Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Eurasian Business Review 1/2021

Open Access 21-01-2021 | Regular Article

The impact of artificial intelligence on labor productivity

Authors: Giacomo Damioli, Vincent Van Roy, Daniel Vertesy

Published in: Eurasian Business Review | Issue 1/2021

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Recent evidence indicates an upsurge in artificial intelligence and robotics (AI) patenting activities in the latest years, suggesting that solutions based on AI technologies might have started to exert an effect on the economy. We test this hypothesis using a worldwide sample of 5257 companies having filed at least a patent related to the field of AI between 2000 and 2016. Our analysis shows that, once controlling for other patenting activities, AI patent applications generate an extra-positive effect on companies’ labor productivity. The effect concentrates on SMEs and services industries, suggesting that the ability to quickly readjust and introduce AI-based applications in the production process is an important determinant of the impact of AI observed to date.
Notes

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

1 Introduction and motivation

The past decades have witnessed major developments in artificial intelligence (AI) technology. The profound social and economic changes brought about by the deployment and advancement of AI applications in the production of goods and services, transportation and logistics, or service provision have triggered an intense debate on the present and future impact of AI on society (Makridakis 2017). As in the case of past general-purpose technologies, AI has the potential to disrupt almost all industries and businesses on a worldwide scale.
Recent studies have investigated the upsurge in AI technological developments in recent decades by analyzing the evolution of AI patent applications and AI-related scientific publications (De Prato et al. 2018; European Commission 2018; Fujii and Managi 2018; Cockburn et al. 2019; Van Roy et al. 2020; WIPO 2019). The innovative landscapes of AI, emerging from these studies, reveal similar patterns; the largest increase in AI took place in the last five years and are dominated by China, Japan, South Korea and the United States. Although AI developments are mainly concentrated in the telecommunications and software services and electronics manufacturing sectors, there are clear signs that almost all other industries are increasingly exploiting the opportunities of a new degree of automation brought about by AI technologies.
While there is a consensus among researchers about the rising trends and transformative nature of AI, the speculative interpretations about its economic impact and value for productivity are less conclusive, echoing the concerns synthetized in the popular Solow’s paradox “You can see the computer age everywhere but in the productivity statistics” (Solow 1987, p. 36). A more positive stream of literature claims that the disruptive content of the AI technology, leveraged through the automation of tasks, reduction of uncertainty, the recombination of existing and generation of new innovations (Agrawal et al. 2019a, b; Cockburn et al. 2019) will have a productivity-enhancing impact (Brynjolfsson et al. 2019). In sharp contrast, other theoretical models predict that the ongoing productivity slowdown is likely to continue due to increased inequalities (Gries and Naudié, 2018), learning costs (Jones 2009) and a lower rate of disruptiveness of AI compared to other general-purpose technologies (Gordon 2016, 2018).
Along with these contrasting predictions, there is a growing need for quantitative analyses to measure the impacts of AI on economic outcomes such as growth, productivity and employment, yet the requirement for high quality, firm-level data acts as an important barrier (Raj and Seamans 2019; Furman and Seamans 2019). Empirical studies have only recently emerged to help better understand the impact of AI on firm labor productivity and are restricted to a handful of papers (e.g. Graetz and Michaels 2018; Alderucci et al. 2020). To our knowledge, none of the empirical papers quantified the impact of AI technologies on firm productivity while accounting for a cause–effect relationship.
This study aims to fill the gap observed in prior research with further and novel empirical evidence. Using a comprehensive definition of AI that refers to the combination of software and hardware components including robotics and taking stock from the literature of innovative AI landscapes (Van Roy et al. 2020), we employ a unique database of 5257 AI patenting firms to evaluate the effect of AI technologies on firm labor productivity. We test for this potential impact using a worldwide sample of companies from four continents that have filed at least one patent related to the field of AI between 2000 and 2016, combining patent applications from the Worldwide Patent Statistical database (PATSTAT) of the European Patent Office with firms’ financial information from Bureau Van Dijk’s ORBIS database. The empirical analysis makes use of a dynamic panel data model estimated with System General Method of Moments (GMM-SYS) and derived from a knowledge-stock augmented production function, which allows us to control for endogeneity and for persistent firm-level differences in productivity levels.
While controlling for patenting activities in non-AI related fields, our findings reveal a positive and significant impact of AI patent applications on labor productivity. This effect concentrates on small and medium enterprises (SMEs) and services industries, suggesting that in the largest companies and most innovative manufacturing sectors the effect of AI patenting is (perhaps yet) not-distinguishable from the larger effect of non-AI patenting. We attribute the heterogeneity of the effects to the diverse pace of different types of firms to fully exploit AI applications in their production process.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. In the next section, we provide an overview of the theoretical and empirical literature exploring the recent upsurge of artificial intelligence and we highlight in particular the literature analyzing the relationship between artificial intelligence and productivity. In Sect. 3, we present the empirical model based on an augmented productivity model, in which AI patent applications are used to capture a firm’s change in knowledge stock in AI. The data construction, variables used in the empirical estimations and summary statistics are highlighted in Sect. 4. After presenting the empirical results in Sect. 5, we discuss our findings and their implications. We conclude with a discussion of the limitations of our study and possible avenues for future research.

2 Literature on artificial intelligence and productivity

The recent upsurge of innovations in technologies related to AI and robotics spurred an intense debate on their consequences on interlinked social outcomes such as growth, productivity, employment, earnings and inequality. Classical economic theories predict that, ultimately, economic growth depends on technological change and innovation (Solow 1957; Romer 1990; Aghion and Howitt 1992). More recent theories, such as the one of skill-biased technological change, posit that technological innovation may lead to wage polarization through relative increases in the demand of skilled workers with respect to unskilled ones (Autor et al. 2003; Barbieri et al. 2020), and to possible job losses through the automation of tasks (Autor and Dorn 2013; Vivarelli 1995, 2013; Piva and Vivarelli 2018; Josten and Lordan 2020). Yet, displacement effects may be potentially outweighed by a productivity effect if automation expands labor demand through the efficiencies brought to production (Acemoglu and Restrepo 2018, 2019a, b, 2020).
As for productivity, economic theories predict a positive impact of technological change on productivity. Yet, sluggish productivity characterizes advanced economies since the 1970s, even within industries intensively investing in digital innovation (the so-called “Productivity Paradox”, Brynjolfsson 1993), with almost half of the slowdown attributed to labor productivity (Gordon 2018). Recent progresses in the AI technology and its vast applicability raised hopes to revert the persistently gloomy productivity trend and revitalize the economy as a whole. AI has the potential to generate productivity gains through a number of channels including the reduction of uncertainties in reason of increased precision of forecasts (Agrawal et al. 2019a), the automated recombination of existing technologies (Agrawal et al. 2019b) and, more generally, the generation of new innovations (Bartelsman et al. 2019; Cockburn et al. 2019). The fact that low productivity growth is continuing even in recent years of sharp technological improvements in AI may depend on the time lag the AI revolution requires to allow complementary inventions to develop, businesses to reorganize and workers to upskill in order to diffuse across the economy (Brynjolfsson et al. 2019).
Not all authors agree on such an enthusiastic view. Gordon (2016, 2018) argues that the productivity slowdown is permanent and that current innovations, including the digital and even the AI revolutions, raised too optimistic expectations as being less disruptive that those that generated the spectacular productivity growth observed in the United Sates between the 1920s and 1970s, such as the electric power and the internal combustion engine. Using a large dataset of inventors, Jones (2009) shows that both the age at first invention, and the specialization and teamwork increase over time. He argues that more and more learning is required for researchers to get capable of pushing the frontier forward. Bloom et al. (2020) document a sharp decline in research productivity across various industries, products, and firms and argue that ideas are getting harder to find. On a different angle, Gries and Naudé (2018) stress the potential role of aggregate demand. In particular, automation and AI lead to declining earnings and labor share as well as increasing inequality with few agents getting the surplus of innovations, which may hinder the full potential capacity for growth and hence productivity.
Given the multiple contrasting theoretical views at stake, rigorous empirical investigation is required to shed light on the issue. The key contribution of this study is to be among the first to assess to what extent AI and robotics innovation affect the productivity of the firms that develop such technologies. Empirical evidence to date is scant, mainly focused on the use of robots at the aggregate level, and not conclusive. As stressed by Raj and Seamans (2019), augmenting empirical evidence on AI invention, AI adoption, and its effects at the firm level is highly valuable. Graetz and Michaels (2018) use country-level data on worldwide delivery of industrial robots and find that robots may have increased average aggregate productivity growth by more than 15 percent for 17 countries between 1993 and 2007. Among the few studies at the firm level, the European Commission (2016), based on a sample of 3000 manufacturing firms in seven European countries, reports that the use of industrial robots is associated with higher levels of labor productivity.
Closer to this study, Alderucci et al. (2020) combine patents related to AI with firm-level microdata from the US Census Bureau for the period 1997–2016, and assess the impact of AI on various outcomes. By comparing AI-inventing firms with a comparable set of similar control firms (i.e. that never patented in AI), they find that the invention of the first AI patent in their sample is related to subsequent increases in sales, employment and within-firm earnings inequality compared to the control group. The study does not claim to report causal effects as both the choice to make the first invention in AI and the outcomes could be due to some common unobserved reason and being therefore endogenous. As for sales per worker, which is similar to the outcome measure under investigation in this study, the authors report an average 4.15% increase after the first AI-related invention, and a negative effect on manufacturing and positive one in services. These are arguably the only existing benchmarks for our analysis and findings, and we will come back to them in the discussion of results.

