Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Social Indicators Research 1/2021

Open Access 28-02-2021 | Original Research

Does Social Capital Affect Voter Turnout? Evidence from Italy

Authors: Nadia Fiorino, Emma Galli, Nicola Pontarollo

Published in: Social Indicators Research | Issue 1/2021

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

In this paper we develop a new composite indicator, named Social Catalyst, able to account for the complex and multifaceted nature of the social capital in a unitary measure. We use our indicator, as well as its components, to explore the relation between social capital and electoral participation in the parliamentary elections in Italy from 1994 to 2008, addressing the potential endogeneity bias. Our findings show that (i) the Social Catalyst positively and significantly affects voter turnout in both Chambers; (ii) among the different dimensions of social capital, social norms and associational networks play a prominent role in the Italian regional context.
Notes

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

1 Introduction

Does community activity lead to collectively virtuous behavior and improve the quality of democracy? Since the second half of the last century social capital has attracted increasing attention as a relevant factor underlying voting in democracies. A bulk of literature has recognized that civic involvement, social connections, sharing common goals may play a crucial role in explaining differences in political participation. People who socially interact represent an important channel to transmit norms of civic and political participation and recruit other people in these activities (see, among others, Almond and Verba 1963; Putnam 1993; Verba et al. 1995). Integration into formal and informal organizations helps members of the organizations to develop communication and cooperation skills; it also increases trust in people as well as in the political system. Trust, and in particular political trust, is considered an important prerequisite for an active and vigilant citizenry (Almond and Verba 1963; Easton 1965; Gronlund and Setala 2007).1
Empirical evidence, mainly based on individual data or experiments performed on survey data in different countries, is mixed. Some papers find that social capital positively affects voter mobilization by strengthening co-operative behavior or increasing the flow of information (e.g. Putnam 1993; Henn et al 2007; Putnam 2000; Gerber et al. 2008). Others show that it discourages electoral participation by exposing citizens to conflicting views or providing them with an alternative channel to achieve personal goals and satisfaction (e.g. Mutz 2002; Aktinson and Fowler 2014). Overall, these mixed findings are the result of several issues: the difficulty to adequately and unanimously define a phenomenon which encompasses different dimensions ranging from social networks to trust and civic norms; the subsequent complexity of translating these multifaceted definitions into a ‘good’ measure2; the methodological problems of omitted variables and endogeneity that may affect the electoral participation-social capital nexus. For all these motives, the empirical evidence on such a nexus is ambivalent. Moreover, if we consider that several governments and international organizations have undertaken policies increasing community activity as a way to promote (in developing countries) and strengthen (in advanced countries) democracy (see, on this point, Krishna 2007), further investigations are useful.
This paper focuses on Italy, an exemplary case study in the literature on social capital (among others, Putnam 1993; Guiso et al. 2004; de Blasio and Nuzzo 2010; Crescenzi et al. 2013; Guiso et al. 2016). Using aggregate data, we aim at verifying whether the regional endowment of social capital is a good predictor of the electoral participation in 5 national parliamentary elections from 1994 to 2008.
Our contribution to the literature is twofold. As we mentioned before, a key issue in the empirical analyses on social capital is its measurement. In this respect, we develop a new composite indicator, named Social Catalyst, able to account for the complex and multifaceted nature of the social capital in a unitary measure that captures the ‘compositional effect power’ of the different dimensions recognized by the literature. The methodology, which we test using Italian data, is not country-specific, and can be generalized and applied to other countries. Then, we use our new measure of social capital, as well as of its components, to verify its impact on electoral participation.
One problem with testing whether social capital affects voter turnout is possible reverse causation. Several works on social capital have stressed the relation between trust and civic engagement arguing that people who do not trust others will be less likely to participate in public life. These works are based on a generalized worldview optimism, which for the most part does not depend on experiences of participation in civil and political life; they rather reflect a conception of trust as a sentiment linking people who do not know each other (Uslaner 2002; Uslaner and Brown 2005). Other contributions, instead, link civic engagement to trust and trust to participation (Brehm and Rahn 1997; Stolle 1998). According to this view, the experiences of political and civic engagement may shape trust; social activity over time may affects voter turnout and, in turn, participating in politics may increase social capital.3 Another concern is that social capital might be related to other unobservable factors that contribute to explain the variation in turnout across regions.
We take into account all these problems and handle them through a robust identification strategy based on an historical instrument, the number of free city-state in each region. Our results show that the nexus between social capital and turnout is positive and strongly significant in both Chambers and in all the specifications. Besides the ‘bundle effect’ identified by the Social Catalyst, we also focus on the channels through which social capital affects voting participation in Italy and find that social norms and civicness play a relevant and positive role, although with a different intensity.
The paper is organized as follows: Section 2 analyzes the dynamics of the national parliamentary elections in our sample and discusses the methodology we use to build the Social Catalyst. Section 3 presents the model and discusses the results. An additional analysis is provided in Sect. 4. Section 5 concludes.

2 Empirical Strategy

2.1 Why Italy?

As mentioned above, our analysis verifies the voter turnout-social capital nexus focusing on 18 Italian regions from 1994 to 2008. We capture various aspects of civic capital in a unitary measure and disentangle the weight of each variable entering the indicator, so that we are able to separately discuss both the effects of the measure and of its individual components.
Since the pioneering research by Almond and Verba (1963), which focuses on voluntary organizations as “the most important foundations” of stable democracies4, Italy has been considered an interesting case-study. Almond and Verba’s results indeed portray the Italian political culture as characterized by alienation, social isolation and horizontal and vertical dis-trust. In other words, Italian citizens are depicted as uninformed and less interested in politics and civic affairs compared to the counterparts of other countries like Germany, Great Britain, Mexico and USA. The subsequent Putnam’s seminal work (1993) relates the variation of social capital in the Italian regions, rooted in different historical experiences, to their different institutional performance. More recently Tabellini (2010) and Guiso et al. (2016) focus on the long-term effects of social capital in the Italian municipalities.
Italy still deserves attention today. The Eurobarometer and World Value Surveys report that the country is characterized by a low level of trust among people and towards politics and institutions (Cartocci 2011). Moreover, the divide between the Northern and the Southern Italian regions continues to embody a paradigm of within-country differences. Indeed, as shown in Figs. 1 and 2 (and also highlighted in previous research by Buonanno et al. 2009; Barone and de Blasio 2010), turnout as well as social capital are heterogeneously distributed throughout the regions despite common institutions, school systems and religious and ethnic identities.
We concentrate our analysis on the period 1994–2008. In the mid-nineties indeed a decentralization process started in Italy and ended up in 2001 with the creation of a federalist architecture which gave autonomy to the regions and greater importance in terms of political decisions and public policies’ provision (Ambrosiano et al. 2010). Moreover, until the end of the 2000s, political participation has followed traditional channels of expression, which only later have radically changed with the rapid diffusion of the Internet (Istat 2018). Also, the traditional form of social capital has been weakened by the recent phenomenon of social networks which have acted as a substitute for the time people devote to voluntary activities (Prior 2005; Campante et al. 2018).

