportunism: in other words, power imbalance is positively associated with opportunism. H3a was supported by study 2 (see Table 6). Furthermore, our results from study 1 (see Table 5) provide support for H3b, which posits that the association between power imbalance and opportunism could be curvilinear (β = − 0.28, t = 3.71, p < 0.001). Figure 4 shows the inverted U-shaped curve which illustrates that the effect of power imbalance on opportunism increases to a point and then decreases.
Table 6
Structural model results and t-statistic for multigroup analysis
Criterion
Predictors
Combined (n = 444)
Non-cooperative membership
(n = 301)
Cooperative membership
(n = 143)
β1 β2
t-value
Path coefficient (β)
t-value#
Path coefficient (β1)
t-value
Path coefficient (β2)
t-value
Power imbalance
Relationship duration
0.03
0.60
0.01
0.02
0.02
0.27
0.01
0.10
 
Sales volume
− 0.19
3.92***
− 0.04
0.65
0.11
1.10
0.15
1.34
Buyer/agent opportunism
Power imbalance
0.18
4.50***
0.17
3.23**
0.19
2.78**
0.03
0.31
Supplier financial performance
Power imbalance
− 0.03
0.64
− 0.15
3.21**
0.25
2.74**
0.40
4.37***
Buyer/agent opportunism
− 0.08
1.64a
− 0.06
1.01
− 0.13
1.47
0.07
0.68
 
Economic satisfaction
0.26
4.66***
0.37
5.71***
0.09
0.92
0.27
2.37*
 
Social satisfaction
0.20
3.46***
0.10
1.36
0.32
3.58***
0.22
1.82
Economic satisfaction
Power imbalance
0.02
0.32
0.07
0.96
− 0.07
0.62
0.14
1.07
Social satisfaction
Power imbalance
− 0.11
2.33*
− 0.11
1.67a
− 0.09
0.89
0.02
0.18
#Based on 10,000 bootstrapping samples: ***significant at p < 0.001 level (two-tailed test); **significant at p < 0.01 (two-tailed test); *significant at p < 0.05 (two-tailed test)
aSignificant at p < 0.05 (one-tailed test)

Financial Consequences of Power Imbalance and Opportunism

The objective behind the statement of the three hypotheses H4a, H4b and H4c is to explore the consequences of power imbalance and opportunism. H4a states that power imbalance is associated with reduced financial performance. We found support for H4a (β = − 0.24, t = 2.65, p < 0.01) (Table 5). H4b states that the effect of power imbalance on reducing financial performance is stronger for non-cooperative members than for cooperative members. To test H4b, we conducted a multigroup analysis based on data from study 2. The results of the multigroup analysis (Table 6) showed significant differences (β1 - β2 = 0.40, p < 0.001) between both groups, such that the effect of power imbalance on reducing financial performance is stronger for the non-cooperative members (β = − 0.15, p < 0.01) than for cooperative members (β = 0.25, p < 0.01). Concerning H4c, buyer/agent opportunism was found to be associated with reduced supplier financial performance (β = − 0.08, t = 1.64, p < 0.05) (Table 6).

Financial Consequences of Buyer Control of Price and Quality Standardization

From our analysis (Table 5), we found that power imbalance increased price control by the power source (β = 0.19, t = 2.24, p < 0.05). We suggest that buyer control of price is associated with reduced financial performance (H5a), while buyer control of quality in terms of quality standardization is associated with higher financial performance (H5b). We found support for both H5a (β = − 0.18, t = 2.69, p < 0.01) and H5b (β = 0.28, t = 2.76, p < 0.01). For H5c, we hypothesized that the effect of power imbalance on financial performance is moderated by quality standardization. The objective behind H5c was to determine the role played by decision control in the association between imbalance in power and reward. Our analysis shows that decision control regarding quality standardization can enhance the coordinative role of power in improving performance. Hence, we found support for H5c (β = 0.27, t = 3.17, p < 0.01) (see Table 5). We illustrate the test for H5c with a simple slope analysis, as shown in Fig. 5. At low levels of quality standardization, power imbalance reduces financial performance.

Linking Psychosocial Satisfaction and Collective Action with Reward

From our analysis (Table 5), we found that power imbalance decreased economic satisfaction (β = − 0.18, t = 1.92, p < 0.05). We propose that economic satisfaction is associated with increased financial performance (H6a) and suggest that the effect of economic satisfaction on financial performance is stronger for cooperative members than for non-cooperative members (H6b). We found support for the positive effect of economic satisfaction on financial performance (β = 0.43, t = 3.49, p < 0.001) (Table 5). The multigroup analysis, however, does not support H6b. Though we found significant differences (β1β2 = 0.27, p < 0.05) between the two groups, the effect of economic satisfaction on financial performance was found to be stronger for non-cooperative members (n = 301, β = 0.37, p < 0.001) than for cooperative members (n = 143, β = 0.09, p > 0.05) (Table 6).

Discussion

Understanding how power asymmetry can provide a conducive environment for unethical behaviours is important in managing buyer–seller relationships in contemporary supply chains. Suppliers in captive agri-food supplier–buyer exchange relationships are highly dependent on buyers while having limited alternative outbound supply/marketing options. These suppliers are also exposed to performance risk and exploitation (Dadzie et al., 2018). We highlight the theoretical contributions and managerial implications of the study.

Theoretical Contributions

Though a substantial number of studies have looked at the role of power and dependency in business exchanges and relationships, the role that power and dependency play in the dark side phenomenon is less understood. This implies that the mechanisms of the dark side phenomenon are not fully explained, and therefore our knowledge of these negative business practices is still insufficient. Our study presents several contributions to fill the knowledge gap. The study provides empirical evidence of the moderating role of transaction volume between supplier dependency and power imbalance consistent with the literature (Anderson & Weitz, 1989; Geyskens et al., 1996). Besides, our findings show that asymmetric power relations have a negative impact on the gains of the other party in the exchange and this is further exacerbated by dependency. This is particularly true when there are few alternatives for the dependent partner, such that the relationship becomes a captive one and prone to exploitation, consistent with the literature.
The effect of switching costs in such captive relationships is equally acknowledged in the literature, highly cited as the cause and most often assumed to be a linear relationship. Our contribution to the literature shows switching costs impact in imbalanced business relationships to be curvilinear. Similarly, the association between power imbalance and opportunism has been much cited (e.g. Grandinetti, 2017; Hawkins et al., 2008; Tangpong et al., 2015), but with little evidence on whether this association is linear or curvilinear. Our study reaffirms the linear association and shows that the effect of power imbalance on opportunism could also be curvilinear.
The study also provides empirical evidence to show the consequences of the dark side phenomenon. Power imbalance is associated with reduced financial performance of the weaker partner (Chicksand, 2015; Griffith et al., 2006; Hingley, 2005a). The concept of collective action refers to an action taken by a group of people with the aim to achieve a common goal and to improve their social or economic situation. Collection action is differentiated by a group/joint action and decision instead of that of an individual. Cooperative supply and marketing associations are typical examples. Our findings show significant differences between cooperative and non-cooperative groups in relation to the impact of power imbalance on financial performance. The theoretical implication is that the negative impact of the dark side phenomenon could be averted to a greater extent with group/joint action and concerted effort.