3 Empirical model

We derive our empirical specification from a knowledge stock augmented Cobb Douglas model (e.g., Lokshin et al. 2008; Hall et al. 2012; Belderbos et al. 2013, 2015), in which a firm’s productivity is a function of capital stock, labor, and the available knowledge stocks for firm i at time t:
$$Y_{it} = \alpha_{i} L_{it}^{\beta } C_{it}^{\gamma } K_{it}^{\delta } e^{{\sigma_{it} }}$$
(1)
where Y is output, L is labor input, C is the physical capital stock and K is the knowledge stock. The parameters β, γ and δ are elasticities with respect to labor, physical capital and the knowledge stock. The constant term αi represents firm-specific and time-invariant characteristics that enable to reach higher productivity levels (such as organizational or managerial abilities). The parameter σit is a time-variant firm-specific efficiency parameter.
Dividing both sides by labor, taking natural logarithms, and differentiating the resulting equation in two consecutive periods (through which the firm fixed effects αi drop out), we obtain the equation in its growth form:
$$p_{it} = (1 + \theta )p_{it - 1} + (\beta - 1)\Delta l_{it} + \delta \Delta c_{it} + \gamma \Delta k_{it} + \mu_{i} + \varepsilon_{it}$$
(2)
where lower case letters denote variables in natural logarithms, pit denotes labor productivity, \(\Delta l_{it}\) is the growth in labor input, \(\Delta c_{it}\) is growth in fixed capital and \(\Delta k_{it}\) is the change in knowledge stock. Lastly, \(\mu_{i}\) is the idiosyncratic individual and time-invariant firm’s fixed effect and \(\varepsilon_{it}\) the usual error term.
Moving from the static expression (1) to a dynamic specification as in (2) allows to account for persistency in productivity differences (Klette 1996). This specification allows for gradual convergence in efficiency levels between firms, which has been observed to be important in the empirical productivity literature, with lagging firms able to improve their productivity faster (Klette 1996; Klette and Johansen 1998; Blundell and Bond 2000; Lokshin et al. 2008; Hall et al. 2012). The convergence parameter is denoted by \(\theta\) and highlights the share of productivity lead that disappears through convergence in a year.
We take the change in knowledge capital stock as a function of the inflow of AI and non-AI patent applications (respectively denoted by \(Pat_{it}^{AI}\) and \(Pat_{it}^{{Non{ - }AI}}\)):
$$\gamma \Delta k_{it} = \varphi Pat_{it}^{AI} + \eta Pat_{it}^{{Non{ - }AI}}$$
(3)
The rationale for approaching the knowledge stock as a function of the innovation efforts in AI and non-AI related fields is discussed in Sect. 4.
The estimation of dynamic production functions is not a straightforward process as methodological problems due to simultaneity and endogeneity can result in biased estimations of factor elasticities. To tackle these issues, we use a system GMM approach as developed by Blundell and Bond (1998, 2000). The system GMM model provides a flexible estimation method to deal with endogenous, predetermined or strictly exogenous regressors. As such, system GMM allows for consistent and efficient estimates when dealing with dynamic panel data, as is the case for our data. This is achieved by means of a system of equations, including a level equation and an equation in first differences that are running simultaneously. In these equations, lagged and differenced lagged variables are used to solve for persistency in time series and endogeneity problems.
By construction, the dynamic production function suffers from endogeneity given the presence of the lagged labor productivity. However, as pointed out in the majority of studies using knowledge-stock augmented Cobb–Douglas models (Piva and Vivarelli 2005; Lokshin et al. 2008; Bogliacino et al. 2012; Van Roy et al. 2018), production input variables of labor, physical capital and knowledge stock may be equally affected. In line with the literature, all the explanatory variables have been considered as potentially endogenous to labor productivity and instrumented in all models.
In the level equation, we use differenced values of the right-hand side variables as instruments, i.e. twice-lagged differences in labor productivity, AI and non-AI patent applications, employment growth, fixed capital growth, and firm size. The level equations also include a set of sector, country and year dummies. In the equations in differences we employ twice-lagged values of the above-mentioned explanatory variables as instruments. The lag limits of the instruments were chosen as to satisfy the outcomes of the autocorrelation tests, to identify a valid set of instruments and to limit instrument proliferation, as highlighted in Roodman (2009a, b).

4 Data and variables

4.1 Dataset construction

The choice of using firms’ patent portfolios as a measure of the stock of prior knowledge for new knowledge production relies on several considerations. Many previous studies resume to R&D expenditures as a measure of firms’ effort to innovate that presumably translates into new knowledge (e.g. Hall and Mairesse 1995; Hall et al. 2012; Belderbos et al. 2015; Ortega-Argilés et al. 2015; Castellani et al. 2019). Yet, R&D expenditures are typically aggregated measures retrieved through firms’ balance sheets, having thus no purpose in studies aiming to focus on specific types of knowledge inputs, as this study does for AI. While traditionally considered as a measure of innovation output (Griliches 1990; Ernst 1995), the present study argues that the patent portfolio of a firm at a given point in time makes a good job at measuring its current knowledge usable for production, by capturing to a good degree of approximation its previous innovative efforts.
This is particularly true for general-purpose technologies such as AI, and even more for machine learning, which has been described as a “method of invention” (Cockburn et al. 2019). This approach is shared by the only other paper to our knowledge that studies the effects of AI at the firm level (Alderucci et al. 2020). In particular, Alderucci et al. (2020, p. 2) claim that “Firms that succeed in using artificial intelligence to create new goods and services have a strong incentive to patent at least some of their inventions. If they fail to do so, other firms can copy their innovations without penalty or use patents to block the original innovator from applying their inventions in the marketplace.” We are aware of the limitations that patents have in capturing innovation, as extensively discussed in previous studies (e.g. Hussinger 2006; Hall et al. 2014), for instance the fact that company may prefer not to patent their inventions to keep them secret. Yet, patents have the appealing advantage to allow tracking and analyzing the use and diffusion of AI technologies in the economy across time and space. Second, patents provide a practical solution for the problem of identifying on a global scale firms that innovate in AI.
Identifying patents related to AI technologies is far from a trivial task. First, there is no established definition to set out the composition and boundaries of AI. The rapid evolution of the field of AI makes its definitions challenging for many of its observers (OECD 2017; European Commission 2018; WIPO 2019). AI typically refers to a diversity of software technologies including, inter alia, machine learning, neural networks, logic programing, and speech recognition. The most important aspects of any definition are the ability of systems to think and act humanly (reasoning and behavioral perspective) aiming to obtain rational outcomes (Ertel 2018; Russell and Norvig 2016). Since automation is a key feature of AI technologies, many studies consider robotics as an integral part of it (European Commission 2018; Fujii and Managi 2018; WIPO 2019). This is especially true as the diffusion of AI brings about the digital interconnection of robots and sensors and the use of “big data” for better optimizing the production process in what is often referred to as Industry 4.0. We believe that to best capture this ongoing, expanding process, it is more appropriate to follow the approach of the European Commission (2018) and apply for this study a comprehensive definition of AI and refer to the combination of software and hardware components (including robotics).
A second main difficulty in identifying patents in the field of AI relates to the nature of AI technologies. As any other general-purpose technology, AI is transversal in nature, i.e. cutting through many scientific disciplines and used in an increasing number of sectors. To overcome these difficulties, previous studies used a keyword approach (De Prato et al. 2018; European Commission 2018) or a pre-selection of AI-related technological classes (Fujii and Managi 2018) or a combination of the two approaches (Cockburn et al. 2019; WIPO 2019). Alderucci et al. (2020) is the first study to make use of advanced AI machine learning techniques to parse the patent corpus in order to identify AI-related patents.
Van Roy et al. (2020), on which this study relies upon for the selection of patents, used a keyword-based approach consisting in the development of a dictionary of AI-related keywords to be retrieved in either the patent’s title or abstract. Text-mining searches have been conducted on patent families1 in the Spring 2018 edition of the PATSTAT database from the European Patent Office (see Van Roy et al. 2020 for additional details).2 Next, the application number of all identified AI patent families served as a link with the patent and company balance sheet data in Bureau van Dijk Electronic Publishing (BvD) ORBIS databases. A first link was established with the ORBIS Patent database in order to obtain the firm’s identifier for those patents having among the applicants a firm collected in the ORBIS Companies database. For the linked firms, key location and financial information could be obtained from the ORBIS Companies database. For the purpose of this study, the sample of firms was augmented with their portfolio of all non-AI patent families (Appendix 1 shows a scheme summarizing the data collection process). While the issues of coverage and data availability are known limitations of ORBIS, these are by far outweighed by its advantage of offering a comprehensive cross-country micro-level dataset for scientific research purposes (e.g. Gal 2013; Hallak and Harasztosi 2019).