2.2 Voter Turnout in Italy

Our dependent variable is regional voter turnout in national parliamentary elections. According to the Italian Constitution the Parliament consists of two Houses – the Chamber of Deputies and the Senate - which share the legislative power. The Chamber represents national interests, while the Senate the regional ones. Citizens who are 18 and older have the right to vote for the Chamber of Deputies; citizens who are 25 and older for Senate.
It is worth clarifying that voter turnout in referenda is excluded from the dependent variable because it has been largely used to proxy social capital (among others, Putnam 1993; Guiso et al. 2004, 2008). Indeed, while turnout in referenda is itself a civic value and is unlikely to be driven by pure individual interests, voting at the political elections could be subject to rent-seeking or patronage, resulting in the erosion of social capital.
Economic literature has employed different measures of voter turnout depending on the statistics available (Geys 2006).5 We employ the share of population which cast its vote (Turnout) calculated in each region as the ratio between the number of voters and the population of voting age (i.e., the ‘age eligible’ population) in parliamentary elections. Data come from the Historical Archive of Italian Ministry of Interior.
Figures 1 and 2 show the dynamics of the regional turnout at the Chamber and Senate elections, respectively. The turnout varies between 65% and 95%. Its trend is decreasing in all the regions of our sample except in four Southern ones (Basilicata, Calabria, Molise and Sicily). The latter are characterized by a very low electoral participation, which has grown between 1996 and 2006 and has decreased again in 2008. Overall, the figures display a general stability of turnout along the time and space dimensions and a higher turnout in the Northern regions. These stylized facts point out a persistent phenomenon of spatial polarization.

2.3 The Social Catalyst

One of the main challenges of the paper is to build a new indicator of social capital, named Social Catalyst, which has two major characteristics: (1) it is able to capture the multiple facets of social capital identified in the literature into a unitary measure; (2) it can be easily generalized to different contexts.
As already highlighted, social capital is a complex phenomenon encompassing various dimensions: social norms, shared community values, trust among people and towards institutions, social networks, memberships in associations, civic engagement, which foster cooperation and collective actions for mutual benefits. Some scholars have mainly focused on trust (see, among others, Fukuyama 1995; Bowles and Gintis 2002). Others have emphasized the civicness dimension of social capital intended as common interests and shared values of a community (like Coleman 1988; Putnam 1993) or the benefits that the access to networks and social connections generate for the individuals (like in Bourdieu 1986; Burt 2000; Glaeser et al. 2002). Several contributions have highlighted the general relevance of culture and social norms (see, among others, Putnam 1993; Bertrand et al. 2000).
Empirical studies on social capital suffer from lack of uniformity with respect to the approaches and the related indicators. In this paper we share the conceptualization offered by Putnam (1993) and subsequently revisited by Guiso et al. (2016). Indeed Putnam (1993) describes social capital as a collective resource referring to social networks, norms of reciprocity and trust that result from connections among individuals. Guiso et al. (2016) which define social capital as a ‘civic capital’, i.e. a set of collective values and beliefs that facilitate cooperation among the members of a community. In this regard, social capital is closely related to ‘civic virtue’.
Therefore, our indicator points towards a measure of social capital generated by a combination of networks/cooperation, social norms and trust as interlinked dimensions which all together depict the heritage of a community, consequently contributing to form a unitary concept. These dimensions are captured individually through several variables that are not mutually exclusive, although each of them has its own characteristics and may have a single impact on the dynamics of voter turnout.
Under this perspective, the individual components of our social capital indicator are important not only per se but because they contribute to form a bundle that can affect voter turnout differently from each component, once separately considered. We name this effect the ‘compositional effect power’ and measure it employing our composite synthetic indicator.
Following Goletsis and Chletsos (2011) and Pontarollo and Serpieri (2020), we construct the Social Catalyst through a normalization and weight elicitation which is based on Principal Component Analysis (PCA). This procedure allows to transform multiple dimensions into a set of uncorrelated dimensions and to reduce dimensionality.
Our approach consists of two stages: (a) normalization of data and (b) weight elicitation. Through normalization6 we remove the different scale of each variable and identify indicators that may be positively correlated with the phenomenon of interest. This stage is necessary to ensure that an increase in the normalized indicators corresponds to an increase in the composite indicator. Considering the hth indicator \(I\) for region i, \(I_{hi}\) is transformed to \(I_{hi}^{std}\), taking values within the interval [0,1] according to the following equation:
$$I_{hi}^{std} = \frac{{I_{{hi}} - {}{\min_{i}} (I_{hi} ) }}{{{}{\max_{i} } (I_{hi} ) - {}{\min_{i}} (I_{hi} )}}$$
(1)
We employ the Principal Component Analysis for weight elicitation. This methodology aggregates sub-indicators that are collinear into new ones named ‘components’ and determines the set of weights, which explains the largest variation in the original data. The PCA has also the advantage that the largest factor loadings are attributed to the sub-indicators that show the greater variation across units.
In order to retain the maximum of information, we keep the first two components that cumulatively explain more than 70% of the overall variance of the original data and use the other components selected for the aggregating procedure to guarantee that our variables are not correlated.
We estimate weights as normalized squared loadings, which implies that each component’s share of variance is explained by each variable, and use the highest loading per variable weighted according to the relative explanatory power of the overall variance by each component.
We aggregate the indicator through the following weighted additive function:
$$Social\;Catalyst_{i} = \sum\limits_{h} {w_{h} } I_{{hi}}^{{std}}$$
(2)
where i is the region, \(w_{h}\) is the weight of indicator h and \(I_{hi}^{adi}\) is the adjusted value of indicator \(I_{h}\) for region i.
Table 1 illustrates the individual components of our Social Catalyst. The choice of these components is in line with the literature, which distinguishes forms of generalized and particularistic trust captured by several proxies (see, among others, Uslaner and Brown 2005; de Blasio et al. 2014).
Table 1
The individual components of the Social Catalyst
Variable
N
Source
Definition
Mean
Std. Dev.
Min.
Max.
Associations
90
ISTAT
Persons aged 14 and older who have volunteered in social activities over total population aged 14 and oldera (%)
10.122
3.600
5.118
17.621
Blood donors
90
AVIS
Blood donors over population (%)
1.582
0.912
0.280
3.727
Newspapers diffusion
90
ADSCronos
Number of national and local newspapers over two times population
4.064
1.920
1.367
8.494
Corruption exposure
90
ISTAT
Number of prosecutions for crimes against public administration over population (%)
0.085
0.052
0.025
0.355
TV taxpayers
90
RAI Radio TelevisioneItaliana
TV tax payers over three times population (%)
27.921
4.508
17.276
36.162
All the variables are defined over the period 1992–2008
a   Social activities include participation in meetings of associations (cultural/recreational, ecological, civil rights, peace, sport), trade union organizations, professional or trade associations and political parties
The dimension of generalized trust signals the degree of honesty and integrity of a whole community and captures the relevance of general rules and values which dominate the entitlements of personal relationships7. We proxy it with the variable Corruption exposure (Istat various years).
We proxy associational networks as a dimension of particularistic trust using Blood donors (AVIS various years) and Associations (Istat various years). These variables depict, in slightly different ways, cooperation and social interactions. While Associations relates to networks often motivated by expectations about the behavior of other individuals which create trust mostly among the members, Blood donors captures the humanitarian people’s propensity to volunteering in favor of others.
We measure the dimension of social norms (civicness) using two variables: Newspapers diffusion (ADS Cronos various years) and TV license taxpayers (RAI-Radio—Televisione Italiana various years).
The variable Newspapers diffusion8 works as a channel that facilitates the transmission and sharing of information among citizens, strengthening their sense of membership to a community and their social participation. It is worth noting that during our time span most of the news in Italy are still diffused by means of printed newspapers9. The circulation of the newspapers in fact is quite stable from 1995 to 2006, while it has been steadily decreasing since 2007 (ASIG 2011). TV license taxpayers captures citizens’ tax morale and civic behavior with respect to a tax payment which is very weakly enforced.10
The choice of the proxies we employ in this paper is driven by the specificity of the Italian case especially with respect to variables like Corruption and TV license taxpayers, which are suited to capture phenomena of social and tax morality. Indeed, corruption and tax morale are fundamental problems in Italy and have been – and still are - at the forefront of the political and economic debate (Barone et al. 2012; Filippin et al. 2013; Fiorino and Galli 2013). However, it is worth noting that such a choice does not undermine the potentiality of generalization of our methodology, which can be tested with alternative measures of the Social Catalyst components.
The identified components account for approximately 82.5% of total variance. Variable loadings and weights are in Table 2. The weight associated with Newspapers diffusion is 0.37, and the weight associated to Corruption exposure and TV taxpayers are around 0.23. The weight of Blood donors is equal to 0.14, and of Associations to 0.01. This means that, in construction of the indicator, newspapers diffusion is the most significant component, followed by corruption exposure and TV taxpayers with equal significance (see Freudenberg 2003: 10).11
Table 2
PCA variable loadings and weights
Dimension
Variable
Axis 1 loading
Axis 2 Loading
Weights
Generalized Tust
Corruption exposure
0.3670
0.0080
0.2381
Social norms/Civicness
Newspapers diffusion
0.1650
0.5740
0.3728
 