Managerial Implications

Based on the research context, the cocoa agri-food supply market, the suppliers are heavily dependent on buyers and their agents. The impact of dependency on the power imbalance was found to be contingent on transaction volume, while the effect of power imbalance on financial performance was found to be moderated by supplier dependency. The implication is that small suppliers’ participation in collective action through supply and marketing cooperatives can help offset the asymmetrical power relations and improve individual and group welfare (Fischer & Qaim, 2012, 2014). Power can be used to control rewards to disadvantage the other party in the exchange; however, group action can provide a powerful voice for such disappointing incidents, relationship problems, and problematic business relationships. Collective action is a constructive group effort to change objectionable relationship conditions with the intent to improve conditions.
We draw on Dabholkar et al. (1994, p. 133), 'the interactions through which the terms of exchange are worked out are often referred to as the negotiation process'. Using the theory of negotiation (bargaining) behaviour (Clopton, 1984; Dabholkar et al., 1994; Perdue et al. 1986; Pruitt, 1981), negotiation behaviour can be classified along two dimensions of ''time'' and ''gain'' perspectives. Four categories of negotiation behaviour are identified: competitive, command, coordinative and cooperative. However, the terms ''cooperative'' and ''coordinative'' are used interchangeably in the literature. Competitive negotiation behaviour emphasizes individual short-term gain where parties maximize their outcomes. Command behaviour seeks out to maximize individual gain; however, the specific strategies are less 'coercive' than competitive bargaining behaviour.
Coordinative strategies focus on the long-term joint gain, while the cooperative approach is characterized by the short-term joint gain (Dabholkar et al., 1994). Though the above-negotiating strategies apply mostly to dyadic exchanges, it can also apply to network relations although more complex. Exchange relations between cocoa suppliers and lead firms can be classified along the two dimensions of short/long-term and individual/joint gain. Individual cocoa farmers dealing with lead firms and the government parastatal organization (Ghana Cocoa Board) have less bargaining power than if organized as cooperatives.
An important strategy for protecting firms from unethical behaviour is information sharing (Eckerd & Hill, 2012). The sharing of records and accounts to reduce the information asymmetry between buyer and supplier firm can help stimulate trust. This action is a critical obligation as emerging markets liberalize their agri-food supply markets and exporters compete for market share for cocoa and coffee in the originating countries (Dadzie et al., 2018). Others have recommended accredited ethical purchasing agents (Buxton & Vorley, 2012), where lead firms dealing with small suppliers can educate, train and align the objectives, incentives and motivations of their sourcing managers, frontline staff and intermediaries to be ethical with suppliers (Vorley & Thorpe, 2014). Building ethical and mutually beneficial relationships between small dependent suppliers and lead firms is an important strategy to reduce the negative consequences of exploitative business relationships and to control opportunism (Glavee-Geo et al., 2020).
Corporate ethical values (CEV) and formal ethical infrastructure are key features of an organization that can be relied on to ensure employees' attitudinal and behavioural change. This calls for clear ethically responsible purchasing practices, codes of conduct, and enforceable company policies (Saini, 2010). However, ethical codes are not enough. Hyman et al. (1990) suggests the need for a checklist for evaluating managerial decisions, and to improve the chances of being ethical. CEVs represent the amount of attention afforded to ethical issues by the firm, and the degree to which the firm behaves ethically (Hunt et al., 1989). A firm's formal ethical infrastructure (FEI) is characterized by formal communication, recurrent communication, formal surveillance, and formal sanctions and has been found to influence employee’s moral awareness (Hawkins et al., 2013; Rottig et al., 2011). The ethical infrastructure of an organization includes a range of organizational systems that guide ethical decision-making (Hawkins et al., 2013). Hence the communication of ethical standards to employees engenders moral behaviour (Eckerd and Hill, 2012).
Laudable as some of the strategies may be, more so when most of the initiatives are at the lead firm's benevolence, the challenge is how can resistant lead firms be convinced? Global supply chains have become overly complex and more vulnerable to disruptions with large unanticipated consequences (Fahimnia et al., 2015). Also, notwithstanding major disruptions either human-made or natural (e.g. COVID-19) and supply risk caused by several sources of inherent uncertainties such as demand fluctuations, supply capacity changes, lead time variability, and exchange rate volatility (Fahimnia et al., 2015), firms face enormous pressure and responsibility to deliver consistently. The need to ensure consistent supply and be resilient implies that firms have no choice than to be ‘compliant’, socially responsible and enforce ethical behaviour among employees (sourcing and purchasing agents, intermediaries, and staff).
Supplier scarcity has been cited (Schiele et al., 2012) as an important reason for supplier resource mobilization and supplier development. Firms compete not only on the sales market but also on the supply market since ‘really good’ suppliers are scarce (Cordón & Vollmann, 2008; Schiele et al., 2012, p. 1178). Suppliers can actively differentiate among competing buyers based on their ethical standards such that ethical behaviour can be a differentiating attribute and cue. Thus, corporate ethical values can be used as a ‘discriminating’ signal to communicate a firm’s attractiveness to suppliers and beat competing buyers (especially regarding strategic products/services). ‘Since more and more sales revenue comes from purchased items, it becomes more critical to get the best—ahead of your competitors’ (Cordón & Vollmann, 2008, p. 14). Being ethical is being ‘smart’. The behaviours and activities (regarding ethicality) of the buying company become a key means of influencing suppliers' resource mobilization. It is also a means of communicating the firm's corporate reputation to other stakeholders (government agencies, customers, civil society organizations, and the wider public) and reinforcing the firm's social responsibility. Besides, unethical opportunistic behaviour can also be a costly problem within the organization and lead to substantial inefficiencies and reputational challenges.
The dark side phenomenon leads to challenges that inhibit creativity, innovation, and value creation (Abosag et al., 2016, p. 5). Value formation is not only associated with value co-creation but also with value co-destruction (Echeverri & Skålén, 2011). The co-destruction of value is one of the downsides of value co-creation, and this has ethical implications for business relations. Besides, power imbalance impedes supply chain innovation and improvement by the less dominant partner. Such a power imbalance can lead to the use of coercive power by the more dominant buyer. Small suppliers must devote more resources to ensuring the continuation of business relationships with powerful buyers at the expense of supply chain innovations (Matanda et al., 2016). Our study suggests that buyer control of price is associated with reduced financial performance, while buyer control of quality in terms of quality standardization is associated with higher financial performance. In addition, we found that decision control regarding quality standardization can enhance the coordinative role of power in improving performance. The implication is that the use of power for coordination can be more effective if this is done within an environment characterized by mutuality, honesty, empathy, and fairness (Woiceshyn, 2011).
Finally, the positive impact of economic satisfaction on financial performance was found to be stronger for non-cooperative members than for cooperative members. This could be explained by the fact that cooperative members expect more gains from their exchanges than non-cooperative members. Cooperative members invest more time and effort in collective action. The implication is that although collective action may not solve all challenges emanating from problematic business relationships, joint/collective action is one of the most viable options in opposition to the negative impact of the dark side. For example, fair trade initiatives that strive for more equitable sharing of profits among the members are typical examples of sustainable collaborative supply chains (Drake and Schlachter, 2008).

