Skip to main content
Top

2018 | OriginalPaper | Chapter

5. The Formulation and Control of the General Purposes of a Company and Its Sub-system Objectives. The Creation of the Organizational Structure and the Information System

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

In this chapter, two management functions are analyzed: one that leads to the formulation of general objectives and the system of corporate objectives and one to create the organizational structure and the communications system. The approach followed by the author is “holistic”: the corporate system is considered as an integrated whole and both the elements that make up the system and the relationships between them are analyzed simultaneously.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Footnotes
1
For example, Barnard (1938), p. 88, seems to use the word “motive” for the term “purpose” to realize for the satisfaction of personal needs. On the contrary, in pp. 17–19, the distinction between motivation and ends is clear; the author states: “We shall call desires, impulses, wants by the name ‘motives’. They are chiefly resultants of forces in the physical, biological, and social environments, present and past. In other words, ‘motives’ are constructions for the psychological factors of individuals in the sense previously discussed in this chapter.”
 
2
Human behavior is mostly directed towards the realization of ends in order to satisfy its own needs in tension. Behavior is, therefore, largely conscious and rational. However, in order to better evaluate human behavior it is also necessary to consider the “field,” the “situation” in which individuals act. Maslow says, “Only rarely can the field be used to conclusively explain behavior. In addition, the field itself must be interpreted according to the human organism. The ‘field theory’ cannot replace ‘motivation theory’” Maslow (1943), article in Sexton (1970), p. 144.
 
3
Barnard (1938), pp. 94–95.
 
4
Ibidem, p. 86.
 
5
Ibidem, p. 95. Barnard points out, as we have seen, that the determination of the general purpose of the organization and the articulation in a system of company objectives is the central moment of the development of the cooperative system.
The specification of the overall purpose (mission) is decisive regarding the operation of the organization. For example, to say that a company should pursue the maximization of value for shareholders, or to affirm otherwise, that the purpose of the same company consists in producing and selling goods and services desired by customers (with the constraint of economic equilibrium) not is not the same thing: the way to govern the organization, the financial results, the quality of life of the organization’s members, etc. vary according to the end adopted. We will return to this topic in Chaps. 7, 8, 11, and 12.
On this point it is very interesting to read the article by Bartlett and Ghoshal (1994), that focuses on the objective of the company, claiming that its mission is the moral response that the organization gives to its stakeholders (defining consequently its responsibilities) and not the plans that are adopted for the economic exploitation of the commercial opportunities offered by the environment.
 
6
Barnard (1938), p. 87.
 
7
Adopting the terminology of Barnard, in the first case people display an organizational personality, while in the second an individual personality.
 
8
This distinction is very important and will affect future studies of economics and management: it will be the key point of the modern “agency theory.”
 
9
“Individual motive is necessarily an internal, personal, subjective thing; common purpose is necessarily an external, impersonal, objective thing even though the individual interpretation of it is subjective.” Barnard (1938), p. 89.
 
10
Barnard states, p. 89,: “It is rare, however, if ever, and then I think only in connection with family, patriotic and religious organizations under special conditions, that organization purpose becomes or can become the only or even the major individual motive.”
 
11
Reference was made to Maslow’s hierarchy of human needs. On this point, see: Maslow (1943), pp. 144–153.
 
12
These statements concern the relationship with employees of all levels. However, it can be extended, even if it becomes much more complicated, to relations with other stakeholders: customers, financiers lenders, suppliers, state and institutional bodies, local communities, etc.
 
13
Barnard (1938), cit., p. 89.
 
14
Ibidem, p. 82; see also p. 43. Efficiency is understood by Barnard as the company’s ability to satisfy the expectations of internal and external stakeholders.
 
15
Ibidem, p. 83, p. 94 and pp. 153–160. The problem of making compatible individual motivations and goals with those of the organization was not new when Barnard wrote; it was anticipated and analyzed by Marx, Taylor, and the Human Relations School. Even today, the issue is debated by sociologists, economists, and scholars of organization and management with conflicting results.
 
16
Barnard (1938), p. 231.
 
17
“The purpose must be broken into fragments, specific objectives, not only ordered in time so that detailed purpose and detailed action follow in the series of progressive cooperation, but also ordered contemporaneously into the specifications – geographical, social and financial – that each unit organization implies” (Ibidem, p. 231).
 
