Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Theory and Decision 2/2014

01-02-2014

Use of data on planned contributions and stated beliefs in the measurement of social preferences

Authors: Anna Conte, M. Vittoria Levati

Published in: Theory and Decision | Issue 2/2014

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

In a series of one-shot linear public goods game, we ask subjects to report their contributions, their contribution plans for the next period, and their first-order beliefs about their present and future partner. We estimate subjects’ preferences from plan data by a finite mixture approach and compare the results with those obtained from contribution data. Controlling for beliefs, which incorporate the information about the others’ decisions, we are able to show that plans convey accurate information about subjects’ preferences and, consequently, are good predictors of their future behavior.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
Survey questions are consequential if the “survey’s results are seen as potentially influencing an agency’s actions and the agent cares about the outcomes of those actions” (Carson and Groves 2007, p. 183).
 
2
We chose this protocol to minimize strategic effects from repeated play and to allow for revisions to beliefs only at the population level.
 
3
To simplify notation, we always refer to player \(i\)’s partner as \(j\), although this is a different person in each period.
 
4
A similar procedure for incentivizing subjects to state a carefully considered, truthful plan has been applied by Barkan and Busemeyer (1999).
 
5
When convenient, we will equivalently use the notation \(p_{\cdot ,t}^{t+1},\, t = 1, \ldots , 14\), to indicate contribution plans made in \(t\) for \(t+1\).
 
6
The instructions make clear that subjects have to predict the decisions of two different persons: the current-period partner (\(\mathbf{b}_{i,t}^{t}\)) and the next-period partner (\(\mathbf{b}_{i,t}^{t+1}\)).
 
7
To simplify presentation, players’ contributions in treatment \(C\) will be sometimes referred to as “final” even though no distinction between final and planned contributions is made in \(C\).
 
8
See Selten (1998) for an axiomatic characterization of the rule, and Offerman et al. (2009) for an experiment investigating its behavioral properties.
 
9
A similar rule has been used by, e.g., Offerman et al. (1996), Costa-Gomes and Weizsäcker (2008), and Rey-Biel (2009), although there exists no consensus among experimentalists about the optimal incentive mechanism for eliciting beliefs. Huck and Weizsäcker (2002) compare beliefs elicited via a quadratic scoring rule with beliefs elicited via a Becker-DeGroot-Marshak pricing rule, and find that the quadratic scoring rule yields more accurate beliefs.
 
10
The instructions are available from the authors upon request.
 
11
Because of our re-matching protocol, the numbers of statistically independent observations are 6 in \(C\), 5 in \(P_\mathrm{I}\), and 5 in \(P_{\mathrm{{NI}}}\).
 
12
In particular, the one-period-ahead and final expected contributions are computed, respectively, as
$$\begin{aligned} E_{i,t-1}[c_{j,t}] = \frac{\sum \nolimits _{a=0}^{10} \left( a\times 10\right) \times b_{i,t-1}^{t}\left( a\right) }{100} \qquad \text{ and } \qquad E_{i,t}[c_{j,t}] = \frac{\sum _{a=0}^{10} \left( a\times 10\right) \times b_{i,t}^{t}\left( a\right) }{100}. \end{aligned}$$
 
13
To characterize the behavior of conditional cooperators, we could have used either a utility function à la Fehr and Smith (1999) or a different rule for \(Y_{j,t}\) like, e.g., the final (one-period-ahead) expected contribution. We opted for our simple rule for three reasons: (a) finding the functional form that fits the data best is not one of the objectives of this article; (b) we wanted for the conditional cooperator type a behavioral rule as straightforward as the one used for the other two types; (c) finally, but most importantly, our data analysis suggests that about 50 % of the contributions, both final and planned, comply with such a rule.
 
14
Nevertheless, identification fails to achieve in the following cases: when one of the modes of \(i\)’s distribution of beliefs always corresponds to \(a = 0\) and \(i\) always chooses to contribute 0 (in this case, a conditional cooperator is indistinguishable from a selfish subject); when one of the modes of \(i\)’s distribution of beliefs always corresponds to the median of \(i\)’s contributions and \(i\) always chooses to contribute exactly that amount (in that case, a conditional cooperator is indistinguishable from an altruist); when subjects change preferences over time.
 