Conclusion, Limitations, and Further Research

Our research highlights the following:
  • How dependency and high switching costs in captive supplier–buyer exchanges influence perceptions of power imbalance.
  • The conditions under which power imbalance provides ideal situations for unethical behaviours.
  • The consequences of power imbalance, opportunistic behaviour, and decision control.
  • The theoretical contributions and managerial implications.
Dependency and high switching costs in captive supplier–buyer exchanges influence perceptions of power imbalance. The impact of dependency on power imbalance is contingent on transaction volume, such that as the volume of transactions between trading partners increases, dependency leads to power imbalance. This eventually leads to opportunities for exploitation of the weaker partner.
Our study has provided empirical evidence of the unique relationships between the main constructs under study (see Table 7) and discussed the theoretical contributions of the study, briefly summarized into five main propositions as follows. (1) Asymmetric power relations’ negative impact on the gains of the other party in the exchange is exacerbated by dependency. (2) The consequences of power imbalance are opportunism and low financial reward. (3) The effect of power imbalance on opportunism is not only linear but could also be curvilinear. (4) The negative impact of power imbalance in reducing financial performance is exacerbated without joint effort and collective action. (5) Not only does decision control in asymmetric relations lead to the unfair distribution of rewards, but it also provides the conditions for exploitation and unethical behaviour. We have also provided managerial insights in relation to control, monitoring, collective action, fairness, transparency, ethical sourcing/purchasing and chain governance. We emphasize the need for businesses to invest in strategies and procedures that protect suppliers against detrimental actions and behaviours by boundary spanning personnel and intermediaries.
Table 7
Summary of findings
Associations
Uniqueness of hypothesized association
Sign
Results
Key antecedents of power imbalance (shadow of dark side)
   
 Supplier dependency → Power imbalance (H1a)
Moderated by transaction volume
+
Strongly supported
 Switching costs → Power imbalance (H2a)
Direct effect and linear
+
Not supported
 Switching costs → Power imbalance (H2b)
Curvilinear (U shape)
+
Supported
Consequences of power imbalance (negative—dark side)
   
 Power imbalance → Financial performance (H1b)
Moderated by supplier dependency
Supported
 Power imbalance → Buyer/agent opportunism (H3a)
Direct effect and linear
+
Supported
 Power imbalance → Buyer/agent opportunism (H3b)
Curvilinear (inverted U shape)
Strongly supported
 Power imbalance → Financial performance (H4a)
Direct effect and linear
Supported
 Power imbalance → Financial performance (H4b)
Moderated by cooperative/collective action
Ncoop>Coopstrongly supported
Consequences of opportunism (negative—dark side)
   
 Buyer/agent opportunism → Financial performance (H4c)
Direct effect and linear
Supported
Negative consequences of decision control (negative—dark side)
   
 Buyer control of price → Financial performance (H5a)
Direct effect and linear
Supported
Positive consequences of decision control (positive—dark side)
   
 Quality standardization → Financial performance (H5b)
Direct effect and linear
+
Strongly supported
 Power imbalance → Financial performance (H5c)
Moderated by quality standardization
+
Strongly supported
Positive consequences of economic satisfaction (positive—light side)
   
 Economic satisfaction → Financial performance (H6a)
Direct effect and linear
+
Strongly supported
 Economic satisfaction → Financial performance (H6b)
Moderated by cooperative/collective action
+
Coop>Ncoopnot supported
Ncoop non-cooperative membership of supplier, Coop cooperative membership of supplier
We acknowledge some limitations of this study, which can be addressed in future research. Firstly, we considered the suppliers’ perspective, which is just one side of the buyer–supplier dyad; however, perceptions may vary across the dyad (John & Reve, 1982), such that suppliers and buyers may have different perceptions and interpretations of what goes on in the dyad. Thus, future research could focus on the interdependent and simultaneously interacting perspectives of suppliers and buyers. Secondly, this study investigated power asymmetry using the cocoa industry in a developing economy as the setting. Hence, the findings may not apply to all industries. However, the results can be extended to industries with similar power relations such as the agribusiness (coffee, tea, horticulture—fruits, vegetables, floral), textiles and garment industries, and the grocery/retail sectors. Some of the cooperative associations studied in this article may vary regarding buyer–supplier relations in industrial settings in the developed economies due to institutional differences. Further replication studies involving small to medium-sized supply companies in asymmetrical industrial supplier–buyer relationships in developed economies will help provide more support and confirmation of the various hypothesized associations in the present study.
Thirdly, the research context and setting's findings assume homogenous outcomes, benefits, and impact for all cooperative members. Our study did not take into consideration the number of cooperative associations. Hence, we were not able to explore if the findings relating to the negative impact of power imbalance on financial performance and the positive effect of economic satisfaction on financial performance differs across the many cooperatives. Future studies should consider how the impact of power imbalance on financial performance as well as the positive effect of economic satisfaction on financial performance differs across the many cooperatives and its corresponding ethical considerations.
Besides, we did not explore the motivations and expectations about cooperative membership or why some farm enterprises did not join the cooperatives. This provides more options for future research about the motivations and expectations of cooperative membership and its impact on value creation and co-destruction. In addition, power, dependence, and exploitation can occur in cooperative relationships and joint actions even among suppliers. Conflict and power dependence can occur in cooperatives.
Our study focused on joint action as one of the possible solutions to address exploitation. Collective action is one of the strategies to tackle this ethical problem. However, other viable options have not been considered in the present study, presenting future research opportunities. Finally, the paper addressed the supplier–buyer perspective and not the buyer–supplier or supplier–supplier exchanges and perspectives. Thus, there is a need for more studies from other perspectives apart from the suppliers. Future studies on power, dependence and exploitation in joint/collaborative actions can present new insights on the dark side phenomenon.

Acknowledgement

The authors appreciate the three anonymous reviewers whose constructive comments led to a significant improvement of this paper.