4.2 Variables and sample

The final dataset covers 5257 firms active in AI patenting for the years 2000–2016. It has a worldwide coverage and includes firms belonging to manufacturing and service sectors. It provides information on firms’ patenting activities in AI and non-AI related fields, accounting information (including turnover, employment, and capital formation), country location, and industrial activity (NACE sector at 2-digit level). By including only firms active in AI patenting, the sample may be affected by a “cherry-picking” effect as it is, by construction, more technology-driven and, in the case of SMEs, there might be selection of the champions, not necessarily representing the majority of small companies.
Our dependent variable is defined as the natural logarithm of firm labor productivity. This choice of dependent variable derives from a knowledge-augmented production function framework, which we adopt to model the effects of innovative AI technologies on firm performance (see Sect. 3).
The key explanatory variable of interest is AI patent applications, which measures the change in a firm’s knowledge stock in the field of AI. Since patents can differ both in economic and technological value, simple patent count may give a distorted impression of a firm’s technological basis. Therefore, other indicators have been proposed to correct for quality or value of patents, such as forward citation-weighted patents and family size (Harhoff et al. 2003; Hall et al. 2005; Gambardella, et al. 2008; Neuhäusler et al. 2011; Squicciarini et al. 2013; Van Roy et al. 2018). Using any of these quality-corrected indicators is particularly difficult in the case of AI, as the real take-off of AI patenting activities took place relatively late (since the late 2000s), and boomed only from 2015 onwards (Cockburn et al. 2019; WIPO 2019; Van Roy et al. 2020).
In addition to the number of AI patent applications as proxy for a firms’ knowledge stock, we also take into account innovative efforts in non-AI related fields. This is done by incorporating the number non-AI patent applications into the knowledge stock function. We use the actual number of patents in a given year rather than the cumulative number as to proxy for the change in knowledge stock as highlighted in Sect. 3. Other variables included in the dynamic productivity model are the growth in employment, measured as the number of employees expressed in full-time equivalents, and the growth in the capital stock, approximated by the growth in fixed capital. The models control for firm size (employment), industry, year and country-specific differences in labor productivity dynamics. Definitions of the variables entering the empirical models are provided in Appendix 2.
Table 1 reports the summary statistics of the dependent and explanatory variables used in the estimations. It presents scores for the full sample as well as for two sub-periods. The two sub-periods are defined based on the following considerations. The financial and economic crises of 2008–2009 serves as a natural divide, as it was followed by a marked, prolonged global slowdown in productivity growth (Dieppe 2020). The crisis also entailed opportunities for firms to follow strategies of creative destruction rather than creative accumulation (Archibugi et al. 2013). Furthermore, it allows reflecting the difference in growth rate in AI patenting activities, which increased substantially over time, especially in the last decade (as also documented in, e.g. Van Roy et al. 2020). To remove observations with possible erroneous values in the data and to prevent outliers from heavily affecting estimation results, we omitted the top 1% values of the distribution of all accounting variables in both the summary statistics and empirical analyses.
Table 1
Summary statistics of the dependent and explanatory variables for the full sample and across periods
Variable name
Full sample
Period 2000–2008
Period 2009–2016
N = 40,717
N = 17,247
N = 23,470
Mean
SD
Mean
SD
Mean
SD
Labor productivity
280,319
312,349
261,061
293,628
294,471
324,699
AI patent applications
0.48
2.60
0.37
2.00
0.56
2.97
Non-AI patent applications
61.18
160.81
65.11
171.52
58.29
152.40
Labor productivity growth
10.03
44.16
9.91
44.73
10.12
43.74
Employment growth
5.76
27.11
6.82
28.91
4.98
25.68
Fixed capital growth
17.68
62.94
16.81
64.43
18.31
61.81
Firm size
5995
16,561
5670
15,466
6233
17,318
Firms in the sample report an average labor productivity growth of 10%, and employment and fixed capital growth rates of, respectively, 5% and 17%. These high growth rates are not surprising as the sample includes highly innovative firms having applied for at least one AI-related patent in the full period. AI patent applications are relatively low, about 1 AI-related patent per year every two firms in the sample, due to a highly skewed distribution, and increases from about 0.4 per firm-year on average between 2000 and 2008 to almost 0.6 between 2009 and 2016. Non-AI patent activity is, by contrast, substantial and slightly declines in the second sub-period (form about 65 to about 58 non-AI-related patent applications per company per year).
Table 2 presents the distribution of firms across sectors, high- and low-tech manufacturing and firm size. With respect to the distribution of firms across sectors, we note that 60% are active in manufacturing and 40% in services. Within manufacturing sectors, high-technology firms are largely over-represented, constituting about 80% of the sample. The machinery and electronics sector are the most represented manufacturing sectors with respective percentages of 25% and 14%. Not surprisingly, the telecommunications sector and the sector of professional, scientific and technical services constitute the largest service sectors with respective percentages around 16% and 8%. We refer to Appendix 3 for a more detailed distribution of firms across sectors.
Table 2
Distribution of firms across sectors, high- and low-tech manufacturing and firm size
 
Full sample
Period 2000–2008
Period 2009–2016
 
Observations
Firms
Observations
Firms
Observations
Firms
 
Numbers
%
Numbers
%
Numbers
%
Numbers
%
Numbers
%
Numbers
%
Sector
            
Manufacturing
26,928
66.13
3205
60.97
11,709
67.89
2385
65.58
15,219
64.84
2918
61.68
Services
13,789
33.87
2052
39.03
5538
32.11
1252
34.42
8251
35.16
1813
38.32
Manufacturing
            
High-tech
21,263
78.96
2578
80.44
9194
78.52
1920
80.50
12,069
79.30
2345
80.36
Low-tech
5665
21.04
627
19.56
2515
21.48
465
19.50
3150
20.70
573
19.64
Firm size
            
SME
18,624
45.74
2833
53.89
7654
44.38
1813
49.85
10,970
46.74
2492
52.67
Large firm
22,093
54.26
2424
46.11
9593
55.62
1824
50.15
12,500
53.26
2239
47.33
Total
40,717
100.00
5257
100.00
17,247
100.00
3637
100.00
23,470
100.00
4731
100.00
We split manufacturing into high and low-tech sectors, according to the Eurostat classification (European Commission 2016; Hatzichronoglou 1997). For the definition of SMEs we follow the EC recommendation in which SMEs are denoted as firms with a number of employees below 250 and a turnover equal to or below € 50 million (European Commission 2003)
In terms of geographical distribution, two-thirds of the firms are located in Asia. This large percentage is driven by the dominating AI patenting activity of Japanese, South-Korean and Chinese firms as highlighted in prior studies (WIPO 2019; Van Roy et al. 2020). A quarter of the firms are located in Europe, with highest percentages in Germany, United Kingdom and France. Lastly, firms in the United States constitute around 10% of the sample. The low share of firms based in the United States depend on the well-known low coverage of ORBIS in the United States. Yet, we opted to include them to enhance the geographic coverage of the sample. We refer to Appendix 3 for a more detailed distribution of firms across regions and countries.

5 Empirical results

The results from the one-step System GMM estimation defined in Eq. (2) using the full sample—40,717 observations originating from 5257 firms active in AI patenting activities—are presented in Table 3.3 Overall, the full model performs well and reveals highly significant coefficients with the expected signs. Both the Wald test on the overall significance of the regressions and the LM tests on AR (1) and AR (2) autocorrelation dynamics provide fully reassuring diagnostic results on the model. At the same time, the null hypothesis of adequate instruments is rejected by the Hansen test. However, Blundell and Bond (2000) and Roodman (2009a) showed that the Hansen test over-rejects the null in case of very large samples. In order to address this issue, the same model was run and the Hansen test was performed on different random sub-samples comprising 10% of the original data. The null was never rejected in this bootstrapping exercise, providing reassurance on the validity of the selected instruments.4
Table 3
Results for the GMM-SYS analysis—full model and subsamples across periods
 