15
See Moffatt and Peters (2001) and Loomes (2005).
 
16
To the best of our knowledge, this is the first time a tremble is estimated under such assumptions. We want the tremble probability to be individual-specific because this allows us to capture different kinds of behavior. There can be subjects who stick with their rule in all periods, subjects whose decisions are noisy at the beginning but not toward the end, and vice versa. Finally, there can be subjects whose decisions are extremely noisy throughout the entire game.
 
17
Details can be found in Train (2003).
 
18
In unreported analysis, we estimate the four models in Table 1 without time effects (i.e., constraining \(b_{1}\) and \(g_{1}\) to equal zero). Likelihood-ratio tests strongly reject the null hypothesis of no time effects (in all cases the \(p\)-values of the tests are \(<\)0.000). The regression results of these models are available from the authors upon request. We do not report the results here for two reasons: none of the conclusions concerning the main hypothesis under investigation changes when time effects are added to the mixture model; the models with time effects showed to be far superior on statistical grounds.
 
19
For this reason, we exclude six subjects from treatment \(P_{\mathrm{{NI}}}\).
 
20
Similar inconsistencies, referred to as “instabilities of preferences,” are found and discussed in Wilcox (2007) and Conte and Hey (2013).
 
Literature
go back to reference Ambrus, A., & Pathak, P. A. (2011). Cooperation over finite horizons: A theory and experiments. Journal of Public Economics, 95(7,8), 500–512.CrossRef Ambrus, A., & Pathak, P. A. (2011). Cooperation over finite horizons: A theory and experiments. Journal of Public Economics, 95(7,8), 500–512.CrossRef
go back to reference Anderson, S. P., Goeree, J. K., & Holt, C. A. (1998). A theoretical analysis of altruism and decision error in public goods games. Journal of Public Economics, 70(2), 297–323.CrossRef Anderson, S. P., Goeree, J. K., & Holt, C. A. (1998). A theoretical analysis of altruism and decision error in public goods games. Journal of Public Economics, 70(2), 297–323.CrossRef
go back to reference Andreoni, J. (1995). Cooperation in public-goods experiments: Kindness or confusion. American Economic Review, 85(4), 891–904. Andreoni, J. (1995). Cooperation in public-goods experiments: Kindness or confusion. American Economic Review, 85(4), 891–904.
go back to reference Andreoni, J., & Miller, J. (2002). Giving according to GARP: An experimental test of the consistency of preferences for altruism. Econometrica, 70(2), 737–753.CrossRef Andreoni, J., & Miller, J. (2002). Giving according to GARP: An experimental test of the consistency of preferences for altruism. Econometrica, 70(2), 737–753.CrossRef
go back to reference Bardsley, N., & Moffatt, P. G. (2007). The experimetrics of public goods: Inferring motivations from contributions. Theory and Decision, 62(2), 161–193.CrossRef Bardsley, N., & Moffatt, P. G. (2007). The experimetrics of public goods: Inferring motivations from contributions. Theory and Decision, 62(2), 161–193.CrossRef
go back to reference Barkan, R., & Busemeyer, J. R. (1999). Changing plans: Dynamic inconsistency and the effect of experience on the reference point. Psychonomic Bulletin & Review, 6(4), 547–554.CrossRef Barkan, R., & Busemeyer, J. R. (1999). Changing plans: Dynamic inconsistency and the effect of experience on the reference point. Psychonomic Bulletin & Review, 6(4), 547–554.CrossRef
go back to reference Bolton, G., & Ockenfels, A. (2000). ERC: A theory of equity, reciprocity and competition. American Economic Review, 90(1), 166–193.CrossRef Bolton, G., & Ockenfels, A. (2000). ERC: A theory of equity, reciprocity and competition. American Economic Review, 90(1), 166–193.CrossRef
go back to reference Bone, J. D., Hey, J. D., & Suckling, J. R. (2003). Do people plan ahead? Applied Economics Letters, 10(5), 277–280.CrossRef Bone, J. D., Hey, J. D., & Suckling, J. R. (2003). Do people plan ahead? Applied Economics Letters, 10(5), 277–280.CrossRef
go back to reference Bone, J. D., Hey, J. D., & Suckling, J. R. (2009). Do people plan? Experimental Economics, 12(1), 12–25.CrossRef Bone, J. D., Hey, J. D., & Suckling, J. R. (2009). Do people plan? Experimental Economics, 12(1), 12–25.CrossRef
