Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Quality & Quantity 2/2020

16-05-2019

When do institutions suddenly collapse? Zones of knowledge and the likelihood of political cascades

Authors: Ian S. Lustick, Dan Miodownik

Published in: Quality & Quantity | Issue 2/2020

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

In this paper institutions are treated as stabilized sets of expectations, an approach that encourages investigation of how cultural formations, political regimes, global financial arrangements, and other institutions can be both reliable and yet also subject to sudden and sometimes catastrophic transformations. We examine conditions that make political cascades, or tipping, more or less likely. We report findings from computer-assisted agent-based modelling experiments designed to test Timur Kuran’s preference falsification model for explaining the possibility, but rare occurrence of, revolutionary political cascades. Since it run on a computer, our operationalized model of Kuran’s theory is a necessarily precise and elaborated refinement of the incompletely specified version presented by Kuran. Our purpose is to go beyond his explanation for why political cascades can occur, albeit rarely, to explore the conditions that make them more or less likely. Our specific focus is on the impact of the amount of knowledge about the state of the entire system possessed by citizens with stronger or weaker inclinations to publicly express their anti-regime sentiments. The “zone of knowledge” of individuals is an unexamined variable whose importance is unrecognized but implied by Kuran’s analysis. We find that with some reasonable but crucial refinements Kuran’s preference falsification theory works to explain the pattern observed in the political world of rare but sweeping cascades of; that the amount of knowledge individuals have about the behavior of the population is crucial to shaping the probability of a cascade; and that variation in the myopia of “early followers” is considerably more important for determining the likelihood and comprehensiveness of sudden political transformations than the influence of first movers or the contribution of other plausible factors.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Footnotes
1
Gramsci (1957, pp. 60–67, 103–104, and 141, 1971, pp. 97–100 and 104–114).
 
2
Max Weber’s classic definition of the state is derived from his more fundamental point that no institution can exist “in a sociologically relevant sense” apart from “a probability that certain kinds of meaningfully oriented social action will take place” (Weber 1922, p. 38). This conception of institutions has become standard in political science (e.g. North 1981, pp. 17–21). On the concept of “emergent properties” (Holland 1998).
 
3
Wejnert (2002) and Dobbin et al. (2007) draw heavily on Rogers's work and show the field still organized by an accumulation of data about how very specific factors associated with new products or populations can affect the likelihood, rapidity, and completeness of diffusion. However, this vast literature has had little impact on social scientists, in part because it has not coped effectively with the “curse of dimensionality” (Achen 2002) (see also De Marchi 2005, p. 35). That is, the interactive implications of dozens of separate variables have been identified, but without a theoretical or methodological approach for testing their potency or for moving beyond description and post hoc analyses toward probability prediction or systematic explanation of patterns of diffusion outcomes.
 
4
A similar pattern—omission of the zones of knowledge problem from formal models but informal if implicit acknowledgement of this factor’s importance—is apparent in Laitin (1998) and Lohmann (1994).
 
5
For excellent examples of this general approach and its limits for understanding the specific impact of variability of individual zones of knowledge for cascading outcomes see Ellison (1993), Ellison and Fudenberg (1995), Young (1999). See also Axtell (2003), Miller and Page (2004).
 
6
Lustick and Miodownik (2004).
 
7
Lustick (2002). The software is available at http://​ps-i.​sourceforge.​net/​.
 
8
Concerning the problem of titrating complexity in agent-based models see Lustick and Miodownik (2009).
 
9
See Grimm et al. (2006).
 
10
Experiments have not yet been run with landscapes with closed edges, but the more general question raised by the shape of the landscape is explored by the “density” variable, which changes the topology of the toroidal landscape with variable amounts of isolation between scattered groups.
 