TV taxpayers
0.2390
0.3630
0.2356
AssociationalNetworks
Associations
0.0150
0.0210
0.0138
 
Blood donors
0.2150
0.0340
0.1397
Figure 3 illustrates the distribution of the average values of the Social Catalyst by quintile. A clear geographical pattern appears. The Northern regions show a higher social capital than the Southern ones, confirming previous research on the Italian North-South divide (Bigoni et al. 2016; Cartocci and Vanelli, 2015).
Finally, Figures 4 and 5 graphically show the correlation between Social Catalyst and turnout in the Chamber of Deputies and in the Senate, respectively. In both cases we observe a clear-cut positive correlation: in areas of the country where social capital is higher, turnout also is higher. Moreover, no outliers and leverage points are detectable in the graphs.

3 The Empirical Model and Results

Our empirical model is the following:
$$Turnout_{{i,t}} = \alpha + \beta Social\;Catalyst_{{i,t - 1}} + \delta {\mathbf{X}}_{{i,t - 1}} + T + \varepsilon _{{i,t}}$$
(3)
Where i is the number of regions, of which there are 18, t is the electoral year, namely 1994, 1998, 2001, 2004, 2008. T is a time dummy, α, β and δ are parameters to be estimated and the εi i.i.d error term. Turnout is alternatively Senate of Chamber turnout. Social capital is proxied by the Social Catalyst which is our variable of interest, and X is a vector accounting for the following demographic, economic and institutional control variables (descriptive statistics are in Table A1 and correlation matrix in Table A2):
  • Population density, measured as the log of population over regional area in squared kilometers. Data come from Istat. The literature is not unanimous about the effect of population density on turnout. On the one hand, urbanization may generate a weakening of interpersonal relations and social norms, hereby reducing social pressure to vote (see, among others, Geys 2006). On the other, the neighborhood context may play a role in shaping voters’ participation to elections as living in close proximity, belonging to the same social networks and interacting frequently can affect people’s patterns of political behavior (see, among others, Fieldhouse and Cutts 2012).
  • Income inequality, measured by the Gini index (based on data on the Survey of Household Income and Wealth conducted by the Bank of Italy). With respect to this issue, the literature is ambivalent. Some studies argue that greater income gap intensifies social conflict for redistribution, increasing expected gains and losses and therefore voter turnout (Meltzer and Richard 1981). Others highlight that poor respond to unequal redistribution by withdrawing from the political process (see, for example, Goodin and Dryzek 1980).
  • School attainment, measured as the share of population enrolled in high school, is associated to greater electoral participation (Blais 2000). Data come from CRENOS and Istat.
  • Winning margin, computed as the percentage vote gap between the largest party and its closest competitor at the district level, captures the positive effect of political parties’ competitiveness on turnout (Matsusaka and Palda 1993; Geys 2006). The source of data is Italian Ministry of Interior.
All the independent variables have been lagged by one year in order to avoid reverse causality issues. As we show in the Results section, we employ a pooled and a random effect model, which is the most suitable model according to the Hausman Test. Although our results are based on covariates lagged of one year, we also provide IV pooled and IV random effects, which allow to address simultaneity bias as well as errors in measurement of the Social Catalyst. The IV approach requires the identification of a valid instrument - i.e. an instrument that should satisfy the relevance and exclusion restrictions conditions. According to these conditions, the instrument should correlate with the key explanatory variable but not with the error term. We instrument the Social Catalyst with the number of free city-state per region as in Guiso et al. (2016).
The choice of this instrument rests on the following. Investigating the factors behind social-capital accumulation, several studies have stressed the role of the long-term evolution of culture and social norms in Italy (Putnam 1993; Bracco et al. 2015; Albanese and de Blasio 2016; Guiso et al 2016). As matter of fact, the medieval experience of self-government (Comuni) stimulated social and political institutions that built mutual trust and cooperative norms over the long run, persisting to the present day. Based on this argument, we hypothesize that the number of free city-state in each region correlates with our Social Catalyst.
Furthermore, several reasons suggest that the free city-state does not exert a direct effect on our dependent variable. Firstly, the long-standing determinants of social capital remove any simultaneity bias caused by local shocks that occurred in more recent history. Indeed, it is hard to believe that these shocks could have influenced both the medieval experience of self-government and the current levels voter turnout. Therefore, we can exclude the existence of any source of simultaneity. Secondly, the exclusion restriction might be violated if some missing permanent characteristics related to people agglomeration or economic conditions of a region drove both the history of the free city-state and the current levels of turnout. However, we directly control in our regressions for the most relevant economic characteristics, and for population density. In light of these motivations, we consider the free city-state a good candidate to instrument our Social Catalyst.
Finally, given that the free city-state is a time invariant variable, we estimate a random effect IV model and a pooled IV model including time fixed effects in both cases. The Kleibergen-Paap F statistic rejects the null hypothesis, meaning that our instrument is strong. The first stage regression on Table A3 confirms the relevance of the instrument. However, the Wu-Hausman test on endogeneity shows that the null hypothesis cannot be rejected, raising doubts about the potential endogeneity of the Social Catalyst.
The results are reported in Table 3. The signs and significance of the coefficients are confirmed in all models. The positive nexus between social capital and turnout is strongly significant in all the specifications, corroborating Henn et al. (2007) and Gerber et al. (2008) findings, although with aggregate rather than individual level or survey data. No differences occur at both Chamber of Deputies and Senate. Among the control variables identified by the literature on the determinants of turnout, population density is positively correlated with the regional turnout, showing the prevalence of a “socialization effect”; income inequality seems to discourage voters, being negatively correlated; education turns out weakly and positively correlated only in the IV pooled model in the Chamber, and in both the pooled and IV pooled models in the Senate; Winning margin has a null effect in stimulating voter turnout.
Table 3
Estimates for the Chamber of Deputies and Senate
 