go back to reference Carson, R. T., & Groves, T. (2007). Incentive and informational properties of preference questions. Environmental and Resource Economics, 37(1), 181–210.CrossRef Carson, R. T., & Groves, T. (2007). Incentive and informational properties of preference questions. Environmental and Resource Economics, 37(1), 181–210.CrossRef
go back to reference Charness, G., & Rabin, M. (2002). Understanding social preferences with simple tests. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(3), 817–869.CrossRef Charness, G., & Rabin, M. (2002). Understanding social preferences with simple tests. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(3), 817–869.CrossRef
go back to reference Costa-Gomes, M. A., & Crawford, V. P. (2006). Cognition and behavior in two-person guessing games: An experimental study. American Economic Review, 96(5), 1737–1768.CrossRef Costa-Gomes, M. A., & Crawford, V. P. (2006). Cognition and behavior in two-person guessing games: An experimental study. American Economic Review, 96(5), 1737–1768.CrossRef
go back to reference Costa-Gomes, M. A., & Weizsäcker, G. (2008). Stated beliefs and play in normal-form games. Review of Economic Studies, 75(3), 729–762.CrossRef Costa-Gomes, M. A., & Weizsäcker, G. (2008). Stated beliefs and play in normal-form games. Review of Economic Studies, 75(3), 729–762.CrossRef
go back to reference Cox, J. C., Friedman, D., & Gjerstad, S. (2007). A tractable model of reciprocity and fairness. Games and Economic Behavior, 59(1), 17–45.CrossRef Cox, J. C., Friedman, D., & Gjerstad, S. (2007). A tractable model of reciprocity and fairness. Games and Economic Behavior, 59(1), 17–45.CrossRef
go back to reference Croson, R. (2000). Thinking like a game theorist: Factors affecting the frequency of equilibrium play. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 41(3), 299–314.CrossRef Croson, R. (2000). Thinking like a game theorist: Factors affecting the frequency of equilibrium play. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 41(3), 299–314.CrossRef
go back to reference Croson, R. (2007). Theories of commitment, altruism and reciprocity: Evidence from linear public goods games. Economic Inquiry, 45(2), 199–216.CrossRef Croson, R. (2007). Theories of commitment, altruism and reciprocity: Evidence from linear public goods games. Economic Inquiry, 45(2), 199–216.CrossRef
go back to reference Echessah, P. N., Swallow, B. M., Kamara, D. W., & Curry, J. J. (1997). Willingness to contribute labor and money to tsetse control: Application of contingent valuation in Busia District, Kenya. World Development, 25(2), 239–253.CrossRef Echessah, P. N., Swallow, B. M., Kamara, D. W., & Curry, J. J. (1997). Willingness to contribute labor and money to tsetse control: Application of contingent valuation in Busia District, Kenya. World Development, 25(2), 239–253.CrossRef
go back to reference Edmunds, A., & Morris, A. (2000). The problem of information overload in business organisations: A review of the literature. International Journal of Information Management, 20(1), 17–28.CrossRef Edmunds, A., & Morris, A. (2000). The problem of information overload in business organisations: A review of the literature. International Journal of Information Management, 20(1), 17–28.CrossRef
go back to reference Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 817–868.CrossRef Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 817–868.CrossRef
go back to reference Fischbacher, U. (2007). Zurich toolbox for readymade economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171–178.CrossRef Fischbacher, U. (2007). Zurich toolbox for readymade economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171–178.CrossRef
go back to reference Fischbacher, U., & Gächter, S. (2010). Social preferences, beliefs, and the dynamics of free riding in public good experiments. American Economic Review, 100(1), 541–556.CrossRef Fischbacher, U., & Gächter, S. (2010). Social preferences, beliefs, and the dynamics of free riding in public good experiments. American Economic Review, 100(1), 541–556.CrossRef
go back to reference Fischbacher, U., Gächter, S., & Fehr, E. (2001). Are people conditionally cooperative? Evidence from a public goods experiment. Economics Letters, 71(3), 397–404.CrossRef Fischbacher, U., Gächter, S., & Fehr, E. (2001). Are people conditionally cooperative? Evidence from a public goods experiment. Economics Letters, 71(3), 397–404.CrossRef