Labor productivity
 
Full model
Period
 
2000–2008
2009–2016
Labor productivity t-1
0.544***
0.621***
0.517***
 
(0.054)
(0.060)
(0.092)
AI patent applications
0.032***
0.011
0.030**
 
(0.011)
(0.014)
(0.015)
Non-AI patent applications
0.019***
0.024*
0.029***
 
(0.007)
(0.013)
(0.010)
Employment growth
− 0.470***
− 0.480***
− 0.497***
 
(0.032)
(0.036)
(0.052)
Fixed capital growth
0.088***
0.123***
0.080***
 
(0.022)
(0.024)
(0.029)
Firm size
0.013
− 0.082
0.083
 
(0.047)
(0.057)
(0.071)
Industry and country dummies
Included
Included
Included
Year dummies
Included
Included
Included
Observations
40,717
17,247
23,470
Number of firms
5257
3637
4731
Wald test
4648.64***
28,906.45***
5375.37***
AR(1)
− 8.78***
− 6.69***
− 6.50***
AR(2)
− 1.22
− 0.68
− 0.34
Nr. of instruments
107
94
97
Hansen test
11.59**
15.81***
851.67***
Standard errors in parentheses. Significance levels are represented as: ***p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1. All variables are expressed in natural logarithms
The models presented in the table are based on system GMM estimations with collapse option to reduce the number of instruments
The estimated coefficient of the lagged labor productivity equals 0.54.5 This indicates a comparatively mild persistence in productivity: approximately half of the productivity lead disappears through convergence. The models indicate an elasticity of output with respect to employment of about 0.53 (1–0.47) and an elasticity of fixed capital around 0.09, while the coefficient estimated for firm size is not statistically significant. These estimates are in line with other studies using a similar production function framework (Fors 1997; Belderbos et al. 2013, 2015).
Table 4
Results for the GMM-SYS analysis—subsamples for the period 2009-2016
 
Labor productivity
 
Full model
Sector
Manufacturing
Firm type
 
Manufacturing
Services
High-tech
Low-tech
SMEs
Large firms
Labor productivity t–1
0.517***
0.567***
0.491***
0.551***
0.603***
0.447***
0.581***
 
(0.092)
(0.086)
(0.175)
(0.090)
(0.129)
(0.105)
(0.180)
AI patent applications
0.030**
0.006
0.077**
0.003
− 0.005
0.069*
0.007
 
(0.015)
(0.014)
(0.034)
(0.016)
(0.029)
(0.040)
(0.011)
Non-AI patent applications
0.029***
0.035***
0.022
0.033***
0.039
0.014
0.033***
 
(0.010)
(0.011)
(0.021)
(0.012)
(0.027)
(0.017)
(0.010)
Employment growth
− 0.497***
− 0.491***
− 0.548***
− 0.456***
− 0.622***
− 0.436***
− 0.540***
 
(0.052)
(0.056)
(0.097)
(0.056)
(0.106)
(0.074)
(0.086)
Fixed capital growth
0.080***
0.088***
0.072
0.099***
0.064
0.039
0.129**
 
(0.029)
(0.030)
(0.055)
(0.026)
(0.068)
(0.043)
(0.050)
Firm size
0.083
0.069
0.163
0.022
0.248
0.086
− 0.049
 
(0.071)
(0.088)
(0.126)
0.087)
(0.154)
(0.146)
(0.098)
Industry and country dummies
Included
Included
Included
Included
Included
Included
Included
Year dummies
Included
Included
Included
Included
Included
Included
Included
Observations
23,470
15,219
8251
12,069
3150
9780
13,690
Number of firms
4731
2918
1813
2345
573
2359
2566
Wald test
5375.37***
3853.71***
48,300.52***
4033.07***
1796.96***
41,176.39***
5531.24***
AR(1)
− 6.50***
− 6.29***
− 3.53***
− 5.79***
− 3.27***
− 5.71***
− 3.45***
AR(2)
− 0.34
− 0.56
0.08
− 0.76
0.38
0.25
− 2
Nr. of instruments
97
76
78
67
60
86
90
Hansen test
851.67***
16.65***
373.42***
16.71***
8.59
2.99***
2304.37***
Standard errors in parentheses. Significance levels are represented as: ***p<0.01, **p<0.05, *p<0.1. All variables are expressed in natural logarithms. We split manufacturing into high and low-tech sectors, according to the Eurostat classification (European Commission 2016; Hatzichronoglou 1997). For the definition of SMEs we follow the EC recommendation in which SMEs are denoted as firms with a number of employees below 250 and a turnover equal to or below € 50 million (European Commission 2003).
Turning our attention to the main variable of interest, the estimate shows a positive and significant effect of AI patent applications on labor productivity as measured by turnover per worker. This effect is far from negligible: if a firm increases its innovative effort in the field of AI and doubles its number of AI patent applications, the predicted increase in labor productivity amounts to 3%. For the full model, companies’ stock of patent applications in technologies other than AI also turns out to be significant (with a lower effect of about 2%), confirming the potential of the AI technology to enhance productivity. This result is compatible with those by Alderucci et al. (2020), which report in the United States between 1997 and 2016 an average increase by 4.15% in the sales per worker of firms making their first AI-related invention as compared to a control group of similar firms that did not file any AI patent.
The results from the separate estimations on the 2000–2008 and 2009–2016 sub-periods indicate an increasing importance of AI over time. AI patent applications have no significant effect on labor productivity in the first sub-period, while having a positive, significant effect only in the sub-period following 2009. The AI technology in the first period was still less mature, characterized by less frequent patenting, and firms probably having less experience in fully exploiting it.
Further investigations were carried out on the subsample covering the more recent time period (2009–2016) in order to better understand structural differences in the impact of AI across industries and companies of varying size. Splitting the sample by industry reveals that AI patent applications are only significant in services (see Table 4). The effect of AI patent applications on labor productivity turns out to be relative strong, elevating at 7.7%. At the same time, the effects of non-AI patent applications as well as fixed capital growth are not significant in the service sector. By contrast, non-AI patent applications have a particularly stronger effect in manufacturing industries, mainly captured in the high-technology manufacturing. Interestingly, the study by Alderucci et al. (2020) on US companies also finds a positive significant effect of AI on sales per worker only in the service industries, while a negative one in manufacturing.
While firm size shows no significant effect on labor productivity, there is a marked difference between SMEs and large firms in the effect of AI patent applications on labor productivity. The effect is significant in the subsample comprising SMEs, with relatively high coefficients (0.07) similar to what was observed for the service sector, while insignificant for large firms. In contrast, large firms report a particularly strong effect of non-AI related patent applications.6

6 Discussion and conclusion

As the ongoing debate on the impact of the technological development in AI and robotics on productivity offers contrasting predictions (Gordon 2016, 2018; Gries and Naudé 2018; Agrawal et al. 2019a, b; Brynjolfsson et al. 2019; Cockburn et al. 2019), empirical studies can offer important insights. Yet, only a handful of papers have investigated the effects of AI and robotics on productivity (Graetz and Micheals 2018; Alderucci et al. 2020). To our knowledge, none of the empirical papers quantified the impact of AI technologies on firm productivity while accounting for a causal-effect relationship.
In this study, we aim to contribute to closing this gap in the literature by employing a unique database of 5257 AI patenting firms to evaluate the short-term effect of AI technologies on firm labor productivity. We test for this potential impact using a sample of worldwide companies having filed at least a patent related to the field of AI between 2000 and 2016. While controlling for firms’ patenting activities in non-AI related fields, our findings reveal a positive and significant impact of AI patent applications on labor productivity. This effect concentrates on SMEs and services industries, suggesting that in the largest and most innovative manufacturing sectors the effect of AI patenting is (perhaps yet) not-distinguishable from the larger effect of non-AI patenting.
Our findings indicate the presence of technological opportunities for economic activities and types of businesses typically characterized by comparatively low capital intensity, organizational complexity and patenting activity. We attribute this evidence to the low economic maturity of the AI technology. Smaller, more agile AI-patenting firms may have been able to readjust faster and introduce AI-based applications in their production processes at a scale allowing the creation of a significant impact on productivity. The larger, more diverse patent portfolio of non-AI technologies, by contrast, still dominates the productivity generating process of the larger and more complex firms, which could take longer to fully exploit in its value chain and upskill the existing workforce to fully benefit from their AI inventions. The low economic maturity of the AI technology is also confirmed by the finding that a significant effect is only observed in the more recent years of the sample. More time is needed to assess whether AI technology development and adoption will generate productivity gains also to large and manufacturing firms, a task which is left for future research to address.
In all subsamples used in the analysis, i.e. manufacturing and high-tech manufacturing, services, SMEs and large firms, the majority of firms patent more in non-AI than in AI technologies. Yet, there are clear signals of technological specialization among SMEs and firms operating in services. More than a quarter of the SMEs and more than 22% firms operating in services only record AI patenting activities and have no patents in other fields. The non-trivial share of firms patenting exclusively in AI contributes to explaining the positive effect on the firm’s labor productivity growth as well as the lack of significance of non-AI patents on productivity for these groups of firms.
Our study has a number of limitations, which qualify the results and suggest avenues for future research. First, only firms filing at least one patent in AI during the period 2000–2016 entered our sample at study. As patenting in AI is a signal of technological excellence, our sample may be affected by a “cherry-picking” effect, especially in the case of SMEs, and the results may incur in a sample selection bias. A clear opportunity for future research would be to test our findings on a sample also including companies that do not patent at all as well as companies patenting in non-AI related fields only.
A second limitation, which is common to most scientific studies related to AI, is the lack of a precise and universally accepted definition of artificial intelligence. Due to the lack of clarity and consensus around the term, studies aimed at mapping the innovative landscape of AI typically use different dictionaries of AI-related keywords (De Prato et al. 2018; European Commission 2018; Van Roy et al. 2020), sometimes combined with pre-selected technological or scientific fields (Cockburn et al. 2019; WIPO 2019). Results of this study rely on the keywords developed by Van Roy et al. (2020). To test the robustness of the analysis, it may be interesting to evaluate to what extent results holds when using different keywords. This calls for studies to compare the robustness of different keyword-based approaches (Bianchini et al. 2020a). In addition, keyword-based dictionaries require regular updates to capture the rapidly evolving changes in AI technologies. A promising avenue rests on AI itself. Recent contributions propose machine learning techniques that train their algorithms on pre-selected bundle of AI patents (Alderucci et al. 2020) or scientific publications (Bianchini et al. 2020b) in order to identify the most appropriate keywords (or clusters of them) to be used in larger sets of corpus.
Third, while AI patents have the important advantage to be available at a large scale across countries and time, it does not allow to capture the full richness of innovative developments in AI. As we rely on AI patent applications, our model does not include inventions protected by other formal (e.g. software copyrights) and informal (e.g. secrecy) intellectual property rights.
We have seen in our study that the acceleration and diffusion of AI and robotics inventions are more recent developments. This also explains why so few studies have attempted to conduct larger scale econometric analyses so far. We expect that as more evidence becomes available at the firm level over time, it will also open up new possibilities for refined analyses on both the economic impact of AI as well as the underlying mechanisms.