Chamber
Senate
 
Pooled
Random eff.
IV Pooled
IV Random eff.
Pooled
Random eff.
IV Pooled
IV Random eff.
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
School attainment-1
0.6398
0.2172
0.7003*
0.2171
0.5159*
0.2255
0.6387*
0.2255
 
(0.4862)
(0.5035)
(0.4755)
(0.5034)
(0.3064)
(0.4391)
(0.5351)
(0.4394)
Income inequality-1
−0.3339**
−0.2353**
−0.3115**
−0.2353**
−0.3589**
−0.2615**
−0.3060**
−0.2615**
 
(0.1355)
(0.1134)
(0.1479)
(0.1137)
(0.1136)
(0.1120)
(0.1545)
(0.1121)
Winning margin-1
0.00004
−0.0003
0.0004
−0.0003
0.0004
−0.0001
0.0006
−0.0005
 
(0.0004)
(0.0004)
(0.0005)
(0.0004)
(0.0004)
(0.0004)
(0.0006)
(0.0004)
log(pop. density) -1
0.0188***
0.0195***
0.0180***
0.0195***
0.0250***
0.0241***
0.0232***
0.0241***
 
(0.0070)
(0.0075)
(0.0074)
(0.0075)
(0.0052)
(0.0073)
(0.0075)
(0.0072)
Social Catalyst-1
0.2046***
0.2210***
0.2061***
0.2210***
0.2030***
0.2183***
0.2109***
0.2183***
 
(0.0210)
(0.0269)
(0.0300)
(0.0268)
(0.0138)
(0.0303)
(0.0271)
(0.0202)
Intercept
0.7649***
0.7416***
0.7532***
0.6572***
0.7349***
0.7142***
0.7118***
0.6414***
 
(0.0534)
(0.0481)
(0.0495)
(0.0688)
(0.0446)
(0.0692)
(0.0504)
(0.0692)
Observations
90
90
90
90
90
90
90
90
Time dummies
yes
yes
yes
yes
yes
yes
yes
yes
R2
0.7937
0.6843
0.7952
0.7834
0.7884
0.6508
0.7910
0.7815
Adjusted R2
0.7705
0.6488
0.7521
 
0.7646
0.6115
0.7675
 
Kleibergen Paap F stat.(p-value)
  
25.963 (<0.01)
   
25.963 (<0.01)
 
Hausman test (p-val)
 
6.648 (0.674)
   
2.900 (0.968)
  
Wu-Hausman test (p-val)
  
0.045 (0.832)
   
0.162 (0.688)
 
*p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01. Estimates are based on random effects models. Regionally cluster robust standard errors in brackets

4 Bundle Effect vs Individual Effects

As emphasized in Sect. 2.3, the Social Catalyst is able to capture the bundle effect on voter turnout created by the individual components of the indicator, which are important not only per se but because of the ‘relational or spillover’ effects they generate on each other as well as on the measure of social capital. Our estimates show that the bundle effect identified by the Social Catalyst is strongly and positively correlated with voter turnout suggesting that the complex and multifaceted nature of social capital overall influence voting decisions.
Table 4 compares the ‘bundle’ with the ‘individual’ effect of each component of our measure of social capital on voter participation, once considered separately. Both the social norms (TV taxpayers and Newspapers’ diffusion) and associational networks’ variables (Associations and Blood donors) are strongly and positively correlated with voter turnout, showing that the particularistic dimensions of social capital is able to promote an active citizenry (see, among others, Gronlund and Setala 2007). Instead, the coefficient on Corruption exposure is not significant, suggesting that electoral participation is not affected by the general sense of integrity and legality of the community. While corruption enters social capital as a relevant dimension, it does not affect electoral participation, once taken separately. This result interestingly implies that the influence of corruption on electoral participation is mediated by the strength of social norms as well as by informational environment (see, Chang et al. 2010). In other words, corruption is not relevant per se in shaping voters’ behavior; what matters is the ‘bundle effect’ of social channels, which make voters aware of corruption in political life.
Table 4
Estimates for the Chamber of Deputies and the Senate by component of the Social Catalyst
 
Chamber
Senate
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
(9)
(10)
School attainment-1
0.6013
0.5153
0.1113
1.0577***
−0.0541
0.5908
0.5077
0.2512
1.1076***
0.0374
 
(0.4171)
(0.4294)
(0.5541)
(0.3822)
(0.3987)
(0.4262)
(0.4066)
(0.5166)
(0.4067)
(0.3845)
Income inequality-1
−0.2787**
−0.2287*
−0.1925*
−0.2955
−0.1803*
−0.2957**
−0.2487**
−0.2305**
−0.3257*
−0.2055**
 
(0.1240)
(0.1315)
(0.1020)
(0.1800)
(0.1076)
(0.1258)
(0.1247)
(0.0945)
(0.1736)
(0.1026)
Winning margin-1
−0.0001
−0.0001
−0.0004
0.0008
−0.000005
0.0002
0.0001
−0.0001
0.0012*
0.0002
 
(0.0005)
(0.0005)
(0.0005)
(0.0007)
(0.0006)
(0.0004)
(0.0004)
(0.0004)
(0.0007)
(0.0005)
log(pop. density) -1
0.0179***
0.0181
0.0126
0.0154
0.0312**
0.0218***
0.0228
0.0158
0.0201
0.0355***
 
(0.0065)
(0.0162)
(0.0110)
(0.0125)
(0.0134)
(0.0083)
(0.0153)
(0.0129)
(0.0127)
(0.0133)
Associations-1
0.9471***
    
0.7918***
    
 
(0.1315)
    
(0.1297)
    
Blood donors-1
 
4.2214***
    
4.3181***
   
  
(0.8095)
    
(0.9375)
   
Newspapers diff. -1
  
1.8505***
    
1.8431***
  
   
(0.5921)
    
(0.6263)
  
Corruption exposure-1
   
−21.1425
    
−23.4911
 
    
(17.1936)
    
(17.2033)
 