go back to reference Gabaix, X., Laibson, D., Moloche, G., & Weinberg, S. (2006). Costly information acquisition: Experimental analysis if a boundedly rational model. American Economic Review, 96(4), 1043–1068.CrossRef Gabaix, X., Laibson, D., Moloche, G., & Weinberg, S. (2006). Costly information acquisition: Experimental analysis if a boundedly rational model. American Economic Review, 96(4), 1043–1068.CrossRef
go back to reference Gächter, S., & Renner, E. (2010). The effects of (incentivized) belief elicitation in public good experiments. Experimental Economics, 13(3), 364–377.CrossRef Gächter, S., & Renner, E. (2010). The effects of (incentivized) belief elicitation in public good experiments. Experimental Economics, 13(3), 364–377.CrossRef
go back to reference Greiner, B. (2004). An online recruitment system for economic experiments. In K. Kremer & V. Macho (Eds.), Forschung und wissenschaftliches Rechnen 2003 (pp. 79–93). Göttingen: GWDG Bericht 63, Ges. für Wiss. Datenverarbeitung. Greiner, B. (2004). An online recruitment system for economic experiments. In K. Kremer & V. Macho (Eds.), Forschung und wissenschaftliches Rechnen 2003 (pp. 79–93). Göttingen: GWDG Bericht 63, Ges. für Wiss. Datenverarbeitung.
go back to reference Guimarães, P., & Lindrooth, R. C. (2007). Controlling for overdispersion in grouped conditional logit models: A computationally simple application of Dirichlet multinomial regression. Econometrics Journal, 10(2), 439–452.CrossRef Guimarães, P., & Lindrooth, R. C. (2007). Controlling for overdispersion in grouped conditional logit models: A computationally simple application of Dirichlet multinomial regression. Econometrics Journal, 10(2), 439–452.CrossRef
go back to reference Hausman, J., Hall, B. H., & Griliches, Z. (1984). Economic models for count data with an application to the patents-R &D relationship. Econometrica, 52(4), 909–938.CrossRef Hausman, J., Hall, B. H., & Griliches, Z. (1984). Economic models for count data with an application to the patents-R &D relationship. Econometrica, 52(4), 909–938.CrossRef
go back to reference Hey, J. D. (2005). Do people (want to) plan? Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 52(1), 122–138.CrossRef Hey, J. D. (2005). Do people (want to) plan? Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 52(1), 122–138.CrossRef
go back to reference Houser, D., & Kurzban, R. (2002). Revisiting kindness and confusion in public goods experiments. American Economic Review, 92(4), 1062–1069.CrossRef Houser, D., & Kurzban, R. (2002). Revisiting kindness and confusion in public goods experiments. American Economic Review, 92(4), 1062–1069.CrossRef
go back to reference Huck, S., & Weizsäcker, G. (2002). Do players correctly estimate what others do? Evidence of conservatism in beliefs. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 47(1), 71–85.CrossRef Huck, S., & Weizsäcker, G. (2002). Do players correctly estimate what others do? Evidence of conservatism in beliefs. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 47(1), 71–85.CrossRef
go back to reference Kamuanga, M., Swallow, B. M., Sigué, H., & Bauer, B. (2001). Evaluating contingent and actual contributions to a local public good: Tsetse control in the Yale agro-pastoral zone, Burkina Faso. Ecological Economics, 39, 115–130.CrossRef Kamuanga, M., Swallow, B. M., Sigué, H., & Bauer, B. (2001). Evaluating contingent and actual contributions to a local public good: Tsetse control in the Yale agro-pastoral zone, Burkina Faso. Ecological Economics, 39, 115–130.CrossRef
go back to reference Levine, D. K. (1998). Modeling altruism and spitefulness in experiments. Review of Economic Dynamics, 1(3), 593–622.CrossRef Levine, D. K. (1998). Modeling altruism and spitefulness in experiments. Review of Economic Dynamics, 1(3), 593–622.CrossRef
go back to reference Loomes, G. (2005). Modelling the stochastic component of behaviour in experiments: Some issues for the interpretation of data. Experimental Economics, 8(4), 301–323.CrossRef Loomes, G. (2005). Modelling the stochastic component of behaviour in experiments: Some issues for the interpretation of data. Experimental Economics, 8(4), 301–323.CrossRef
go back to reference Manski, C. F. (1990). The use of intentions data to predict behavior: A best-case analysis. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 85(412), 934–940.CrossRef Manski, C. F. (1990). The use of intentions data to predict behavior: A best-case analysis. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 85(412), 934–940.CrossRef