Declarations

Conflict of interest

All authors certify that they have no affiliations with or involvement in any organization or entity with any financial interest or non-financial interest in the subject matter or materials discussed in this manuscript.
Open AccessThis article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://​creativecommons.​org/​licenses/​by/​4.​0/​.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Literature
go back to reference Abosag, I., Yen, DssA., & Barnes, B. R. (2016). What is dark about the dark-side of business relationships? Industrial Marketing Management, 55, 5–9.CrossRef Abosag, I., Yen, DssA., & Barnes, B. R. (2016). What is dark about the dark-side of business relationships? Industrial Marketing Management, 55, 5–9.CrossRef
go back to reference Anderson, E., & Weitz, B. (1989). Determinants of continuity in conventional industrial channel dyads. Marketing science, 8(4), 310–323.CrossRef Anderson, E., & Weitz, B. (1989). Determinants of continuity in conventional industrial channel dyads. Marketing science, 8(4), 310–323.CrossRef
go back to reference Anderson, E., & Jap, S. D. (2005). The dark side of close relationships. MIT Sloan Management Review, 46(3), 75. Anderson, E., & Jap, S. D. (2005). The dark side of close relationships. MIT Sloan Management Review, 46(3), 75.
go back to reference Belaya, V., & Hanf, J. H. (2009). The two sides of power in business-to-business relationships: Implications for supply chains. Marketing Review, 9(4), 361–381.CrossRef Belaya, V., & Hanf, J. H. (2009). The two sides of power in business-to-business relationships: Implications for supply chains. Marketing Review, 9(4), 361–381.CrossRef
go back to reference Benton, W. C., & Maloni, M. (2005). The influence of power-driven buyer/seller relationships on supply chain satisfaction. Journal of Operations Management, 23, 1–22.CrossRef Benton, W. C., & Maloni, M. (2005). The influence of power-driven buyer/seller relationships on supply chain satisfaction. Journal of Operations Management, 23, 1–22.CrossRef
go back to reference Buchanan, L. (1992). Vertical trade relationships: The role of dependence and symmetry in attaining organizational goals. Journal of Marketing Research, 29(1), 65–75.CrossRef Buchanan, L. (1992). Vertical trade relationships: The role of dependence and symmetry in attaining organizational goals. Journal of Marketing Research, 29(1), 65–75.CrossRef
go back to reference Buvik, A., & Andersen, O. (2015). The effect of multiple sourcing and bilateral dependency on buyer control in industrial buyer-seller relationships. International Journal of Procurement Management, 8(4), 441–456.CrossRef Buvik, A., & Andersen, O. (2015). The effect of multiple sourcing and bilateral dependency on buyer control in industrial buyer-seller relationships. International Journal of Procurement Management, 8(4), 441–456.CrossRef
go back to reference Buxton, A., & Vorley, B. (2012). The ethical agent: Fresh flowers in Kenya. International Institute for Environment and Development/Sustainable Food Lab. Buxton, A., & Vorley, B. (2012). The ethical agent: Fresh flowers in Kenya. International Institute for Environment and Development/Sustainable Food Lab.
go back to reference Caniels, M. C. J., & Gelderman, C. J. (2007). Power and interdependency in buyer–supplier relationships: A purchasing portfolio approach. Industrial Marketing Management, 36(2), 219–229.CrossRef Caniels, M. C. J., & Gelderman, C. J. (2007). Power and interdependency in buyer–supplier relationships: A purchasing portfolio approach. Industrial Marketing Management, 36(2), 219–229.CrossRef
go back to reference Chicksand, D. (2015). Partnerships: The role that power plays in shaping collaborative buyer–supplier exchanges. Industrial Marketing Management, 48, 121–139.CrossRef Chicksand, D. (2015). Partnerships: The role that power plays in shaping collaborative buyer–supplier exchanges. Industrial Marketing Management, 48, 121–139.CrossRef
go back to reference Chin, W. W. (1998). The partial least squares approach to structural equation modelling. In G. A. Marcoulides (ed.), Modern methods for business research. Lawrence Erlbaum. Chin, W. W. (1998). The partial least squares approach to structural equation modelling. In G. A. Marcoulides (ed.), Modern methods for business research. Lawrence Erlbaum.
go back to reference Chin, W., & Newsted, P. R. (1999). Structural equation modelling analysis with small samples using partial least squares. In R. Hoyle (Ed.), Statistical strategies for small sample research (pp. 307–341). Sage. Chin, W., & Newsted, P. R. (1999). Structural equation modelling analysis with small samples using partial least squares. In R. Hoyle (Ed.), Statistical strategies for small sample research (pp. 307–341). Sage.
go back to reference Chowdhury, I. N., Gruber, T., & Zolkiewski, J. (2016). Every cloud has a silver lining: Exploring the dark side of value co-creation in B2B service networks. Industrial Marketing Management, 55, 97–109.CrossRef Chowdhury, I. N., Gruber, T., & Zolkiewski, J. (2016). Every cloud has a silver lining: Exploring the dark side of value co-creation in B2B service networks. Industrial Marketing Management, 55, 97–109.CrossRef
go back to reference Clopton, S. W. (1984). Seller and buying firm factors affecting industrial buyers’ negotiation behavior and outcomes. Journal of Marketing Research, 21(1), 39–53. Clopton, S. W. (1984). Seller and buying firm factors affecting industrial buyers’ negotiation behavior and outcomes. Journal of Marketing Research, 21(1), 39–53.
go back to reference Coelho, P., & Henseler, J. (2012). Creating customer loyalty through service customization. European Journal of Marketing, 46(3/4), 331–356.CrossRef Coelho, P., & Henseler, J. (2012). Creating customer loyalty through service customization. European Journal of Marketing, 46(3/4), 331–356.CrossRef
go back to reference Coughlan, A. T., Anderson, E., Stern, L. W., & El-Ansary, A. I. (2006). Marketing channels (7th ed.). Pearson/Prentice Hall. Coughlan, A. T., Anderson, E., Stern, L. W., & El-Ansary, A. I. (2006). Marketing channels (7th ed.). Pearson/Prentice Hall.
go back to reference Cordón, C., & Vollmann, T. (2008). The power of two: How smart companies create win: win customer-supplier partnerships that outperform the competition. Palgrave Macmillan. Cordón, C., & Vollmann, T. (2008). The power of two: How smart companies create win: win customer-supplier partnerships that outperform the competition. Palgrave Macmillan.
go back to reference Cox, A., Sanderson, J., & Watson, C. (2000). Power regimes: Mapping the DNA of business and supply chain relationships. Earlsgate Press. Cox, A., Sanderson, J., & Watson, C. (2000). Power regimes: Mapping the DNA of business and supply chain relationships. Earlsgate Press.
go back to reference Crosby, L. A., Evans, K. R., & Crowles, D. (1990). Relationship quality in services selling: An interpersonal influence perspective. Journal of Marketing, 54(3), 68–81.CrossRef Crosby, L. A., Evans, K. R., & Crowles, D. (1990). Relationship quality in services selling: An interpersonal influence perspective. Journal of Marketing, 54(3), 68–81.CrossRef
go back to reference Dabholkar, P. A., Johnston, W. J., & Cathey, A. S. (1994). The dynamics of long-term business-to-business exchange relationships. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 22(2), 130.CrossRef Dabholkar, P. A., Johnston, W. J., & Cathey, A. S. (1994). The dynamics of long-term business-to-business exchange relationships. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 22(2), 130.CrossRef
go back to reference Dadzie, K. Q., Dadzie, C. A., & Williams, A. J. (2018). Trust and duration of buyer-seller relationship in emerging markets. Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing, 33(1), 134–144.CrossRef Dadzie, K. Q., Dadzie, C. A., & Williams, A. J. (2018). Trust and duration of buyer-seller relationship in emerging markets. Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing, 33(1), 134–144.CrossRef
go back to reference Dahl, R. A. (1957). The concept of power. Behavioral Science, 2, 201–218.CrossRef Dahl, R. A. (1957). The concept of power. Behavioral Science, 2, 201–218.CrossRef