TV taxpayers-1
    
0.3093***
    
0.3121***
     
(0.0777)
    
(0.0789)
Intercept
0.7419***
0.7606***
0.7711***
0.8358***
0.4981***
0.7290***
0.7289***
0.7498***
0.8074***
0.4658***
 
(0.0482)
(0.0898)
(0.0690)
(0.0613)
(0.1073)
(0.0488)
(0.0923)
(0.0743)
(0.0620)
(0.1112)
Observations
90
90
90
90
90
90
90
90
90
90
Time dummies
yes
yes
yes
yes
yes
yes
yes
yes
yes
yes
R2
0.5526
0.5756
0.5056
0.3942
0.5608
0.4877
0.5759
0.4849
0.3945
0.5492
Adjusted R2
0.5023
0.5279
0.4499
0.3260
0.5114
0.4300
0.5281
0.4269
0.3264
0.4985
Hausman test (p-value)
32.082 (<0.01)
16.187 (0.0631)
5.772 (0.7625)
19.089 (0.0244)
11.647 (0.234)
76.150 (<0.01)
10.774 (0.2915)
9.906 (0.3581)
10.660 (0.2997)
4.684 (0.8609)
*p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01. Estimates are based on random effects models. Regionally cluster robust standard errors in brackets

5 Conclusions

In this paper we develop a new composite indicator of social capital, the Social Catalyst, which is able to capture the ‘compositional effect power’ of different dimension of trust by analyzing the weight of each individual component. The methodology, which we test using Italian data, can be generalized and applied to different countries.
The Social Catalyst is employed to explore the following questions: Is local social capital a good predictor of the electoral participation in national Parliamentary elections? Among the different dimensions of social capital, which are the drivers of voter turnout? Firstly, we provide empirical evidence that the nexus between social capital and turnout is positive and strongly significant in both Chambers, after testing for the circular causation between social capital and political participation. Secondly, we find that social norms and civicness play a prominent role, although with a different intensity. We can conclude therefore that greater involvement in politics and trust in the electoral process seems to be favored by an increase of community social norms and civic participation.
Future studies may consider other methodologies that would allow to empirically test latent variables relationships, enriching the set of indicators for each latent variable and further developing our empirical contribution.
Open AccessThis article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://​creativecommons.​org/​licenses/​by/​4.​0/​.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Appendix

Appendix 1

Table A1
Descriptive statistics
 
Mean
Std. Dev.
Min.
Max.
Turnout Senate
0.8127
0.0623
0.6600
0.9600
Turnout Chamber
0.8166
0.06190
0.6736
0.9315
School attainment -1
0.0059
0.0022
0.0023
0.0120
Income inequality -1
0.2590
0.3080
0.3190
0.4270
Winning margin -1
8.8310
6.6486
0.0200
31.5500
log(pop. density) -1
5.0640
0.6105
3.8430
6.0540
Social Catalyst -1
0.4152
0.2139
0.0488
0.0876
Table A2
Correlation matrix
 
TurnoutChamber
TurnoutSenate
SchoolAttainm. −1
IncomeIneq. −1
Winningmargin −1
Log(pop. den.) −1
SocialCatalyst −1
Assoc. −1
Blooddonors −1
Newspap.diff. −1
Corruptionexposure −1
TVtaxpayers −1
Turnout Chamber
1.0000
           
Turnout Senate
0.9799
1.0000
          
School attainment -1
0.0991
0.1507
1.0000
         
Income inequality -1
−0.3215
−0.3221
−0.3247
1.0000
        
Winning margin -1
0.3470
0.3636
−0.1976
−0.0535
1.0000
       
log(pop. density) -1
0.1941
0.2437
0.1746
0.2240
0.0431
1.0000
      
Social Catalyst -1
0.7609
0.7710
0.2486
−0.3238
0.2934
0.0214
1.0000
     
Associations -1
0.6737
0.6752
0.2019
−0.2799
0.3315
0.0029
0.9104
1.0000
    
Blood donors -1
0.5640
0.5984
0.2437
−0.1729
0.2762
0.0186
0.7943
0.6153
1.0000
   
Newspapers diff. -1
0.6088
0.5826
0.1430
−0.3313
0.1375
0.1145
0.7203
0.6667
0.2082
1.0000
  
Corruption exposure -1
−0.4049
−0.4178
0.3697
−0.0672
−0.1550
−0.0009
−0.3191
−0.3040
−0.2822
−0.1229
1.0000
 
TV taxpayers -1
0.6405
0.6487
0.2103
−0.3633
0.1109
−0.1417
0.7987
0.6731
0.4552
0.7211
−0.2871
1.0000
Table A3
First stage regression
Dependent variable: Social Catalyst
Variable
School attainment
6.3177***
 
(2.0186)
Income inequality
−0.5879
 
(0.5977)
Winning margin
0.0073**
 
(0.0033)
log(pop. density)
−0.0974***
 
(0.0366)
Free city-state
0.0216***
 
(0.0033)
Constant
0.5780
 
(0.2342)
Observations
90
Time dummies
yes
R2
0.4501
Adjusted R2
0.3882
F-test (coeff. Free city-state = 0)
25.963 ***
*p<0.1; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01. Regionally cluster robust standard errors in brackets
Footnotes
1
The impact of political trust on electoral turnout is contested. Indeed, also dis-trust is considered positive for democracy as it helps to mobilize critical citizens who hold the decision-makers accountable (Norris 1999).
 
2
For a recent and exhaustive review of the definitions and measures of social capital see de Blasio et al. 2014.
 
3
However, not all forms of civic engagement are alike, and trust should not work the same way across all of them. While generalized trust does not specifically shape political participation but leads people to participate to a variety of collective actions, particularized trust mostly leads them away from civic life (Uslaner 2000).
 
4
Almond and Verba (1963) consider voluntary organizations as socialization’ environments and “schools for democracy”, since they combine the role of membership with that of citizen in the social practice.
 
5
Most of the empirical studies have used either the ratio between the number of voters and voting age population and/or the number of voters over the number registered to vote. Some papers use the absolute number of votes cast and the number of voters over the number of eligible voters. Nevertheless, it is difficult to state which operationalization of the turnout rate is the ‘best’.
 
6
There are different methods of normalization: ranking, re-scaling or min-max transformation, standardization or z-scores. Following Goletsis and Chletsos (2011), we employ the min-max transformation. However, the min max transformation may be sensitive to outliers, modifying the range of the distribution and consequently the distance between transformed observations different from the max (or min). We checked for the presence of outliers by comparing each original and transformed variable through a scatter plot with marginal density plots and did not observed extreme values.
 
7
It is worth noting that when people trust governments and institutions it is easier to build trust and cooperation among them. There are several examples of untrustworthy and corrupt governments and institutions that have spread distrust throughout society (Paldam 2000).
 
8
Newspapers are both national and local. We assume that each copy is read by two individuals and therefore consider the variable over two times population, as in Gentzkow et al. (2011).
 