11
For technical reasons we used nine agent classes in our model rather than ten. This is an irrelevant difference.
 
12
Replication of our experiments can be accomplished by downloading the PS-I modeling platform at SourceForge, Version 4.0.5 at http://​ps-i.​sourceforge.​net/​. A manual to guide use of the platform is available at http://​www.​polisci.​upenn.​edu/​ps-i/​publications/​PSIManual.​pdf. Scripts (*.scp) and model platform file (*.mdl) as well as replication files of the statistical analysis are available here: https://​bit.​ly/​2TUm2UL.
 
13
We also ran models with a threshold of 90% (N = 136) but these were substantially the same as a threshold of 80% hence these are not reported here.
 
Literature
go back to reference Axelrod, R.: Promoting norms: an evolutionary approach to norms. In: Axelrod, R. (ed.) The Complexity of Cooperation, pp. 40–68. Princeton University Press, Princeton (1997b) Axelrod, R.: Promoting norms: an evolutionary approach to norms. In: Axelrod, R. (ed.) The Complexity of Cooperation, pp. 40–68. Princeton University Press, Princeton (1997b)
go back to reference Axtell, R.L.: Economics as distributed computation. In: Terano, T., Deguchi, H., Takadama, K. (eds.) Meeting the Challenge of Social Problems via Agent-Based Simulation, pp. 3–25. Springer, Tokyo (2003)CrossRef Axtell, R.L.: Economics as distributed computation. In: Terano, T., Deguchi, H., Takadama, K. (eds.) Meeting the Challenge of Social Problems via Agent-Based Simulation, pp. 3–25. Springer, Tokyo (2003)CrossRef
go back to reference De Marchi, S.: Computational and Mathematical Modeling in the Social Sciences. Cambridge University Press, New York (2005)CrossRef De Marchi, S.: Computational and Mathematical Modeling in the Social Sciences. Cambridge University Press, New York (2005)CrossRef
go back to reference De, S., Nau, D.S., Pan, X., Gelfand, M.J.: Tipping points for norm change in human cultures. In: Thomson, R., Dancy, C., Hyder, A., Bisgin, H. (eds.) Social, Cultural, and Behavioral Modeling. SBP-BRiMS 2018. Lecture Notes in Computer Science, vol. 10899. Springer, Cham (2018) De, S., Nau, D.S., Pan, X., Gelfand, M.J.: Tipping points for norm change in human cultures. In: Thomson, R., Dancy, C., Hyder, A., Bisgin, H. (eds.) Social, Cultural, and Behavioral Modeling. SBP-BRiMS 2018. Lecture Notes in Computer Science, vol. 10899. Springer, Cham (2018)
go back to reference Ellison, G.: Learning, local interaction, and coordination. Econometrica 61, 1047–1071 (1993)CrossRef Ellison, G.: Learning, local interaction, and coordination. Econometrica 61, 1047–1071 (1993)CrossRef
go back to reference Gramsci, A.: The study of philosophy and of historical materialism; Critical notes on an attempt at a popular presentation of marxism by Bukharin; The modern prince. In: Marks, L. (ed.) The Modern Prince and Other Writings, pp. 60–67, 103–104, and 141. International Publishers, New York (1957) Gramsci, A.: The study of philosophy and of historical materialism; Critical notes on an attempt at a popular presentation of marxism by Bukharin; The modern prince. In: Marks, L. (ed.) The Modern Prince and Other Writings, pp. 60–67, 103–104, and 141. International Publishers, New York (1957)
go back to reference Gramsci, A.: Notes on Italian history. In: Hoare, Q., Nowell-Smith, G. (eds.) Selections from the Prison Notebooks, pp. 97–100 and 104–114. International Publishers, New York (1971) Gramsci, A.: Notes on Italian history. In: Hoare, Q., Nowell-Smith, G. (eds.) Selections from the Prison Notebooks, pp. 97–100 and 104–114. International Publishers, New York (1971)
go back to reference Holland, J.H.: Emergence: From Chaos To Order. Basic Books, New York (1998) Holland, J.H.: Emergence: From Chaos To Order. Basic Books, New York (1998)
go back to reference Kuran, T.: Private truths, public lies: the social consequences of preference falsification. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA (1995) Kuran, T.: Private truths, public lies: the social consequences of preference falsification. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA (1995)