go back to reference Diamantopoulos, A., & Siguaw, J. A. (2006). Formative versus reflective indicators in organizational measure development: A comparison and empirical illustration. British Journal of Management, 17(4), 263–282.CrossRef Diamantopoulos, A., & Siguaw, J. A. (2006). Formative versus reflective indicators in organizational measure development: A comparison and empirical illustration. British Journal of Management, 17(4), 263–282.CrossRef
go back to reference Dong, B., Evans, K. R., & Zou, S. (2008). The effects of customer participation in co-created service recovery. Journal of the academy of marketing science, 36(1), 123–137.CrossRef Dong, B., Evans, K. R., & Zou, S. (2008). The effects of customer participation in co-created service recovery. Journal of the academy of marketing science, 36(1), 123–137.CrossRef
go back to reference Drake, M. J., & Schlachter, J. T. (2008). A virtue-ethics analysis of supply chain collaboration. Journal of Business Ethics, 82(4), 851–864.CrossRef Drake, M. J., & Schlachter, J. T. (2008). A virtue-ethics analysis of supply chain collaboration. Journal of Business Ethics, 82(4), 851–864.CrossRef
go back to reference Dutta, S., Bergen, M., & John, G. (1994). The governance of exclusive territories when dealers can bootleg. Marketing Science, 13(1), 83–99.CrossRef Dutta, S., Bergen, M., & John, G. (1994). The governance of exclusive territories when dealers can bootleg. Marketing Science, 13(1), 83–99.CrossRef
go back to reference Dwyer, F. R., Schurr, P. H., & Oh, S. (1987). Developing buyer-seller relationships. Journal of Marketing, 51(2), 11–27.CrossRef Dwyer, F. R., Schurr, P. H., & Oh, S. (1987). Developing buyer-seller relationships. Journal of Marketing, 51(2), 11–27.CrossRef
go back to reference Echeverri, P., & Skålén, P. (2011). Co-creation and co-destruction: A practice-theory based study of interactive value formation. Marketing theory, 11(3), 351–373.CrossRef Echeverri, P., & Skålén, P. (2011). Co-creation and co-destruction: A practice-theory based study of interactive value formation. Marketing theory, 11(3), 351–373.CrossRef
go back to reference Eckerd, S., & Hill, J. A. (2012). The buyer-supplier social contract: information sharing as a deterrent to unethical behaviors. International Journal of Operations & Production Management, 32(2), 238–255.CrossRef Eckerd, S., & Hill, J. A. (2012). The buyer-supplier social contract: information sharing as a deterrent to unethical behaviors. International Journal of Operations & Production Management, 32(2), 238–255.CrossRef
go back to reference Eisenhardt, K. M. (1989). Agency theory: An assessment and review. Academy of Management Review, 14(1), 57–74.CrossRef Eisenhardt, K. M. (1989). Agency theory: An assessment and review. Academy of Management Review, 14(1), 57–74.CrossRef
go back to reference El-Ansary, A. I., & Stern, L. W. (1972). Power measurement in the distribution channel. Journal of Marketing Research, 9(1), 47–52.CrossRef El-Ansary, A. I., & Stern, L. W. (1972). Power measurement in the distribution channel. Journal of Marketing Research, 9(1), 47–52.CrossRef
go back to reference El Meladi, Y., Glavee-Geo, R., & Buvik, A. (2018). Understanding how opportunism and resource capability affect performance in exporter–LSP outsourcing relationships. Logistique & Management, 26(4), 229–246.CrossRef El Meladi, Y., Glavee-Geo, R., & Buvik, A. (2018). Understanding how opportunism and resource capability affect performance in exporter–LSP outsourcing relationships. Logistique & Management, 26(4), 229–246.CrossRef
go back to reference Emerson, R. M. (1962). Power-dependence relations. American Sociological Review, 27(1), 31–41.CrossRef Emerson, R. M. (1962). Power-dependence relations. American Sociological Review, 27(1), 31–41.CrossRef
go back to reference Fahimnia, B., Tang, C. S., Davarzani, H., & Sarkis, J. (2015). Quantitative models for managing supply chain risks: A review. European Journal of Operational Research, 247(1), 1–15.CrossRef Fahimnia, B., Tang, C. S., Davarzani, H., & Sarkis, J. (2015). Quantitative models for managing supply chain risks: A review. European Journal of Operational Research, 247(1), 1–15.CrossRef
go back to reference Fang, S. R., Chang, Y. S., & Peng, Y. C. (2011). Dark side of relationships: A tensions-based view. Industrial Marketing Management, 40(5), 774–784.CrossRef Fang, S. R., Chang, Y. S., & Peng, Y. C. (2011). Dark side of relationships: A tensions-based view. Industrial Marketing Management, 40(5), 774–784.CrossRef
go back to reference Ferro, C., Padin, C., Svensson, G., & Payan, J. (2016). Trust and commitment as mediators between economic and non-economic satisfaction in manufacturer-supplier relationships. Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing, 31(1), 13–23.CrossRef Ferro, C., Padin, C., Svensson, G., & Payan, J. (2016). Trust and commitment as mediators between economic and non-economic satisfaction in manufacturer-supplier relationships. Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing, 31(1), 13–23.CrossRef
go back to reference Fischer, E., & Qaim, M. (2012). Linking smallholders to markets: Determinants and impacts of farmer collective action in Kenya. World Development, 40(6), 1255–1268.CrossRef Fischer, E., & Qaim, M. (2012). Linking smallholders to markets: Determinants and impacts of farmer collective action in Kenya. World Development, 40(6), 1255–1268.CrossRef
go back to reference Fischer, E., & Qaim, M. (2014). Smallholder farmers and collective action: What determines the intensity of participation? Journal of Agricultural Economics, 65(3), 683–702.CrossRef Fischer, E., & Qaim, M. (2014). Smallholder farmers and collective action: What determines the intensity of participation? Journal of Agricultural Economics, 65(3), 683–702.CrossRef
go back to reference Fontrodona, J., & Sison, A. J. G. (2006). The nature of the firm, agency theory and shareholder theory: A critique from philosophical anthropology. Journal of Business Ethics, 66(1), 33–42.CrossRef Fontrodona, J., & Sison, A. J. G. (2006). The nature of the firm, agency theory and shareholder theory: A critique from philosophical anthropology. Journal of Business Ethics, 66(1), 33–42.CrossRef
go back to reference Fornell, C., & Larcker, D. F. (1981). Evaluating structural equation models with unobservable variables and measurement error. Journal of Marketing Research, 18, 39–50.CrossRef Fornell, C., & Larcker, D. F. (1981). Evaluating structural equation models with unobservable variables and measurement error. Journal of Marketing Research, 18, 39–50.CrossRef
go back to reference Franke, G., & Sarstedt, M. (2019). Heuristics versus statistics in discriminant validity testing: A comparison of four procedures. Internet Research, 29(3), 430–447.CrossRef Franke, G., & Sarstedt, M. (2019). Heuristics versus statistics in discriminant validity testing: A comparison of four procedures. Internet Research, 29(3), 430–447.CrossRef
go back to reference Gaski, J. F. (1984). The theory of power and conflict in channels of distribution. Journal of Marketing, 48(3), 9–29.CrossRef Gaski, J. F. (1984). The theory of power and conflict in channels of distribution. Journal of Marketing, 48(3), 9–29.CrossRef
go back to reference Geiger, I., Durand, A., Saab, S., Kleinaltenkamp, M., Baxter, R., & Lee, Y. (2012). The bonding effects of relationship value and switching costs in industrial buyer-seller relationships: An investigation into role differences. Industrial Marketing Management, 41(1), 82–93.CrossRef Geiger, I., Durand, A., Saab, S., Kleinaltenkamp, M., Baxter, R., & Lee, Y. (2012). The bonding effects of relationship value and switching costs in industrial buyer-seller relationships: An investigation into role differences. Industrial Marketing Management, 41(1), 82–93.CrossRef
go back to reference Geyskens, I., & Steenkamp, J.-B.E.M. (2000). Economic and social satisfaction: Measurement and relevance to marketing channel relationships. Journal of Retailing, 76(1), 11–32.CrossRef Geyskens, I., & Steenkamp, J.-B.E.M. (2000). Economic and social satisfaction: Measurement and relevance to marketing channel relationships. Journal of Retailing, 76(1), 11–32.CrossRef