9
World Bank data indicate that Internet use in Italy began to take hold around 1998, reaching almost 41 percent of the population in 2007. See https://​data.​worldbank.​org/​indicator/​IT.​NET.​USER.​ZS?​locations=​IT (last accessed October 1, 2018). It is also worth noting that from 2001 to 2010 newspaper readership has been growing increasingly reaching almost 45% of the adult population in 2010. This is also explained by the growing diffusion of access to sites web of newspapers (ASIG 2011).
 
10
During our sample period the television license tax was easy to evade and the fines for a household are low relative to cost (up to 516 Euros plus a mandatory 5-year license purchase) (Bracco et al. 2015). We consider the variable over three times population since a representative family in Italy includes three people.
 
11
The weights are related to the significance of each component and not to the relative importance in the indicator (Becker et al., 2015) According to Nardo et al. (2008) in additive aggregations weights the meaning of substitution rates. For an interesting overview see Decancq and Lugo (2013).
 
Literature
go back to reference Albanese, G., & de Blasio, G. (2016). Civic capital and development: Italy, 1951–2001. Politica Economica - Journal of Economic Policy, 1, 47–64. Albanese, G., & de Blasio, G. (2016). Civic capital and development: Italy, 1951–2001. Politica Economica - Journal of Economic Policy, 1, 47–64.
go back to reference Almond, G., & Verba, S. (1963). The civic culture: Political attitudes and democracy in five nations. Princeton University Press: Princeton.CrossRef Almond, G., & Verba, S. (1963). The civic culture: Political attitudes and democracy in five nations. Princeton University Press: Princeton.CrossRef
go back to reference Ambrosanio, M. F., Bordignon, M., & Cerniglia, F. (2010). Constitutional reforms, fiscal decentralization and regional fiscal flows in Italy. In: N. Bosch, M. Espasa, & A. Solé Ollé (Eds.), The political economy of inter-regional fiscal flows (pp. 75–107). London: Edward Elgar. Ambrosanio, M. F., Bordignon, M., & Cerniglia, F. (2010). Constitutional reforms, fiscal decentralization and regional fiscal flows in Italy. In: N. Bosch, M. Espasa, & A. Solé Ollé (Eds.), The political economy of inter-regional fiscal flows (pp. 75–107). London: Edward Elgar.
go back to reference ASIG (2001). Rapporto 2011 sull’industria dei quotidiani in Italia. Roma. ASIG (2001). Rapporto 2011 sull’industria dei quotidiani in Italia. Roma.
go back to reference Atkinson, M., & Fowler, A. (2014). Social capital and voter turnout: Evidence from Saint’s Day fiestas in Mexico. British Journal of Political Science, 44, 41–59.CrossRef Atkinson, M., & Fowler, A. (2014). Social capital and voter turnout: Evidence from Saint’s Day fiestas in Mexico. British Journal of Political Science, 44, 41–59.CrossRef
go back to reference Barone, G., Cannari, L., & Mocetti, S. (2012). Gli italiani e l’atteggiamento nei confronti del fisco. In A. Gentile & S. Giannini (Eds.), Evasione fiscale e tax compliance. Bologna: Il Mulino. Barone, G., Cannari, L., & Mocetti, S. (2012). Gli italiani e l’atteggiamento nei confronti del fisco. In A. Gentile & S. Giannini (Eds.), Evasione fiscale e tax compliance. Bologna: Il Mulino.
go back to reference Barone, G., de Blasio, G. (2010). Il capitale sociale. In Il Mezzogiorno e la politica economica dell’Italia, Seminari e Convegni, 4, Banca d’Italia, Roma. Barone, G., de Blasio, G. (2010). Il capitale sociale. In Il Mezzogiorno e la politica economica dell’Italia, Seminari e Convegni, 4, Banca d’Italia, Roma.
go back to reference Becker, W., Paruolo, P., Saisana, M., & Saltelli, A. (2015). Weights and importance in composite indicators: Mind the gap. In R. Ghanem, D. Higdon, & H. Owhadi (Eds.), Handbook of uncertainty quantification. Cham: Springer. Becker, W., Paruolo, P., Saisana, M., & Saltelli, A. (2015). Weights and importance in composite indicators: Mind the gap. In R. Ghanem, D. Higdon, & H. Owhadi (Eds.), Handbook of uncertainty quantification. Cham: Springer.
go back to reference Bertrand, M., Luttmer, E. F. P., & Mullainathan, S. (2000). Network effects and welfare culture. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, 1019–55.CrossRef Bertrand, M., Luttmer, E. F. P., & Mullainathan, S. (2000). Network effects and welfare culture. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, 1019–55.CrossRef
go back to reference Bigoni, M., Bortolotti, S., Casari, M., Gambetta, D., & Pancotto, F. (2016). Amoral familism, social capital, or trust? The behavioural foundations of the Italian North-South divide. The Economic Journal, 126, 1318–41.CrossRef Bigoni, M., Bortolotti, S., Casari, M., Gambetta, D., & Pancotto, F. (2016). Amoral familism, social capital, or trust? The behavioural foundations of the Italian North-South divide. The Economic Journal, 126, 1318–41.CrossRef
go back to reference Blais, A. (2000). To vote or not to vote: The merits and limits of rational choice theory. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press.CrossRef Blais, A. (2000). To vote or not to vote: The merits and limits of rational choice theory. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Bourdieu, P. (1986). The forms of capital. In J. G. Richardson (Ed.), Handbook of theory and research for the sociology of education (pp. 241–258). New York: Greenwood Press. Bourdieu, P. (1986). The forms of capital. In J. G. Richardson (Ed.), Handbook of theory and research for the sociology of education (pp. 241–258). New York: Greenwood Press.
go back to reference Bowles, S., & Gintis, H. (2002). ‘Social Capital’ and community governance. Economic Journal, 112, 419–36.CrossRef Bowles, S., & Gintis, H. (2002). ‘Social Capital’ and community governance. Economic Journal, 112, 419–36.CrossRef
go back to reference Bracco, E., De Paola, M., & Green, C. P. (2015). Long lasting differences in civic capital: Evidence from a unique immigration event in Italy. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 120, 160–173.CrossRef Bracco, E., De Paola, M., & Green, C. P. (2015). Long lasting differences in civic capital: Evidence from a unique immigration event in Italy. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 120, 160–173.CrossRef
go back to reference Brehm, J., & Rahn, W. (1997). Individual level evidence for the causes and consequences of social capital. American Journal of Political Science, 41, 881–1023.CrossRef Brehm, J., & Rahn, W. (1997). Individual level evidence for the causes and consequences of social capital. American Journal of Political Science, 41, 881–1023.CrossRef
go back to reference Buonanno, P., Montolio, D., & Vanin, P. (2009). Does social capital reduce crime? The Journal of Law and Economics, 52, 145–170.CrossRef Buonanno, P., Montolio, D., & Vanin, P. (2009). Does social capital reduce crime? The Journal of Law and Economics, 52, 145–170.CrossRef
go back to reference Burt, R. S. (2000). The network structure of social capital R., in I. Sutton and B. M. Shaw (eds.), Research in organizational behavior, Greenwich, JAI Press. Burt, R. S. (2000). The network structure of social capital R., in I. Sutton and B. M. Shaw (eds.), Research in organizational behavior, Greenwich, JAI Press.