go back to reference Laitin, D.D.: Identities in formation. Cornell University Press, Ithaca, NY (1998) Laitin, D.D.: Identities in formation. Cornell University Press, Ithaca, NY (1998)
go back to reference Latané, B., Nowak, A.: Self-organizing social systems: necessary and sufficient conditions for the emergence of clustering, consolidation and continuing diversity. In: Barnett, G.A., Boster, F.J. (eds.) Progress in Communication Sciences, Volume 13: Persuasion, pp. 43–74. Albex, Norwood, NJ (1997) Latané, B., Nowak, A.: Self-organizing social systems: necessary and sufficient conditions for the emergence of clustering, consolidation and continuing diversity. In: Barnett, G.A., Boster, F.J. (eds.) Progress in Communication Sciences, Volume 13: Persuasion, pp. 43–74. Albex, Norwood, NJ (1997)
go back to reference Lohmann, S.: I know you know she knows we know you know they know: common knowledge and the unpredictability of informational cascades. In: Richards, D. (ed.) Political Complexity: Nonlinear Models of Politics, pp. 137–173. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor (2002) Lohmann, S.: I know you know she knows we know you know they know: common knowledge and the unpredictability of informational cascades. In: Richards, D. (ed.) Political Complexity: Nonlinear Models of Politics, pp. 137–173. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor (2002)
go back to reference Lustick, I.S.: Unsettled states, disputed lands: Britain and Ireland, France and Algeria, Israel and the West Bank-Gaza. Cornell University Press, Ithaca, NY (1993) Lustick, I.S.: Unsettled states, disputed lands: Britain and Ireland, France and Algeria, Israel and the West Bank-Gaza. Cornell University Press, Ithaca, NY (1993)
go back to reference Lustick, I.S., Miodownik, D.: Everyone I know is doing it: tipping, political cascades, and individual zones of knowledge. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Chicago, IL, September 1–5 (2004). http://www.polisci.upenn.edu/ps-i/papers.htm. Accessed 2 Sep 2004 Lustick, I.S., Miodownik, D.: Everyone I know is doing it: tipping, political cascades, and individual zones of knowledge. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Chicago, IL, September 1–5 (2004). http://​www.​polisci.​upenn.​edu/​ps-i/​papers.​htm. Accessed 2 Sep 2004
go back to reference North, D.C.: Structure and Change in Economic History. Norton, New York (1981) North, D.C.: Structure and Change in Economic History. Norton, New York (1981)
go back to reference Picker, R.C.: Simple games in a complex world: a generative approach to the adoption of norms. Chicago Working Paper in Law & Economics, vol. 48 (1997) Picker, R.C.: Simple games in a complex world: a generative approach to the adoption of norms. Chicago Working Paper in Law & Economics, vol. 48 (1997)
go back to reference Rogers, E.M.: Diffusion of innovations, 5th edn. Free Press, New York (2003) Rogers, E.M.: Diffusion of innovations, 5th edn. Free Press, New York (2003)
go back to reference Watts, D.J.: Six Degrees: The Science of a Connected Age. WW Norton and Company, New York (2004) Watts, D.J.: Six Degrees: The Science of a Connected Age. WW Norton and Company, New York (2004)
go back to reference Young, H.P.: Diffusion in Social Networks. CSED Working Paper 2. Brookings Institution, Washington DC (1999) Young, H.P.: Diffusion in Social Networks. CSED Working Paper 2. Brookings Institution, Washington DC (1999)
Metadata
Title
When do institutions suddenly collapse? Zones of knowledge and the likelihood of political cascades
Authors
Ian S. Lustick
Dan Miodownik
Publication date
16-05-2019
Publisher
Springer Netherlands
Published in
Quality & Quantity / Issue 2/2020
Print ISSN: 0033-5177
Electronic ISSN: 1573-7845
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11135-019-00883-9

Other articles of this Issue 2/2020

Quality & Quantity 2/2020 Go to the issue