Acknowledgements

The authors are grateful to the participants of the 2019 Workshops “Data infrastructure for mapping production and diffusion of AI technologies” (Copenhagen Business School, Copenhagen) and “The Economics and Management of AI Technologies” (BETA—Université de Strasbourg, France) and of the 2020 virtual Workshop “Timely topics in innovation: AI, digitalization and inter-regional investments” (European Commission, Joint Research Centre) for helpful comments and suggestions. The authors acknowledge financial support from the European Union’s Horizon 2020 Framework Programme under the ‘Innova Measure IV’ project (Grant agreement no. 857088).

Compliance with ethical standards

Conflict of interest

The scientific output expressed here are those of the authors and does not imply a policy position of the European Commission or the International Telecommunication Union and their Member States. Neither the European Commission nor any person acting on behalf of the Commission is responsible for the use which might be made of this study.
Open AccessThis article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://​creativecommons.​org/​licenses/​by/​4.​0/​.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Appendix

Appendix 1: Data sources and matching procedure

For the collection of AI patents, we draw on a database of AI patents developed by Van Roy et al. (2020). Given the transversal nature of AI, it is particularly difficult to identify which patents are related to the field of AI. To overcome this difficulty, many researchers have used keyword-based approaches in which a collection of AI-related terms (identified by experts in the field) are searched in the text of the patent document (European Commission 2018; Cockburn et al. 2019; De Prato et al., 2018; Keisner et al. 2015; WIPO, 2019). Taking stock of the AI-related keywords employed in this prior literature, Van Roy et al. (2020) developed an AI-related dictionary, displayed in Table
Table 5
List of keywords related to Artificial Intelligence
Keywords related to artificial intelligence
Artificial intelligence
Face recognition
Random forest
Artificial intelligent
Facial recognition
Reinforcement learning
Artificial reality
Gesture recognition
Robotics
Augmented realities
Holographic display
Self drive
Augmented reality
Humanoid robot
Sentiment analysis
Automatic classification
Internet of things
Smart glasses
Autonomous car
Knowledge representation
Speech recognition
Autonomous vehicle
Machine intelligence
Statistical learning
Bayesian modeling
Machine learn
Supervized learning
Big data
Machine to machine
Transfer learning
Computational neuroscience
Mixed reality
Unmanned aerial vehicle
Computer vision
Natural language processing
Unmanned aircraft system
Data mining
Neural network
Unsupervised learning
Data science
Neuro-linguistic programing
Virtual reality
Decision tree
Object detection
Voice recognition
Deep learn
Predictive modeling
 
Evolutionary computation
Probabilistic modeling
 
Based on Van Roy et al. (2020)
5.
Figure 1 presents a scheme summarizing the data collection process. To retrieve AI patents, the list of AI keywords has been processed by Tools for Innovation Monitoring (TIM), which is an analytics tool developed by the Joint Research Centre to support policy-making in the field of innovation and technological development. TIM provides access to patent documents of the PATSTAT database from the European Patent Office and allows for text-mining searches. TIM contains patents from more than 90 patent authorities including all the major patenting countries and regroups patent documents per patent family when at least one of the members of the family is in English.
Once the relevant patent families in AI have been retrieved with this text-mining technique, the patent family number has been linked with the ORBIS patent database. Subsequently, patent applicants have been linked to their BVD ID number to obtain account information on turnover, employment, fixed capital and sector.

Appendix 2: Variable names and definitions

See Table
Table 6
Description of the variables
Variable name
Variable definition
Labor productivity
Natural logarithm of labor productivity (turnover/number of employees)
Labor productivity t−1
Natural logarithm of labor productivity in t−1
AI patent applications
Natural logarithm of the number of AI patent applications
Non-AI patent applications
Natural logarithm of the number of non-AI patent applications
Employment growth
Natural logarithm of employment in t—natural logarithm of employment in t−1
Fixed capital growth
Natural logarithm of fixed capital in t—natural logarithm of fixed capital in t−1
Firm size
Natural logarithm of number of employees
The number of AI and non-AI patent applications are defined as yearly patent applications
6.

Appendix 3: Country and sector summary statistics

See Tables
Table 7
Distribution of firms across regions and countries
 
Observations
Firms
 
Numbers
%
Numbers
%
Asia
26,626
65.39
3531
67.17
Japan
11,432
28.08
888
16.89
South-Korea
9406
23.10
1468
27.92
China
4456
10.94
991
18.85
Taiwan
1065
2.62
149
2.83
Rest of Asia
267
0.66
35
0.67
Europe
10,175
24.99
1252
23.82
Germany
2381
5.85
337
6.41
United Kingdom
1494
3.67
150
2.85
France
1402
3.44
174
3.31
Italy
1075
2.64
117
2.23
Sweden
679
1.67
62
1.18
Spain
632
1.55
73
1.39
Belgium
348
0.85
30
0.57
Denmark
322
0.79
27
0.51
Finland
209
0.51
30
0.57
Netherlands
168
0.41
24
0.46
Romania
153
0.38
16
0.30
Austria
132
0.32
29
0.55
Poland
131
0.32
20
0.38
Czech Republic
126
0.31
18
0.34
Switzerland
107
0.26
7
0.13
Rest of Europe
816
2.00
138
2.63
United States
3774
9.27
449
8.54
Rest of World
142
0.35
25
0.48
Total
40,717
100
5257
100
7 and
Table 8
Distribution of firms across sectors
 
Observations
Firms
 
Numbers
%
Numbers
%
Manufacturing
26,928
66.13
3205
60.97
Primary
279
0.69
29
0.55
Food
209
0.51
30
0.57
Textile
273
0.67
31
0.59
Paper
322
0.79
32
0.61
Chemistry
620
3.98
166
3.16
Pharmaceutical
708
1.74
71
1.35
Minerals
356
0.87
36
0.68
Metal
2038
5.01
213
4.05
Electronics
10,221
25.10
1353
25.74
Machinery
6602
16.21
750
14.27
Transport
2782
6.83
305
5.80
Other manufacturing
1518
3.73
189
3.60
Services
13,789
33.87
2052
39.03
Construction
1290
3.17
162
3.08
Electricity/water
465
1.14
58
1.10
Retail trade
2174
5.34
305
5.80
Transport services
167
0.41
19
0.36
Hotel and catering
59
0.14
6
0.11
Telecommunication
5554
13.64
856
16.28
Finance
163
0.40
28
0.53
Real estate and rental
881
2.16
123
2.34
Scientific
2709
6.65
426
8.10
Administration/education
115
0.28
26
0.49
Other services
212
0.52
43
0.82
Total
40,717
100.00
5257
100.00
8.