go back to reference Campante, F., Durante, R., & Sobbrio, F. (2018). Politics 2.0: The multifaceted effect of broadband internet on political participation. Journal of the European Economic Association, 16, 1094–1136.CrossRef Campante, F., Durante, R., & Sobbrio, F. (2018). Politics 2.0: The multifaceted effect of broadband internet on political participation. Journal of the European Economic Association, 16, 1094–1136.CrossRef
go back to reference Cartocci, R. (2011). Capitale sociale. In M. Almagisti & D. Piana (Eds.), Parole-chiave della politica italiana. Carocci: Roma. Cartocci, R. (2011). Capitale sociale. In M. Almagisti & D. Piana (Eds.), Parole-chiave della politica italiana. Carocci: Roma.
go back to reference Cartocci, R. & Vanelli, V. (2015). Una mappa del capitale sociale e della cultura civica in Italia’. L’Italia e le sue regioni. L’età repubblicana. Società Istituto Enciclopedia Italiana Treccani, Roma, 17–36. Cartocci, R. & Vanelli, V. (2015). Una mappa del capitale sociale e della cultura civica in Italia’. L’Italia e le sue regioni. L’età repubblicana. Società Istituto Enciclopedia Italiana Treccani, Roma,  17–36.
go back to reference Chang, E. C. C., Golden, M. A., & Hill, S. I. (2010). Legislative malfeasance and political accountability. Word Politics, 62, 177–220.CrossRef Chang, E. C. C., Golden, M. A., & Hill, S. I. (2010). Legislative malfeasance and political accountability. Word Politics, 62, 177–220.CrossRef
go back to reference Coleman, J. (1988). Social capital in the creation of human capital. American Journal of Sociology, 94, 95–120.CrossRef Coleman, J. (1988). Social capital in the creation of human capital. American Journal of Sociology, 94, 95–120.CrossRef
go back to reference Fieldhouse, E., & Cutts, D. (2012). The companion effect: Household and local context and the turnout of young people. The Journal of Politics, 74, 856–869.CrossRef Fieldhouse, E., & Cutts, D. (2012). The companion effect: Household and local context and the turnout of young people. The Journal of Politics, 74, 856–869.CrossRef
go back to reference Crescenzi, R., Gagliardi, L., & Percoco, M. (2013). Social capital and the innovative performance of Italian provinces. Environment and Planning, 45, 908–29.CrossRef Crescenzi, R., Gagliardi, L., & Percoco, M. (2013). Social capital and the innovative performance of Italian provinces. Environment and Planning, 45, 908–29.CrossRef
go back to reference Crescenzi, R., & Rodríguez-Pose, A. (2012). Infrastructure and regional growth in the European Union. Papers in Regional Science, 91, 487–615.CrossRef Crescenzi, R., & Rodríguez-Pose, A. (2012). Infrastructure and regional growth in the European Union. Papers in Regional Science, 91, 487–615.CrossRef
go back to reference de Blasio, G., Scalise, D., & Sestito, P. (2014). Universalism vs. particularism: a round trip from sociology to economics. Questioni di Economia e Finanza (Occasional Papers), 212, 6–37. de Blasio, G., Scalise, D., & Sestito, P. (2014). Universalism vs. particularism: a round trip from sociology to economics. Questioni di Economia e Finanza (Occasional Papers), 212, 6–37.
go back to reference de Blasio, G., & Nuzzo, G. (2010). Historical traditions of civicness and local economic development. Journal of Regional Science, 50, 833–57.CrossRef de Blasio, G., & Nuzzo, G. (2010). Historical traditions of civicness and local economic development. Journal of Regional Science, 50, 833–57.CrossRef
go back to reference Decancq, K., & Lugo, M. A. (2013). Weights in multidimensional indices of wellbeing: An overview. Econometric Reviews, 32, 7–34.CrossRef Decancq, K., & Lugo, M. A. (2013). Weights in multidimensional indices of wellbeing: An overview. Econometric Reviews, 32, 7–34.CrossRef
go back to reference Easton, D. (1965). A systems analysis of political life. New York: Wiley. Easton, D. (1965). A systems analysis of political life. New York: Wiley.
go back to reference Filippin, A., Fiorio, C. V., & Viviano, E. (2013). The effect of tax enforcement on tax morale. European Journal of Political Economy, 32, 320–331.CrossRef Filippin, A., Fiorio, C. V., & Viviano, E. (2013). The effect of tax enforcement on tax morale. European Journal of Political Economy, 32, 320–331.CrossRef
go back to reference Fiorino, N., & Galli, E. (2013). La corruzione in Italia. Bologna: Il Mulino. Fiorino, N., & Galli, E. (2013). La corruzione in Italia. Bologna: Il Mulino.
go back to reference Freudenberg, M. (2003). Composite indicators of country performance: a critical assessment. OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers. Paris: No. 2003/16, OECD Publishing. Freudenberg, M. (2003). Composite indicators of country performance: a critical assessment. OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers. Paris: No. 2003/16, OECD Publishing.
go back to reference Fukuyama, F. (1995). Trust. New York: Free Press. Fukuyama, F. (1995). Trust. New York: Free Press.
go back to reference Gentzkow, M., Shapiro, J., & Sinkinson, M. (2011). The effect of newspaper entry and exit on electoral politics. American Economic Review, 101, 2980–3018.CrossRef Gentzkow, M., Shapiro, J., & Sinkinson, M. (2011). The effect of newspaper entry and exit on electoral politics. American Economic Review, 101, 2980–3018.CrossRef
go back to reference Gerber, A., Green, D., & Larimer, C. (2008). Social pressure and voter turnout: Evidence from a large-scale field experiment. American Political Science Review, 102, 33–48.CrossRef Gerber, A., Green, D., & Larimer, C. (2008). Social pressure and voter turnout: Evidence from a large-scale field experiment. American Political Science Review, 102, 33–48.CrossRef
go back to reference Geys, B. (2006). Explaining voter turnout: A review of aggregate-level research. Electoral Studies, 25, 637–663.CrossRef Geys, B. (2006). Explaining voter turnout: A review of aggregate-level research. Electoral Studies, 25, 637–663.CrossRef
go back to reference Goletsis, Y., & Chletsos, M. (2011). Measurement of development and regional disparities in Greek periphery: A multivariate approach. Socio-Economic Planning, 45, 174–183.CrossRef Goletsis, Y., & Chletsos, M. (2011). Measurement of development and regional disparities in Greek periphery: A multivariate approach. Socio-Economic Planning, 45, 174–183.CrossRef
go back to reference Glaeser, E. L., Laibson, D. I., & Sacerdote, B. (2002). An economic approach to social capital. The Economic Journal, 112, 437–458.CrossRef Glaeser, E. L., Laibson, D. I., & Sacerdote, B. (2002). An economic approach to social capital. The Economic Journal, 112, 437–458.CrossRef
go back to reference Goodin, R., & Dryzek, J. (1980). Rational participation: The politics of relative power. British Journal of Political Science, 10, 273–292.CrossRef Goodin, R., & Dryzek, J. (1980). Rational participation: The politics of relative power. British Journal of Political Science, 10, 273–292.CrossRef
go back to reference Gronlund, K., & Setala, M. (2007). Political trust, satisfaction and voter turnout. Comparative European Politics, 5, 400–422.CrossRef Gronlund, K., & Setala, M. (2007). Political trust, satisfaction and voter turnout. Comparative European Politics, 5, 400–422.CrossRef