18
Barnard (1938), p. 231.
 
19
Barnard is not speaking about the planning process, but of decisions taken by the various participants in a process that involves the articulation of the general objectives by increasingly specific objectives until operational activity is reached.
 
20
Simon (1948, chap. I) thinks that any decision-making process chooses active or passive behavior to achieve a certain end, and, in turn, this end can be mediated by another end further away, and so on, until a relatively final objective is reached. However, the concept of teleology inevitably leads to the notion of “hierarchy” of decisions, each step of this hierarchy representing a means for the realization of the objectives of the step above.
 
21
Barnard (1938), p. 232.
 
22
Barnard (1938), p. 232.
 
23
Barnard (1938), p. 233.
 
24
“Without that up-and-down-the-line coordination of purposeful decisions, general decisions and general purposes are mere intellectual processes in an organization vacuum, insulated from realities by layers of misunderstanding. The function of formulating grand purposes and providing for their redefinition is one which needs sensitive systems of communication, experience in interpretation, imagination, and delegation of responsibility.” Ibidem p. 233.
 
25
Ibidem, p. 231.
 
26
The model of K.E.M. Weber, of 1922, is outlined in Economy and Society, Bedminster Press, New York, 1968, Vol. I, p. 217 and following and Vol. III, p. 956 and following.
The ideal bureaucratic model—but the discussion also applies to substantially similar patterns of classical organizational theory and also for the subsequent “administrative organization theory of labor” (Fayol and Urwick)—it was certainly not able to interpret the structure and operation of large enterprises (especially commercial) of the American managerial economy and in general, the companies operating in sectors characterized by considerable dynamism. In that model, the top management, in relation to the purposes to be achieved, created an organizational structure that included duties, responsibilities, and specific powers. The organizational centers located below the top management had no discretionary powers; specifically, the objectives of each unit, the means and the ways to achieve the objectives were analytically specified by the top of the organization. Procedures and operating rules regulated the activities of the organizational system, eliminating any discretion. Managers, owners of the units placed under the top of the organization, were simple “order-passers” and were concerned essentially to control their subordinates in order to make them comply completely and correctly with the requirements and procedures established at the top. The “knowledge” of the organization was concentrated at the top that “recapitulated” and held the specialized skills needed to take all business decisions rationally. In essence, the company moved and evolved because of impulses generated by top management, who imposed their decisions primarily through authority.
 
27
This subject is dealt with in Chap. 12.
 
28
Cyert and March (1963); Italian translation: Teoria del comportamento dell’impresa (1970). This edition is referred to in subsequent citations.
 
29
Galbraith (1967).
 
30
On p. 84, the authors state that the idea of organization objective and the concept of organization as a coalition are inherently contradictory.
 
31
The model illustrates the decision to “belong,” the balance between company incentives and commitments of participants, the conditions for the survival of the company. The organization appears as an instrument that manages the “payments” to participants (capitalists, workers, etc.) in relation to the need to attract and retain them.
 
32
Ibidem, p. 48.
 
33
Passim.
 
34
Ibidem, p. 50.
 
35
Ibidem, p. 51.
 
36
Ibidem, p. 53.
 
37
Ibidem, p. 53.
 
38
Ibidem, p. 69.
 
39
Ibidem, pp. 56–58.
 
40
Galbraith (1967), chap. VI; the author points out that the need for this group personality depends on the fact that in industry today a large number of decisions and all the important ones are based on information available to many people. As a rule, they are based on scientific and technical specialized knowledge, on information, and on the accumulated experience and the artistic sense and intuition of many people. All of this is directed through additional information, ordered, analyzed, and interpreted by experts through the use of highly technical equipment. The final decision will be taken only when it is based systematically on the contribution of all those whose information is relevant.
 