go back to reference Moffatt, P. G., & Peters, S. A. (2001). Testing for the presence of a tremble in economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 4(3), 221–228. Moffatt, P. G., & Peters, S. A. (2001). Testing for the presence of a tremble in economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 4(3), 221–228.
go back to reference Morwitz, V. G. (1997). Why consumers don’t always accurately predict their own future behavior. Marketing Letters, 8(1), 57–70.CrossRef Morwitz, V. G. (1997). Why consumers don’t always accurately predict their own future behavior. Marketing Letters, 8(1), 57–70.CrossRef
go back to reference Offerman, T., Sonnemans, J., & Schram, A. (1996). Value orientations, expectations, and voluntary contributions in public goods. Economic Journal, 106(437), 817–845.CrossRef Offerman, T., Sonnemans, J., & Schram, A. (1996). Value orientations, expectations, and voluntary contributions in public goods. Economic Journal, 106(437), 817–845.CrossRef
go back to reference Offerman, T., Sonnemans, J., Van de Kuilen, G., & Wakker, P. P. (2009). A truth serum for non-Bayesians: Correcting proper scoring rules for risk attitudes. Review of Economic Studies, 76(4), 1461–1489.CrossRef Offerman, T., Sonnemans, J., Van de Kuilen, G., & Wakker, P. P. (2009). A truth serum for non-Bayesians: Correcting proper scoring rules for risk attitudes. Review of Economic Studies, 76(4), 1461–1489.CrossRef
go back to reference Palfrey, T. R., & Prisbrey, J. E. (1996). Altruism, reputation and noise in linear public goods experiments. Journal of Public Economics, 61(3), 409–427.CrossRef Palfrey, T. R., & Prisbrey, J. E. (1996). Altruism, reputation and noise in linear public goods experiments. Journal of Public Economics, 61(3), 409–427.CrossRef
go back to reference Palfrey, T. R., & Prisbrey, J. E. (1997). Anomalous behavior in public goods experiments: How much and why? American Economic Review, 87(5), 829–846. Palfrey, T. R., & Prisbrey, J. E. (1997). Anomalous behavior in public goods experiments: How much and why? American Economic Review, 87(5), 829–846.
go back to reference Rey-Biel, P. (2009). Equilibrium play and best response to (stated) beliefs in normal form games. Games and Economic Behavior, 65(2), 572–585.CrossRef Rey-Biel, P. (2009). Equilibrium play and best response to (stated) beliefs in normal form games. Games and Economic Behavior, 65(2), 572–585.CrossRef
go back to reference Schnake, M. E. (1991). Equity in effort: The “sucker effect” in co-acting groups. Journal of Management, 17(1), 41–55.CrossRef Schnake, M. E. (1991). Equity in effort: The “sucker effect” in co-acting groups. Journal of Management, 17(1), 41–55.CrossRef
go back to reference Selten, R. (1998). Axiomatic characterization of the quadratic scoring rule. Experimental Economics, 1(1), 43–62. Selten, R. (1998). Axiomatic characterization of the quadratic scoring rule. Experimental Economics, 1(1), 43–62.
go back to reference Train, K. (2003). Discrete choice methods with simulation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Train, K. (2003). Discrete choice methods with simulation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Wilcox, N. T. (2007). Predicting risky choices out of context: A Monte Carlo study. University of Houston Working Paper. Wilcox, N. T. (2007). Predicting risky choices out of context: A Monte Carlo study. University of Houston Working Paper.
go back to reference Wilcox, N. T., & Feltovich, N. (2000). Thinking like a game theorist: Comment. University of Houston Department of Economics Working Paper. Wilcox, N. T., & Feltovich, N. (2000). Thinking like a game theorist: Comment. University of Houston Department of Economics Working Paper.
Metadata
Title
Use of data on planned contributions and stated beliefs in the measurement of social preferences
Authors
Anna Conte
M. Vittoria Levati
Publication date
01-02-2014
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Theory and Decision / Issue 2/2014
Print ISSN: 0040-5833
Electronic ISSN: 1573-7187
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-013-9365-4

Other articles of this Issue 2/2014

Theory and Decision 2/2014 Go to the issue

OriginalPaper

Stronger utility