go back to reference Geyskens, I., Steenkamp, J.-B.E.M., & Kumar, N. (1999). A meta-analysis of satisfaction in marketing channel relationships. Journal of Marketing Research, 36(2), 223–238.CrossRef Geyskens, I., Steenkamp, J.-B.E.M., & Kumar, N. (1999). A meta-analysis of satisfaction in marketing channel relationships. Journal of Marketing Research, 36(2), 223–238.CrossRef
go back to reference Geyskens, I., Steenkamp, J.-B.E.M., Scheer, L. K., & Kumar, N. (1996). The effects of trust and interdependence on relationship commitment: A trans-Atlantic study. International Journal of Research in Marketing, 13(4), 303–317.CrossRef Geyskens, I., Steenkamp, J.-B.E.M., Scheer, L. K., & Kumar, N. (1996). The effects of trust and interdependence on relationship commitment: A trans-Atlantic study. International Journal of Research in Marketing, 13(4), 303–317.CrossRef
go back to reference Glavee-Geo, R. (2019). Does supplier development lead to supplier satisfaction and relationship continuation? Journal of Purchasing and Supply Management, 25(3), 100537.CrossRef Glavee-Geo, R. (2019). Does supplier development lead to supplier satisfaction and relationship continuation? Journal of Purchasing and Supply Management, 25(3), 100537.CrossRef
go back to reference Glavee-Geo, R., Burki, U., & Buvik, A. (2020). Building trustworthy relationships with smallholder (small-scale) agro-commodity suppliers: Insights from the Ghana cocoa industry. Journal of Macromarketing, 40(1), 110–127.CrossRef Glavee-Geo, R., Burki, U., & Buvik, A. (2020). Building trustworthy relationships with smallholder (small-scale) agro-commodity suppliers: Insights from the Ghana cocoa industry. Journal of Macromarketing, 40(1), 110–127.CrossRef
go back to reference Good, D. J., & Evans, K. R. (2001). Relationship unrest: A strategic perspective for business-to-business marketers. European Journal of Marketing, 35(5/6), 549–565.CrossRef Good, D. J., & Evans, K. R. (2001). Relationship unrest: A strategic perspective for business-to-business marketers. European Journal of Marketing, 35(5/6), 549–565.CrossRef
go back to reference Grandinetti, R. (2017). Exploring the dark side of cooperative buyer-seller relationships. Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing, 32(2), 326–336.CrossRef Grandinetti, R. (2017). Exploring the dark side of cooperative buyer-seller relationships. Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing, 32(2), 326–336.CrossRef
go back to reference Griffith, D. A., Harvey, M. G., & Lusch, R. F. (2006). Social exchange in supply chain: The resulting benefits of procedural and distributive justice. Journal of Operations Management, 24, 85–98.CrossRef Griffith, D. A., Harvey, M. G., & Lusch, R. F. (2006). Social exchange in supply chain: The resulting benefits of procedural and distributive justice. Journal of Operations Management, 24, 85–98.CrossRef
go back to reference Hair, J. F., Jr., Hult, G. T. M., Ringle, C. M., & Sarstedt, M. A. (2017). Primer on partial least squares structural equation modeling (PLS-SEM). Sage. Hair, J. F., Jr., Hult, G. T. M., Ringle, C. M., & Sarstedt, M. A. (2017). Primer on partial least squares structural equation modeling (PLS-SEM). Sage.
go back to reference Haugland, S. A., Myrtveit, I., & Nygaard, A. (2007). Market orientation and performance in the service industry: A data envelopment analysis. Journal of Business Research, 60(11), 1191–1197.CrossRef Haugland, S. A., Myrtveit, I., & Nygaard, A. (2007). Market orientation and performance in the service industry: A data envelopment analysis. Journal of Business Research, 60(11), 1191–1197.CrossRef
go back to reference Hawkins, T. G., Wittman, C. M., & Beyerlein, M. M. (2008). Antecedents and consequences of opportunism in buyer–supplier relations: Research synthesis and new frontiers. Industrial Marketing Management, 37(8), 895–909.CrossRef Hawkins, T. G., Wittman, C. M., & Beyerlein, M. M. (2008). Antecedents and consequences of opportunism in buyer–supplier relations: Research synthesis and new frontiers. Industrial Marketing Management, 37(8), 895–909.CrossRef
go back to reference Hawkins, T. G., Pohlen, T. L., & Prybutok, V. R. (2013). Buyer opportunism in business-to-business exchange. Industrial marketing management, 42(8), 1266–1278.CrossRef Hawkins, T. G., Pohlen, T. L., & Prybutok, V. R. (2013). Buyer opportunism in business-to-business exchange. Industrial marketing management, 42(8), 1266–1278.CrossRef
go back to reference Henseler, J., Ringle, C. M., & Sarstedt, M. (2015). A new criterion for assessing discriminant validity in variance-based structural equation modeling. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 43(1), 115–135.CrossRef Henseler, J., Ringle, C. M., & Sarstedt, M. (2015). A new criterion for assessing discriminant validity in variance-based structural equation modeling. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 43(1), 115–135.CrossRef
go back to reference Hingley, M. K. (2005). Power imbalance in UK agri-food supply chain channels: Learning to live with the supermarkets? Journal of Marketing Management, 21(1/2), 63–88.CrossRef Hingley, M. K. (2005). Power imbalance in UK agri-food supply chain channels: Learning to live with the supermarkets? Journal of Marketing Management, 21(1/2), 63–88.CrossRef
go back to reference Hingley, M. K. (2005). Power to all our friends? Living with imbalance in supplier-retailer relationships. Industrial Marketing Management, 34(8), 848–858.CrossRef Hingley, M. K. (2005). Power to all our friends? Living with imbalance in supplier-retailer relationships. Industrial Marketing Management, 34(8), 848–858.CrossRef
go back to reference Holmlund-Rytkönen, M., & Strandvik, T. (2005). Stress in business relationships. Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing, 20(1), 12–22.CrossRef Holmlund-Rytkönen, M., & Strandvik, T. (2005). Stress in business relationships. Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing, 20(1), 12–22.CrossRef
go back to reference Hulland, J., Baumgartner, H., & Smith, K. M. (2018). Marketing survey research best practices: Evidence and recommendations from a review of JAMS articles. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 46(1), 92–108.CrossRef Hulland, J., Baumgartner, H., & Smith, K. M. (2018). Marketing survey research best practices: Evidence and recommendations from a review of JAMS articles. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 46(1), 92–108.CrossRef
go back to reference Hunt, S. D., Wood, V. R., & Chonko, L. B. (1989). Corporate ethical values and organizational commitment in marketing. Journal of marketing, 53(3), 79–90.CrossRef Hunt, S. D., Wood, V. R., & Chonko, L. B. (1989). Corporate ethical values and organizational commitment in marketing. Journal of marketing, 53(3), 79–90.CrossRef
go back to reference Hyman, M. R., Skipper, R., & Tansey, R. (1990). Ethical codes are not enough. Business Horizons, 33(2), 15–23.CrossRef Hyman, M. R., Skipper, R., & Tansey, R. (1990). Ethical codes are not enough. Business Horizons, 33(2), 15–23.CrossRef
go back to reference Håkansson, H., & Snehota, I. (1998). The burden of relationships or who’s next? In P. Naude & P. W. Turnbull (Eds.), Network dynamics in international marketing (pp. 16–25). Pergamon. Håkansson, H., & Snehota, I. (1998). The burden of relationships or who’s next? In P. Naude & P. W. Turnbull (Eds.), Network dynamics in international marketing (pp. 16–25). Pergamon.
go back to reference Ireland, R. D., & Webb, J. W. (2007). A multi-theoretic perspective on trust and power in strategic supply chains. Journal of Operations Management, 25(2), 482–497.CrossRef Ireland, R. D., & Webb, J. W. (2007). A multi-theoretic perspective on trust and power in strategic supply chains. Journal of Operations Management, 25(2), 482–497.CrossRef
go back to reference John, G. (1984). An empirical investigation of some antecedents of opportunism in a marketing channel. Journal of Marketing Research, 21(3), 278–289.CrossRef John, G. (1984). An empirical investigation of some antecedents of opportunism in a marketing channel. Journal of Marketing Research, 21(3), 278–289.CrossRef