go back to reference Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2016). Long term persistence. Journal of the European Economics Association, 14, 1401–1436.CrossRef Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2016). Long term persistence. Journal of the European Economics Association, 14, 1401–1436.CrossRef
go back to reference Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2008). Social capital and good culture. Marshall Lecture, Journal of the European Economics Association, 6, 295–320.CrossRef Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2008). Social capital and good culture. Marshall Lecture, Journal of the European Economics Association, 6, 295–320.CrossRef
go back to reference Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2004). The role of social capital in financial development. American Economic Review, 94(3), 526–556.CrossRef Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2004). The role of social capital in financial development. American Economic Review, 94(3), 526–556.CrossRef
go back to reference Hansen, L. P. (1982). Large sample properties of generalized method of moments estimators. Econometrica, 50, 1029–1054.CrossRef Hansen, L. P. (1982). Large sample properties of generalized method of moments estimators. Econometrica, 50, 1029–1054.CrossRef
go back to reference Henn, M., Weinstein, M., & Hodgkinson, S. (2007). Social capital and political participation: understanding the dynamics of young people’s political disengagement in contemporary Britain. Social Policy and Society, 6(4), 467–479.CrossRef Henn, M., Weinstein, M., & Hodgkinson, S. (2007). Social capital and political participation: understanding the dynamics of young people’s political disengagement in contemporary Britain. Social Policy and Society, 6(4), 467–479.CrossRef
go back to reference Istat (various years). Annuario delle statistiche giudiziarie. Roma: Istat. Istat (various years). Annuario delle statistiche giudiziarie. Roma: Istat.
go back to reference Istat (2018). Rapporto sulla Conoscenza in Italia. Istat: Roma. Istat (2018). Rapporto sulla Conoscenza in Italia. Istat: Roma.
go back to reference Krishna, A. (2007). How does social capital grow? A seven-year study of villages in India. Journal of Politics, 69, 941–56.CrossRef Krishna, A. (2007). How does social capital grow? A seven-year study of villages in India. Journal of Politics, 69, 941–56.CrossRef
go back to reference Norris, P. (Ed.). (1999). Critical citizens – global support for democratic government. Oxford University Press: Oxford. Norris, P. (Ed.). (1999). Critical citizens – global support for democratic government. Oxford University Press: Oxford.
go back to reference Matsusaka, J. G., & Palda, F. (1993). The Downsian voter meets the ecological fallacy. Public Choice, 77, 855–878.CrossRef Matsusaka, J. G., & Palda, F. (1993). The Downsian voter meets the ecological fallacy. Public Choice, 77, 855–878.CrossRef
go back to reference Meltzer, A. H., & Richard, S. F. (1981). A rational theory of the size of government. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 914–27.CrossRef Meltzer, A. H., & Richard, S. F. (1981). A rational theory of the size of government. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 914–27.CrossRef
go back to reference Mutz, D. (2002). The consequences of cross-cutting networks for political participation. American Journal of Political Science, 46, 838–55.CrossRef Mutz, D. (2002). The consequences of cross-cutting networks for political participation. American Journal of Political Science, 46, 838–55.CrossRef
go back to reference Nardo, M., Saisana, M., Saltelli, A., & Tarantola, S. (2008). Handbook on constructing composite indicators: Methodology and user guide OECD, European Commission. Joint Research Centre: OECD Publishing. Nardo, M., Saisana, M., Saltelli, A., & Tarantola, S. (2008). Handbook on constructing composite indicators: Methodology and user guide OECD, European Commission. Joint Research Centre: OECD Publishing.
go back to reference Pontarollo, N., & Serpieri, C. (2020). A composite policy tool to measure territorial resilience capacity. Socio-Economic Planning Sciences, 70, 100669.CrossRef Pontarollo, N., & Serpieri, C. (2020). A composite policy tool to measure territorial resilience capacity. Socio-Economic Planning Sciences, 70, 100669.CrossRef
go back to reference Prior, M. (2005). News vs. entertainment: How increasing media choice widens gaps in political knowledge and turnout. American Journal of Political Science, 49, 577–592.CrossRef Prior, M. (2005). News vs. entertainment: How increasing media choice widens gaps in political knowledge and turnout. American Journal of Political Science, 49, 577–592.CrossRef
go back to reference Putnam, R. (1993). Making democracy work: Civic traditions in modern Italy. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press. Putnam, R. (1993). Making democracy work: Civic traditions in modern Italy. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Putnam, R. (2000). Bowling alone: The collapse and revival of American community. New York: Simon and Schuster. Putnam, R. (2000). Bowling alone: The collapse and revival of American community. New York: Simon and Schuster.
go back to reference Stolle, D. (1998). Bowling together, bowling alone: The development of generalized trust in voluntary associations. Political Psychology, 19, 497–526.CrossRef Stolle, D. (1998). Bowling together, bowling alone: The development of generalized trust in voluntary associations. Political Psychology, 19, 497–526.CrossRef
go back to reference Tabellini, G. (2010). Culture and institutions: Economic development in the region of Europe. Journal of the European Economic Association, 8, 677–716.CrossRef Tabellini, G. (2010). Culture and institutions: Economic development in the region of Europe. Journal of the European Economic Association, 8, 677–716.CrossRef
go back to reference Uslaner, E. M. (2002). The moral foundations of trust. UK: Cambridge University Press. Uslaner, E. M. (2002). The moral foundations of trust. UK: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Uslaner, E. M., & Brown, M. (2005). Inequality, trust, and civic engagement. American Politics Research, 33, 868–894.CrossRef Uslaner, E. M., & Brown, M. (2005). Inequality, trust, and civic engagement. American Politics Research, 33, 868–894.CrossRef
go back to reference Verba, S., Schlozman, K. L., & Brady, H. E. (1995). Voice and equality: Civic voluntarism in American politics. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRef Verba, S., Schlozman, K. L., & Brady, H. E. (1995). Voice and equality: Civic voluntarism in American politics. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Does Social Capital Affect Voter Turnout? Evidence from Italy
Authors
Nadia Fiorino
Emma Galli
Nicola Pontarollo
Publication date
28-02-2021
Publisher
Springer Netherlands
Published in
Social Indicators Research / Issue 1/2021
Print ISSN: 0303-8300
Electronic ISSN: 1573-0921
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-021-02642-6

Other articles of this Issue 1/2021

Social Indicators Research 1/2021 Go to the issue

Premium Partner