Appendix 4: Model choice

See Table 9
Table 9
Results from OLS, fixed effects and GMM models
 
Labor productivity
 
OLS
Fixed effects
Diff. GMM
Sys. GMM
  
One-step
Two-step
One-step
Two-step
Labor productivity t−1
0.793***
0.450***
0.336***
0.379***
0.544***
0.479***
 
(0.014)
(0.028)
(0.046)
(0.044)
(0.054)
(0.057)
AI patent applications
0.008
0.009
0.011
0.012
0.032***
0.017*
 
(0.006)
(0.007)
(0.009)
(0.009)
(0.011)
(0.010)
Non-AI patent applications
0.016***
0.036***
0.041***
0.030**
0.019***
0.026**
 
(0.003)
(0.005)
(0.014)
(0.012)
(0.007)
(0.012)
Employment growth
− 0.558***
− 0.426***
− 0.349***
− 0.375***
− 0.470***
− 0.426***
 
(0.026)
(0.026)
(0.033)
(0.031)
(0.032)
(0.038)
Fixed capital growth
0.163***
0.103***
0.020
0.025
0.088***
0.080***
 
(0.021)
(0.025)
(0.031)
(0.029)
(0.022)
(0.023)
Firm size
− 0.003
− 0.125***
− 0.152
− 0.194
0.013
0.013
 
(0.003)
(0.021)
(0.139)
(0.129)
(0.047)
(0.054)
Constant
2.628***
7.420***
    
 
(0.229)
(0.374)
    
Industry and country dummies
Included
   
Included
Included
Year dummies
Included
Included
Included
Included
Included
Included
Observations
40,717
40,717
34,375
34,375
40,717
40,717
Number of firms
5257
5257
4651
4651
5257
5257
R-squared
0.794
0.566
    
F test
 
(22,5256)
    
  
117.14***
    
Wald test
  
1473.96***
1483.11***
4648.64***
310,084.15***
AR(1)
  
− 6.87***
− 7.49***
− 8.78***
− 8.86***
AR(2)
  
− 1.71
− 1.56
− 1.22
− 1.30
Nr. of instruments
  
28
28
107
107
Hansen test
  
7.61***
7.61***
11.59**
11.59**
Standard errors in parentheses. Significance levels are represented as: *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1. All variables are expressed in natural logarithms
The GMM models presented in the table use twice-lagged instruments, and apply the collapse option to reduce the number of instruments
.
Footnotes
1
The key advantage of using patent families is that it avoids double counting of the same or similar inventions filed in different patent offices.
 
2
Bianchini et al. (2020a) compare different keyword-based criteria on a sample of world leading corporate R&D investors (the COR&DIP© database) and find that the Van Roy et al. (2020)’s approach is more selective compared to other classifications (i.e. it reduces false positives).
 
3
Since a high instrument count may imply a downward bias in the two-step GMM-SYS standard errors (see Roodman 2009b, pp. 140–141), to be on the safer side we opted for a one-step methodology; however, a robustness check using a two-step methodology is reported in Appendix 4 (Table 9).
 
4
Results are available from the authors upon request.
 
5
Table 9 in Appendix 4 reports the Pooled Ordinary Least Squared (POLS) and Fixed Effects (FE) estimations of the baseline specification, as robustness checks. However, POLS estimates provide very preliminary and approximate results, since they do not control for unobserved individual effects and for the endogeneity of (at least) the lagged dependent variable, the corresponding coefficient being over-estimated. On the other hand, FE estimates control for individual unobservables but are still affected by the endogeneity of (at least) the lagged dependent variable, the corresponding coefficient turning out to be under-estimated. Indeed, it can be noticed that the one-step GMM coefficients of the lagged dependent variable reported in Table 4 are correctly situated within the corresponding FE (lower bound) and OLS coefficients (upper bound).
 
6
We recall that SMEs show lower average levels and higher variance in labor productivity with respect to large firms. Large firms in the sample have a very diverse patent portfolio in which also the ratio of AI patents to their stock is lower than for SMEs. It is also important to recognize that the share of SMEs among manufacturing firms is much lower than among services (43 and 62%, respectively), which may explain the sectoral differences observed above.
 