41
Ibidem, chap. VI.
 
42
Ibidem, chap. VI.
 
43
Simon (1958), Introduction.
 
44
Ibidem, chap. I.
 
45
Zanda (2012), p. 98 and ss.
 
46
Caselli (1966), p. 5; Marris (1965); Salvati (1967), p. 138.
 
47
Küng (2011), pp. 7–15 and 203–263.
 
48
Goshal and Moran (2009), chap. I. This chapter coincides with the publication of Goshal and Moran (2006).
 
Literature
go back to reference Barnard, C. I. (1938). The functions of the executive. Boston, MA: Harvard College. Barnard, C. I. (1938). The functions of the executive. Boston, MA: Harvard College.
go back to reference Bartlett, C.A., & Ghoshal, S. (1994, November-December). Changing the role of top management: Beyond strategy to purpose. Harvard Business Review Bartlett, C.A., & Ghoshal, S. (1994, November-December). Changing the role of top management: Beyond strategy to purpose. Harvard Business Review
go back to reference Caselli, L. (1966). Teoria dell’organizzazione e processi decisionali nell’impresa. Turin: Giappichelli. Caselli, L. (1966). Teoria dell’organizzazione e processi decisionali nell’impresa. Turin: Giappichelli.
go back to reference Cyert, R. M., & March, J. G. (1963). A behavioral theory of the firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall Inc. (Italian translation, Teoria del comportamento dell’impresa (1970). Milan; Angeli). Cyert, R. M., & March, J. G. (1963). A behavioral theory of the firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall Inc. (Italian translation, Teoria del comportamento dell’impresa (1970). Milan; Angeli).
go back to reference Galbraith, J.K. (1967). The new industrial state. London: Hamish Hamilton, (Italian translation, Il nuovo stato industriale. Turin: Einaudi). Galbraith, J.K. (1967). The new industrial state. London: Hamish Hamilton, (Italian translation, Il nuovo stato industriale. Turin: Einaudi).
go back to reference Goshal, S., & Moran, P. (2006). Toward a good theory of management. In J. Birkinshan, G. Piramal, & S. Goshal (Eds.), On management. New York: Prentice-Hall. Goshal, S., & Moran, P. (2006). Toward a good theory of management. In J. Birkinshan, G. Piramal, & S. Goshal (Eds.), On management. New York: Prentice-Hall.
go back to reference Goshal, S., & Moran, P. (2009). Una buona teoria manageriale. Milan: Il Sole 24ore. Goshal, S., & Moran, P. (2009). Una buona teoria manageriale. Milan: Il Sole 24ore.
go back to reference Küng, H. (2011). Onestà. Perchè l’economia ha bisogno di un’etica. Milan: Rizzoli. Küng, H. (2011). Onestà. Perchè l’economia ha bisogno di un’etica. Milan: Rizzoli.
go back to reference Marris, R. (1965). Les théories de la croissance de l’entreprise. Economie Appliquée, Tome XVIII, 1–2. Marris, R. (1965). Les théories de la croissance de l’entreprise. Economie Appliquée, Tome XVIII, 1–2.
go back to reference Maslow, A. H. (1943, July). A theory of human motivation. Psychological Review. Maslow, A. H. (1943, July). A theory of human motivation. Psychological Review.
go back to reference Salvati, M. (1967). Una critica alle teorie dell’impresa. Edizioni dell’Ateneo: Rome. Salvati, M. (1967). Una critica alle teorie dell’impresa. Edizioni dell’Ateneo: Rome.
go back to reference Sexton, W. P. (1970). Organization theories. Columbus, OH: C.E. Merrill Publishing Company. Sexton, W. P. (1970). Organization theories. Columbus, OH: C.E. Merrill Publishing Company.
go back to reference Simon, H. A. (1958). Administrative behavior. New York: MacMillan Company. Simon, H. A. (1958). Administrative behavior. New York: MacMillan Company.
go back to reference Weber, R. E. M. (1968). Economy and Society. New York: Bedminster Press. Weber, R. E. M. (1968). Economy and Society. New York: Bedminster Press.
go back to reference Zanda, G. (2012). Corporate management in a knowledge-based economy. London: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRef Zanda, G. (2012). Corporate management in a knowledge-based economy. London: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
The Formulation and Control of the General Purposes of a Company and Its Sub-system Objectives. The Creation of the Organizational Structure and the Information System
Author
Stefania Zanda
Copyright Year
2018
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-60068-0_5

Premium Partner