go back to reference John, G., & Reve, T. (1982). The reliability and validity of key informant data from dyadic relationships in marketing channels. Journal of Marketing Research, 19(4), 517–524.CrossRef John, G., & Reve, T. (1982). The reliability and validity of key informant data from dyadic relationships in marketing channels. Journal of Marketing Research, 19(4), 517–524.CrossRef
go back to reference Joshi, A. W. (1998). How and why do relatively dependent manufacturers resist supplier power? Journal of Marketing Theory and Practice, 6(4), 61–77.CrossRef Joshi, A. W. (1998). How and why do relatively dependent manufacturers resist supplier power? Journal of Marketing Theory and Practice, 6(4), 61–77.CrossRef
go back to reference Joshi, A. W., & Stump, R. L. (1999). Determinants of commitment and opportunism: Integrating and extending insights from transaction costs analysis and relational exchange theory. Revue Canadienne des Sciences de l’Administration, 16(4), 334–352.CrossRef Joshi, A. W., & Stump, R. L. (1999). Determinants of commitment and opportunism: Integrating and extending insights from transaction costs analysis and relational exchange theory. Revue Canadienne des Sciences de l’Administration, 16(4), 334–352.CrossRef
go back to reference Kale, S. H. (1986). Dealer perceptions of manufacturer power and influence strategies in a developing country. Journal of Marketing Research, 23(4), 387–393.CrossRef Kale, S. H. (1986). Dealer perceptions of manufacturer power and influence strategies in a developing country. Journal of Marketing Research, 23(4), 387–393.CrossRef
go back to reference Krause, D. R., Handfield, R. B., & Tyler, B. B. (2007). The relationships between supplier development, commitment, social capital accumulation and performance improvement. Journal of Operations Management, 25(2), 528–545.CrossRef Krause, D. R., Handfield, R. B., & Tyler, B. B. (2007). The relationships between supplier development, commitment, social capital accumulation and performance improvement. Journal of Operations Management, 25(2), 528–545.CrossRef
go back to reference Kumar, N., Scheer, L. K., & Steenkamp, J. E. M. (1995). The effects of supplier fairness on vulnerable resellers. Journal of Marketing Research, 32(1), 54–65.CrossRef Kumar, N., Scheer, L. K., & Steenkamp, J. E. M. (1995). The effects of supplier fairness on vulnerable resellers. Journal of Marketing Research, 32(1), 54–65.CrossRef
go back to reference Lado, A. A., Dant, R. R., & Tekleab, A. G. (2008). Trust-opportunism paradox, relationalism, and performance in interfirm relationships: evidence from the retail industry. Strategic Management Journal, 29(4), 401–423.CrossRef Lado, A. A., Dant, R. R., & Tekleab, A. G. (2008). Trust-opportunism paradox, relationalism, and performance in interfirm relationships: evidence from the retail industry. Strategic Management Journal, 29(4), 401–423.CrossRef
go back to reference Liu, Y., Liu, T., & Li, Y. (2014). How to inhibit a partner’s strong and weak forms of opportunism: Impacts of network embeddedness and bilateral TSIs. Industrial Marketing Management, 43(2), 280–292.CrossRef Liu, Y., Liu, T., & Li, Y. (2014). How to inhibit a partner’s strong and weak forms of opportunism: Impacts of network embeddedness and bilateral TSIs. Industrial Marketing Management, 43(2), 280–292.CrossRef
go back to reference Maglaras, G., Bourlakis, M., & Fotopoulos, C. (2015). Power-imbalanced relationships in dyadic food chain: An empirical investigation of retailers’ commercial practices with suppliers. Industrial Marketing Management, 48, 187–201.CrossRef Maglaras, G., Bourlakis, M., & Fotopoulos, C. (2015). Power-imbalanced relationships in dyadic food chain: An empirical investigation of retailers’ commercial practices with suppliers. Industrial Marketing Management, 48, 187–201.CrossRef
go back to reference Matanda, M. J., Ndubisi, N. O., & Jie, F. (2016). Effects of relational capabilities and power asymmetry on innovativeness and flexibility of sub-Sahara Africa small exporting firms. Journal of Small Business Management, 54(1), 118–138.CrossRef Matanda, M. J., Ndubisi, N. O., & Jie, F. (2016). Effects of relational capabilities and power asymmetry on innovativeness and flexibility of sub-Sahara Africa small exporting firms. Journal of Small Business Management, 54(1), 118–138.CrossRef
go back to reference McDonald, F. (1999). The importance of power in partnership relationships. Journal of General Management, 25(1), 43–59.CrossRef McDonald, F. (1999). The importance of power in partnership relationships. Journal of General Management, 25(1), 43–59.CrossRef
go back to reference Meier zu Selhausen, F. . (2016). What determines women’s participation in collective action? Evidence from a western Ugandan coffee cooperative. Feminist Economics, 22(1), 130–157.CrossRef Meier zu Selhausen, F. . (2016). What determines women’s participation in collective action? Evidence from a western Ugandan coffee cooperative. Feminist Economics, 22(1), 130–157.CrossRef
go back to reference Nunnally, J. C. (1978). Psychometric theory (2nd ed.). McGraw-Hill. Nunnally, J. C. (1978). Psychometric theory (2nd ed.). McGraw-Hill.
go back to reference Nyga, G. N., Lynch, D. F., Marshall, D., & Ambrose, E. (2013). Power asymmetry, adaptation and collaboration in dyadic relationships involving a powerful partner. Journal of Supply Chain Management, 49(3), 42–65.CrossRef Nyga, G. N., Lynch, D. F., Marshall, D., & Ambrose, E. (2013). Power asymmetry, adaptation and collaboration in dyadic relationships involving a powerful partner. Journal of Supply Chain Management, 49(3), 42–65.CrossRef
go back to reference Oomes, N., Tieben, B., Laven, A., Ammerlaan, T., Appelman, R., Biesenbeek, C., & Buunk, E. (2016). Market concentration and price formation in global value chain. SEO Amsterdam Economics. Technical report commissioned by Ministry of Foreign Affairs, The Netherlands, 15 November 2016. Oomes, N., Tieben, B., Laven, A., Ammerlaan, T., Appelman, R., Biesenbeek, C., & Buunk, E. (2016). Market concentration and price formation in global value chain. SEO Amsterdam Economics. Technical report commissioned by Ministry of Foreign Affairs, The Netherlands, 15 November 2016.
go back to reference Perdue, B. C., Day, R. L., & Michaels, R. E. (1986). Negotiation styles of industrial buyers. Industrial Marketing Management, 15(3), 171–176.CrossRef Perdue, B. C., Day, R. L., & Michaels, R. E. (1986). Negotiation styles of industrial buyers. Industrial Marketing Management, 15(3), 171–176.CrossRef
go back to reference Philips, L. W. (1982). Explaining control losses in corporate marketing channels: An organizational analysis. Journal of Marketing Research, 19(4), 525–549.CrossRef Philips, L. W. (1982). Explaining control losses in corporate marketing channels: An organizational analysis. Journal of Marketing Research, 19(4), 525–549.CrossRef
go back to reference Plé, L., & Cáceres, R. C. (2010). Not always co-creation: introducing interactional co-destruction of value in service-dominant logic. Journal of Services Marketing, 24(6), 430–437.CrossRef Plé, L., & Cáceres, R. C. (2010). Not always co-creation: introducing interactional co-destruction of value in service-dominant logic. Journal of Services Marketing, 24(6), 430–437.CrossRef
go back to reference Podsakoff, P. M., Mackenzie, S. B., & Podsakoff, N. P. (2003). Common method biases in behavioural research: A critical review of literature and recommended remedies. Journal of Applied Psychology, 88(5), 879–903.CrossRef Podsakoff, P. M., Mackenzie, S. B., & Podsakoff, N. P. (2003). Common method biases in behavioural research: A critical review of literature and recommended remedies. Journal of Applied Psychology, 88(5), 879–903.CrossRef
go back to reference Podsakoff, N. P., & Organ, D. W. (1986). Self-reports in organizational research: Problems and prospects. Journal of Management, 12(4), 531–544.CrossRef Podsakoff, N. P., & Organ, D. W. (1986). Self-reports in organizational research: Problems and prospects. Journal of Management, 12(4), 531–544.CrossRef
go back to reference Pruitt, D. G. (1981). Negotiation behavior. Academic Press. Pruitt, D. G. (1981). Negotiation behavior. Academic Press.