Literature
go back to reference Acemoglu, A. D., & Restrepo, P. (2020). Robots and jobs: Evidence from US labor markets. Journal of Political Economy, 128, 2188–2244. Acemoglu, A. D., & Restrepo, P. (2020). Robots and jobs: Evidence from US labor markets. Journal of Political Economy, 128, 2188–2244.
go back to reference Acemoglu, A. D., & Restrepo, P. (2019a). Automation and new tasks: How technology displaces and reinstates labor’. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 33(2), 3–30. Acemoglu, A. D., & Restrepo, P. (2019a). Automation and new tasks: How technology displaces and reinstates labor’. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 33(2), 3–30.
go back to reference Acemoglu, A. D., & Restrepo, P. (2019b). Artificial intelligence, automation and work. In A. Agrawal, J. Gans, & A. Goldfarb (Eds.), The economics of artificial intelligence: An agenda. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Acemoglu, A. D., & Restrepo, P. (2019b). Artificial intelligence, automation and work. In A. Agrawal, J. Gans, & A. Goldfarb (Eds.), The economics of artificial intelligence: An agenda. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
go back to reference Acemoglu, A. D., & Restrepo, P. (2018). The race between man and machine:Implications of technology for growth, factor shares, and employment. American Economic Review, 108(6), 1488–1542. Acemoglu, A. D., & Restrepo, P. (2018). The race between man and machine:Implications of technology for growth, factor shares, and employment. American Economic Review, 108(6), 1488–1542.
go back to reference Aghion, P, & Howitt, P. (1992). A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica, 60 (2), 323–51 Aghion, P, & Howitt, P. (1992). A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica, 60 (2), 323–51
go back to reference Agrawal, A., Gans, J. S., & Goldfarb, A. (2019a). Prediction, judgment, and complexity: a theory of decision-making and artificial intelligence. In A. Agrawal, J. Gans, & A. Goldfarb (Eds.), The economics of artificial intelligence: An agenda. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Agrawal, A., Gans, J. S., & Goldfarb, A. (2019a). Prediction, judgment, and complexity: a theory of decision-making and artificial intelligence. In A. Agrawal, J. Gans, & A. Goldfarb (Eds.), The economics of artificial intelligence: An agenda. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
go back to reference Agrawal, A., McHale, J., & Oettl, A. (2019b). Finding needles in haystacks: Artificial intelligence and recombinant growth. In A. Agrawal, J. Gans, & A. Goldfarb (Eds.), The economics of artificial intelligence: An agenda. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Agrawal, A., McHale, J., & Oettl, A. (2019b). Finding needles in haystacks: Artificial intelligence and recombinant growth. In A. Agrawal, J. Gans, & A. Goldfarb (Eds.), The economics of artificial intelligence: An agenda. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
go back to reference Alderucci, D., Branstetter, L., Hovy, E., Runge, A. & Zolas, N. (2020). Quantifying the impact of AI on productivity and labor demand: Evidence from U.S. census microdata. In Paper presented at the Allied Social Science Associations—ASSA 2020 Annual Meeting. Alderucci, D., Branstetter, L., Hovy, E., Runge, A. & Zolas, N. (2020). Quantifying the impact of AI on productivity and labor demand: Evidence from U.S. census microdata. In Paper presented at the Allied Social Science Associations—ASSA 2020 Annual Meeting.
go back to reference Archibugi, D., Filippetti, A., & Frenz, M. (2013). The impact of the economic crisis on innovation: Evidence from Europe. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 80(7), 1247–1260. Archibugi, D., Filippetti, A., & Frenz, M. (2013). The impact of the economic crisis on innovation: Evidence from Europe. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 80(7), 1247–1260.
go back to reference Autor, D., & Dorn, D. (2013). The growth of low-skill service jobs and the polarization of the US labor market. The American Economic Review, 103(5), 1553–1597. Autor, D., & Dorn, D. (2013). The growth of low-skill service jobs and the polarization of the US labor market. The American Economic Review, 103(5), 1553–1597.
go back to reference Autor, D., Levy, F., & Murnane, R. (2003). The skill content of recent technological change: an empirical exploration. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(4), 1279–1311. Autor, D., Levy, F., & Murnane, R. (2003). The skill content of recent technological change: an empirical exploration. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(4), 1279–1311.
go back to reference Barbieri, L., Mussida, C., Piva, M., & Vivarelli, M. (2020). Testing the employment and skill impact of new technologies. In K. Zimmermann (Ed.) Handbook of labor, human resources and population economics. Cham: Springer. Barbieri, L., Mussida, C., Piva, M., & Vivarelli, M. (2020). Testing the employment and skill impact of new technologies. In K. Zimmermann (Ed.) Handbook of labor, human resources and population economics. Cham: Springer.
go back to reference Bartelsman, E. J., Falk, M., Hagsten, E., & Polder, M. (2019). Productivity, technological innovations and broadband connectivity: Firm-level evidence for ten European Countries. Eurasian Business Review, 9, 25–48. Bartelsman, E. J., Falk, M., Hagsten, E., & Polder, M. (2019). Productivity, technological innovations and broadband connectivity: Firm-level evidence for ten European Countries. Eurasian Business Review, 9, 25–48.
go back to reference Bianchini, S., Millot, V., & Sorbe, S. (2020a). Artificial intelligence technologies and firm-level productivity: Preliminary evidence. Mimeo. Bianchini, S., Millot, V., & Sorbe, S. (2020a). Artificial intelligence technologies and firm-level productivity: Preliminary evidence. Mimeo.
go back to reference Bloom, N., Jones, C. I., & Van Reenen, J. (2020). Are ideas getting harder to find? American Economic Review, 110(4), 1104–1144. Bloom, N., Jones, C. I., & Van Reenen, J. (2020). Are ideas getting harder to find? American Economic Review, 110(4), 1104–1144.
go back to reference Belderbos, R., Lokshin, B., & Sadowski, B. (2015). The returns to foreign R&D. Journal of International Business Studies, 46(4), 491–504. Belderbos, R., Lokshin, B., & Sadowski, B. (2015). The returns to foreign R&D. Journal of International Business Studies, 46(4), 491–504.
go back to reference Belderbos, R., Van Roy, V., & Duvivier, F. (2013). International and domestic technology transfers and productivity growth: firm level evidence. Industrial and corporate change, 22(1), 1–32. Belderbos, R., Van Roy, V., & Duvivier, F. (2013). International and domestic technology transfers and productivity growth: firm level evidence. Industrial and corporate change, 22(1), 1–32.
go back to reference Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (2000). GMM estimation with persistent panel data: an application to production functions. Econometrics Reviews, 19, 321–340. Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (2000). GMM estimation with persistent panel data: an application to production functions. Econometrics Reviews, 19, 321–340.
go back to reference Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87, 115–143. Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87, 115–143.
go back to reference Bogliacino, F., Piva, M., & Vivarelli, M. (2012). R&D and employment: An application of the LSDVC estimator using European microdata. Economics Letters, 116(1), 56–59. Bogliacino, F., Piva, M., & Vivarelli, M. (2012). R&D and employment: An application of the LSDVC estimator using European microdata. Economics Letters, 116(1), 56–59.
go back to reference Brynjolfsson, E., Rock, D., & Syverson, C. (2019). Artificial intelligence and the modern productivity paradox: A clash of expectations and statistics. In A. Agrawal, J. Gans, & A. Goldfarb (Eds.), The economics of artificial intelligence: an agenda. Chicago: University of Chicago Press and NBER. Brynjolfsson, E., Rock, D., & Syverson, C. (2019). Artificial intelligence and the modern productivity paradox: A clash of expectations and statistics. In A. Agrawal, J. Gans, & A. Goldfarb (Eds.), The economics of artificial intelligence: an agenda. Chicago: University of Chicago Press and NBER.
go back to reference Brynjolfsson, E. (1993). The productivity paradox of information technology. Communications of the ACM, 36(12), 66–77. Brynjolfsson, E. (1993). The productivity paradox of information technology. Communications of the ACM, 36(12), 66–77.
go back to reference Castellani, D., Piva, M., Schubert, T., & Vivarelli, M. (2019). R&D and productivity in the US and the EU: Sectoral specificities and differences in the crisis. Technoloigcal Forecasting and Social Change, 138, 279–291. Castellani, D., Piva, M., Schubert, T., & Vivarelli, M. (2019). R&D and productivity in the US and the EU: Sectoral specificities and differences in the crisis. Technoloigcal Forecasting and Social Change, 138, 279–291.
go back to reference Cockburn, I., Henderson, R., & Stern, S. (2019). The impact of artificial intelligence on innovation. In A. Agrawal, J. Gans, & A. Goldfarb (Eds.), The economics of artificial intelligence: an agenda. Chicago: University of Chicago Press and NBER. Cockburn, I., Henderson, R., & Stern, S. (2019). The impact of artificial intelligence on innovation. In A. Agrawal, J. Gans, & A. Goldfarb (Eds.), The economics of artificial intelligence: an agenda. Chicago: University of Chicago Press and NBER.
go back to reference Commission, E. (2016). Analysis of the impact of robotic systems on employment in the European Union. Luxembourg: Publications Office of the European Union. Commission, E. (2016). Analysis of the impact of robotic systems on employment in the European Union. Luxembourg: Publications Office of the European Union.
go back to reference De Prato, G., Lopez Cobo, M., et al. (2018). The AI techno-economic segment analysis. Selected Indicators. Seville: European Commission, Joint Research Centre. De Prato, G., Lopez Cobo, M., et al. (2018). The AI techno-economic segment analysis. Selected Indicators. Seville: European Commission, Joint Research Centre.
go back to reference Dieppe, A. (2020). Global productivity: trends, drivers and policies. Washington, DC: World Bank. Dieppe, A. (2020). Global productivity: trends, drivers and policies. Washington, DC: World Bank.
go back to reference Ertel, W. (2018). Introduction to artificial intelligence: Undergraduate topics in computer science. New-York: Springer International Publishing. Ertel, W. (2018). Introduction to artificial intelligence: Undergraduate topics in computer science. New-York: Springer International Publishing.
go back to reference European Commission (2003). Commission recommendation of 6 May 2003 concerning the definition of micro, small and medium-sized enterprises. Official Journal of European Union, L124/36. European Commission (2003). Commission recommendation of 6 May 2003 concerning the definition of micro, small and medium-sized enterprises. Official Journal of European Union, L124/36.
go back to reference Ernst, H. (1995). Patenting strategies in the German mechanical engineering industry and their relationship to firm performance. Technovation, 15(225), 240. Ernst, H. (1995). Patenting strategies in the German mechanical engineering industry and their relationship to firm performance. Technovation, 15(225), 240.
go back to reference Fors, G. (1997). Utilization of R&D results in the home and foreign plants of multinationals. Journal of Industrial Economics, 45(3), 341–358. Fors, G. (1997). Utilization of R&D results in the home and foreign plants of multinationals. Journal of Industrial Economics, 45(3), 341–358.
go back to reference Fujii, H., & Managi, S. (2018). Trends and priority shifts in artificial intelligence technology invention: A global patent analysis. Economic Analysis and Policy, 58, 60–69. Fujii, H., & Managi, S. (2018). Trends and priority shifts in artificial intelligence technology invention: A global patent analysis. Economic Analysis and Policy, 58, 60–69.
go back to reference Furman, J., & Seamans, R. (2019). AI and the economy. Innovation Policy and the Economy, 19, 161–191. Furman, J., & Seamans, R. (2019). AI and the economy. Innovation Policy and the Economy, 19, 161–191.
go back to reference Gambardella, A., Harhoff, D., & Verspagen, B. (2008). The value of European patents. European Management Review, 5(2), 69–84. Gambardella, A., Harhoff, D., & Verspagen, B. (2008). The value of European patents. European Management Review, 5(2), 69–84.
go back to reference Gordon, R. J. (2018). Why Has Economic Growth Slowed When Innovation Appears to be Accelerating? NBER Working Paper 24554. National Bureau for Economic Research. Gordon, R. J. (2018). Why Has Economic Growth Slowed When Innovation Appears to be Accelerating? NBER Working Paper 24554. National Bureau for Economic Research.
go back to reference Gordon, R. J. (2016). The rise and fall of American growth: The US standard of living since the Civil War. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Gordon, R. J. (2016). The rise and fall of American growth: The US standard of living since the Civil War. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Graetz, G., & Michaels, G. (2018). Robots at work. Review of Economic Statistics, 100(5), 753–768. Graetz, G., & Michaels, G. (2018). Robots at work. Review of Economic Statistics, 100(5), 753–768.
go back to reference Gries, T., & Naudié, W. (2018). Artificial intelligence, jobs, inequality and productivity: Does aggregate demand matter? IZA DP No. 12005, Bonn. Gries, T., & Naudié, W. (2018). Artificial intelligence, jobs, inequality and productivity: Does aggregate demand matter? IZA DP No. 12005, Bonn.
go back to reference Griliches, Z. (1990). Patent statistics as economic indicators: A survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 18, 1661–1707. Griliches, Z. (1990). Patent statistics as economic indicators: A survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 18, 1661–1707.
go back to reference Hall, B., Helmers, C., Rogers, M., & Sena, V. (2014). The choice between formal and informal intellectual property: A review. Journal of Economic Literature, 52(2), 375–423. Hall, B., Helmers, C., Rogers, M., & Sena, V. (2014). The choice between formal and informal intellectual property: A review. Journal of Economic Literature, 52(2), 375–423.
go back to reference Hall, B., Mairesse, J., & Mohnen, P. (2012). Measuring the returns to R&D. In B. Hall & N. Rosenberg (Eds.), Handbooks in economics: Economics of innovation, Vol. 2 (pp. 1033–1082). Amsterdam: North-Holland. Hall, B., Mairesse, J., & Mohnen, P. (2012). Measuring the returns to R&D. In B. Hall & N. Rosenberg (Eds.), Handbooks in economics: Economics of innovation, Vol. 2 (pp. 1033–1082). Amsterdam: North-Holland.
go back to reference Hall, B., Jaffe, A., & Trajtenberg, M. (2005). Market value and patent citations. RAND Journal of Economics, 36(1), 16–38. Hall, B., Jaffe, A., & Trajtenberg, M. (2005). Market value and patent citations. RAND Journal of Economics, 36(1), 16–38.
go back to reference Hall, B., & Mairesse, J. (1995). Exploring the relationship between R&D and productivity in French manufacturing firms. Journal of Econometrics, 65(1), 263–293. Hall, B., & Mairesse, J. (1995). Exploring the relationship between R&D and productivity in French manufacturing firms. Journal of Econometrics, 65(1), 263–293.
go back to reference Hallak, I. & Harasztosi, P. (2019). Job creation in Europe: A firm-level analysis, EUR 29689 EN, Publications Office of the European Union, Luxembourg, doi:10.2760/590043. Hallak, I. & Harasztosi, P. (2019). Job creation in Europe: A firm-level analysis, EUR 29689 EN, Publications Office of the European Union, Luxembourg, doi:10.2760/590043.
go back to reference Harhoff, D., Scherer, F. M., & Vopel, K. (2003). Citations, family size, opposition and the value of patent rights. Research Policy, 32(8), 1343–1363. Harhoff, D., Scherer, F. M., & Vopel, K. (2003). Citations, family size, opposition and the value of patent rights. Research Policy, 32(8), 1343–1363.
go back to reference Hatzichronoglou, T. (1997). Revision of the high-technology sector and product classification. OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers No. 1997/02. Hatzichronoglou, T. (1997). Revision of the high-technology sector and product classification. OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers No. 1997/02.
go back to reference Hussinger, K. (2006). Is silence golden? Patents versus secrecy at the firm level. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 15(8), 735–752. Hussinger, K. (2006). Is silence golden? Patents versus secrecy at the firm level. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 15(8), 735–752.
go back to reference Jones, B. F. (2009). The burden of knowledge and the ‘Death of the Renaissance Man’: Is innovation getting harder? Review of Economic Studies, 76(1), 283–317. Jones, B. F. (2009). The burden of knowledge and the ‘Death of the Renaissance Man’: Is innovation getting harder? Review of Economic Studies, 76(1), 283–317.
go back to reference Josten, C., & Lordan, G. (2020). Robots at work: Automatable and non-automatable jobs. In K. Zimmermann (Ed.), Handbook of labor, human resources and population economics. Cham: Springer. Josten, C., & Lordan, G. (2020). Robots at work: Automatable and non-automatable jobs. In K. Zimmermann (Ed.), Handbook of labor, human resources and population economics. Cham: Springer.
go back to reference Keisner, A., Raffo, J., & Wunsch-Vincent, S. (2015). Breakthrough technologies—Robotics, innovation and intellectual property. WIPO Economic Research Working Paper No. 30. Keisner, A., Raffo, J., & Wunsch-Vincent, S. (2015). Breakthrough technologies—Robotics, innovation and intellectual property. WIPO Economic Research Working Paper No. 30.
go back to reference Klette, T. (1996). R&D, scope economies and plant performance. RAND Journal of Economics, 27, 502–522. Klette, T. (1996). R&D, scope economies and plant performance. RAND Journal of Economics, 27, 502–522.
go back to reference Klette, T., & Johansen, F. (1998). Accumulation of R&D capital and dynamic firm performance: A not-so-fixed effect model. Annales d’Économie et de Statistique, 49(50), 389–419. Klette, T., & Johansen, F. (1998). Accumulation of R&D capital and dynamic firm performance: A not-so-fixed effect model. Annales d’Économie et de Statistique, 49(50), 389–419.
go back to reference Lokshin, B., Belderbos, R., & Carree, M. (2008). The productivity effects of internal and external R&D: Evidence from a dynamic panel data model. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 70(3), 399–413. Lokshin, B., Belderbos, R., & Carree, M. (2008). The productivity effects of internal and external R&D: Evidence from a dynamic panel data model. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 70(3), 399–413.
go back to reference Makridakis, S. (2017). The forthcoming artificial intelligence (AI) revolution: Its impact on society and firms. Futures, 90, 46–60. Makridakis, S. (2017). The forthcoming artificial intelligence (AI) revolution: Its impact on society and firms. Futures, 90, 46–60.
go back to reference Neuhäusler, P., Frietsch, R., Schubert, T., & Blind, K. (2011). Patents and the financial performance of firms-An analysis based on stock market data (No. 28). Fraunhofer ISI Discussion Papers-Innovation Systems and Policy Analysis. Neuhäusler, P., Frietsch, R., Schubert, T., & Blind, K. (2011). Patents and the financial performance of firms-An analysis based on stock market data (No. 28). Fraunhofer ISI Discussion Papers-Innovation Systems and Policy Analysis.
go back to reference Ortega-Argilés, R., Piva, M., & Vivarelli, M. (2015). The productivity impact of R&D investment: Are high-tech sectors still ahead? Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 24(3), 204–222. Ortega-Argilés, R., Piva, M., & Vivarelli, M. (2015). The productivity impact of R&D investment: Are high-tech sectors still ahead? Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 24(3), 204–222.
go back to reference Piva, M., & Vivarelli, M. (2005). Innovation and employment: Evidence from Italian microdata. Journal of Economics, 86(1), 65–83. Piva, M., & Vivarelli, M. (2005). Innovation and employment: Evidence from Italian microdata. Journal of Economics, 86(1), 65–83.
go back to reference Piva, M., & Vivarelli, M. (2018). Is Innovation destroying jobs? Firm-level evidence from the EU. Sustainability, 10(4), 1279. Piva, M., & Vivarelli, M. (2018). Is Innovation destroying jobs? Firm-level evidence from the EU. Sustainability, 10(4), 1279.
go back to reference Raj, M., & Seamans, R. (2019). AI, labor, productivity and the need for firm-level data. In A. Agrawal, J. Gans, & A. Goldfarb (Eds.), The economics of artificial intelligence: an agenda. Chicago: University of Chicago Press and NBER. Raj, M., & Seamans, R. (2019). AI, labor, productivity and the need for firm-level data. In A. Agrawal, J. Gans, & A. Goldfarb (Eds.), The economics of artificial intelligence: an agenda. Chicago: University of Chicago Press and NBER.
go back to reference Romer, P. M. (1990). Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), S71–102. Romer, P. M. (1990). Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), S71–102.
go back to reference Roodman, D. (2009a). How to do xtabond2: An introduction to "Difference" and "System" GMM in Stata. Stata Journal, 9, 86–136. Roodman, D. (2009a). How to do xtabond2: An introduction to "Difference" and "System" GMM in Stata. Stata Journal, 9, 86–136.
go back to reference Roodman, D. (2009b). A note on the theme of too many instruments. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 71, 135–158. Roodman, D. (2009b). A note on the theme of too many instruments. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 71, 135–158.
go back to reference Russell, S., & Norvig, P. (2016). Artificial intelligence: A modern approach. Malaysia: Pearson Education Limited. Russell, S., & Norvig, P. (2016). Artificial intelligence: A modern approach. Malaysia: Pearson Education Limited.
go back to reference Solow, R. M. (1957). Technical change and the aggregate production function. Review of Economics and Statistics, 39(3), 312–320. Solow, R. M. (1957). Technical change and the aggregate production function. Review of Economics and Statistics, 39(3), 312–320.
go back to reference Solow, R. (1987). We'd better watch out, New York Times Book Review, July 12, p. 36. Solow, R. (1987). We'd better watch out, New York Times Book Review, July 12, p. 36.
go back to reference Squicciarini, M., Dernis, H., & Criscuolo, C. (2013). Measuring patent quality. OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers 2013/03. Squicciarini, M., Dernis, H., & Criscuolo, C. (2013). Measuring patent quality. OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers 2013/03.
go back to reference Van Roy, V., Vertesy, D., & Damioli, G. (2020). AI and robotics innovation. In K. Zimmermann (Ed.) Handbook of labor, human resources and population economics. Cham: Springer. Van Roy, V., Vertesy, D., & Damioli, G. (2020). AI and robotics innovation. In K. Zimmermann (Ed.) Handbook of labor, human resources and population economics. Cham: Springer.
go back to reference Van Roy, V., Vértesy, D., & Vivarelli, M. (2018). Technology and employment: Mass unemployment or job creation? Empirical evidence from European patenting firms. Research Policy, 47(9), 1762–1776. Van Roy, V., Vértesy, D., & Vivarelli, M. (2018). Technology and employment: Mass unemployment or job creation? Empirical evidence from European patenting firms. Research Policy, 47(9), 1762–1776.
go back to reference Vivarelli, M. (1995). The economics of technology and employment: Theory and empirical evidence. Aldershot: Edward Elgar. Vivarelli, M. (1995). The economics of technology and employment: Theory and empirical evidence. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.
go back to reference Vivarelli, M. (2013). Technology, employment and skills: An interpretative framework. Eurasian Business Review, 3(1), 66–89. Vivarelli, M. (2013). Technology, employment and skills: An interpretative framework. Eurasian Business Review, 3(1), 66–89.
go back to reference WIPO. (2019). WIPO Technology Trends 2019: Artificial Intelligence. Geneva: World Intellectual Property Organization. WIPO. (2019). WIPO Technology Trends 2019: Artificial Intelligence. Geneva: World Intellectual Property Organization.
Metadata
Title
The impact of artificial intelligence on labor productivity
Authors
Giacomo Damioli
Vincent Van Roy
Daniel Vertesy
Publication date
21-01-2021
Publisher
Springer International Publishing
Published in
Eurasian Business Review / Issue 1/2021
Print ISSN: 1309-4297
Electronic ISSN: 2147-4281
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s40821-020-00172-8

Other articles of this Issue 1/2021

Eurasian Business Review 1/2021 Go to the issue