go back to reference Rodriguez, R. I. B., Agudo, J. C., & Gutierrez, H. S. M. (2006). Determinants of economic and social satisfaction in manufacturer-distributor relationships. Industrial Marketing Management, 35, 666–675.CrossRef Rodriguez, R. I. B., Agudo, J. C., & Gutierrez, H. S. M. (2006). Determinants of economic and social satisfaction in manufacturer-distributor relationships. Industrial Marketing Management, 35, 666–675.CrossRef
go back to reference Rokkan, A. I., & Buvik, A. (2003). Inter-firm cooperation and the problem of free riding behavior: An empirical study of voluntary retail chains. Journal of Purchasing and Supply Management, 9(5–6), 247–256.CrossRef Rokkan, A. I., & Buvik, A. (2003). Inter-firm cooperation and the problem of free riding behavior: An empirical study of voluntary retail chains. Journal of Purchasing and Supply Management, 9(5–6), 247–256.CrossRef
go back to reference Rottig, D., Koufteros, X., & Umphress, E. (2011). Formal infrastructure and ethical decision making: An empirical investigation and implications for supply management. Decision Sciences, 42(1), 163–204.CrossRef Rottig, D., Koufteros, X., & Umphress, E. (2011). Formal infrastructure and ethical decision making: An empirical investigation and implications for supply management. Decision Sciences, 42(1), 163–204.CrossRef
go back to reference Saini, A. (2010). Purchasing ethics and inter-organizational buyer–supplier relational determinants: A conceptual framework. Journal of Business Ethics, 95(3), 439–455.CrossRef Saini, A. (2010). Purchasing ethics and inter-organizational buyer–supplier relational determinants: A conceptual framework. Journal of Business Ethics, 95(3), 439–455.CrossRef
go back to reference Scheer, L. K., Mio, C. F., & Palmatier, R. W. (2015). Dependence and interdependence in marketing relationships: Meta-analytic insights. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 43, 694–712.CrossRef Scheer, L. K., Mio, C. F., & Palmatier, R. W. (2015). Dependence and interdependence in marketing relationships: Meta-analytic insights. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 43, 694–712.CrossRef
go back to reference Schiele, H., Calvi, R., & Gibbert, M. (2012). Customer attractiveness, supplier satisfaction and preferred customer status: Introduction, definitions and an overarching framework. Industrial marketing management, 41(8), 1178–1185.CrossRef Schiele, H., Calvi, R., & Gibbert, M. (2012). Customer attractiveness, supplier satisfaction and preferred customer status: Introduction, definitions and an overarching framework. Industrial marketing management, 41(8), 1178–1185.CrossRef
go back to reference Schleper, M. C., Blome, C., & Wuttke, D. A. (2017). The dark side of buyer power: Supplier exploitation and the role of ethical climates. Journal of Business Ethics, 140(1), 97–114.CrossRef Schleper, M. C., Blome, C., & Wuttke, D. A. (2017). The dark side of buyer power: Supplier exploitation and the role of ethical climates. Journal of Business Ethics, 140(1), 97–114.CrossRef
go back to reference Shen, L., Zhang, C., & Teng, W. (2019). The double-edged effects of guanxi on partner opportunism. Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing, 34(6), 1313–1322.CrossRef Shen, L., Zhang, C., & Teng, W. (2019). The double-edged effects of guanxi on partner opportunism. Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing, 34(6), 1313–1322.CrossRef
go back to reference Skarmeas, D., Katsikeas, C. S., & Schlegelmilch, B. B. (2002). Drivers of commitment and its impact on performance in cross-cultural buyer-seller relationships: The importer’s perspective. Journal of International Business Studies, 33(4), 757–783.CrossRef Skarmeas, D., Katsikeas, C. S., & Schlegelmilch, B. B. (2002). Drivers of commitment and its impact on performance in cross-cultural buyer-seller relationships: The importer’s perspective. Journal of International Business Studies, 33(4), 757–783.CrossRef
go back to reference Skinner, S. J., Gassenheimer, J. B., & Kelly, S. W. (1992). Cooperation in supplier-dealer relations. Journal of Retailing, 68(2), 174–193. Skinner, S. J., Gassenheimer, J. B., & Kelly, S. W. (1992). Cooperation in supplier-dealer relations. Journal of Retailing, 68(2), 174–193.
go back to reference Strandvik, T., & Holmlund, M. (2008). How to diagnose business-to-business relationships by mapping negative incidents. Journal of Marketing Management, 24(3–4), 361–381.CrossRef Strandvik, T., & Holmlund, M. (2008). How to diagnose business-to-business relationships by mapping negative incidents. Journal of Marketing Management, 24(3–4), 361–381.CrossRef
go back to reference Tangpong, C., Michalisin, M. D., Traub, R. D., & Melcher, A. J. (2015). A review of buyer–supplier relationship typologies: Progress, problems, and future directions. Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing, 30(2), 153–170.CrossRef Tangpong, C., Michalisin, M. D., Traub, R. D., & Melcher, A. J. (2015). A review of buyer–supplier relationship typologies: Progress, problems, and future directions. Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing, 30(2), 153–170.CrossRef
go back to reference Economist, The. (1996). The over-prescription machine. The Economist, 341(October), 66. Economist, The. (1996). The over-prescription machine. The Economist, 341(October), 66.
go back to reference Vorley, B., & Thorpe, J. (2014). Success factors for lead firms to shape inclusive procurement. IIED Issue Paper. Vorley, B., & Thorpe, J. (2014). Success factors for lead firms to shape inclusive procurement. IIED Issue Paper.
go back to reference Wang, X., & Yang, Z. (2013). Inter-firm opportunism: A meta-analytic review and assessment of its antecedents and effect on performance. Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing, 28(2), 137–146.CrossRef Wang, X., & Yang, Z. (2013). Inter-firm opportunism: A meta-analytic review and assessment of its antecedents and effect on performance. Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing, 28(2), 137–146.CrossRef
go back to reference Wilemon, D. L. (1972). Power and negotiation strategies in marketing channels. The Southern Journal of Business, 7, 12–32. Wilemon, D. L. (1972). Power and negotiation strategies in marketing channels. The Southern Journal of Business, 7, 12–32.
go back to reference Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. The Free Press. Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. The Free Press.
go back to reference Woiceshyn, J. (2011). A model for ethical decision making in business: Reasoning, intuition, and rational moral principles. Journal of Business Ethics, 104(3), 311–323.CrossRef Woiceshyn, J. (2011). A model for ethical decision making in business: Reasoning, intuition, and rational moral principles. Journal of Business Ethics, 104(3), 311–323.CrossRef
go back to reference Xiao, Z., Dong, M. C., & Zhu, X. (2019). Learn to be good or bad? Revisited observer effects of punishment: Curvilinear relationship and network contingencies. Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing, 34(4), 754–766.CrossRef Xiao, Z., Dong, M. C., & Zhu, X. (2019). Learn to be good or bad? Revisited observer effects of punishment: Curvilinear relationship and network contingencies. Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing, 34(4), 754–766.CrossRef
go back to reference Zhou, N., Zhuang, G., & Yip, L. S. C. (2007). Perceptual difference of dependence and its impact on conflict in marketing channels in China: An empirical study with two-sided data. Industrial Marketing Management, 36(3), 309–321.CrossRef Zhou, N., Zhuang, G., & Yip, L. S. C. (2007). Perceptual difference of dependence and its impact on conflict in marketing channels in China: An empirical study with two-sided data. Industrial Marketing Management, 36(3), 309–321.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Power Imbalance and the Dark Side of the Captive Agri-food Supplier–Buyer Relationship
Authors
Richard Glavee-Geo
Per Engelseth
Arnt Buvik
Publication date
19-03-2021
Publisher
Springer Netherlands
Published in
Journal of Business Ethics / Issue 3/2022
Print ISSN: 0167-4544
Electronic ISSN: 1573-0697
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-021-04791-7

Other articles of this Issue 3/2022

Journal of Business Ethics 3/2022 Go to the issue