Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Social Choice and Welfare 3/2023

07-06-2023 | Original Paper

Strength in numbers: robust mechanisms for public goods with many agents

Authors: Jin Xi, Haitian Xie

Published in: Social Choice and Welfare | Issue 3/2023

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This study examines the mechanism design problem for public goods provision in a large economy with n independent agents. We propose a class of dominant-strategy incentive compatible and ex-post individually rational mechanisms, which we call the adjusted mean-thresholding (AMT) mechanisms. We show that when the cost of provision grows slower than the \(\sqrt{n}\)-rate, the AMT mechanisms are both eventually ex-ante budget balanced and asymptotically efficient. When the cost grows faster than the \(\sqrt{n}\)-rate, in contrast, we show that any incentive compatible, individually rational, and eventually ex-ante budget balanced mechanism must have provision probability converging to zero and hence cannot be asymptotically efficient. The AMT mechanisms have a simple form and are more informationally robust when compared to, for example, the second-best mechanism. This is because the construction of an AMT mechanism depends only on the first moment of the valuation distribution.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
Myerson and Satterthwaite (1983) establish the impossibility result in the bilateral trade setting, but it extends directly to the public goods problem. We provide a more substantial overview of this problem below.
 
2
For any measurable set E, we use \({\mathbf {1}}E\) to denote the indicator function of E.
 
3
The second-best mechanism maximizes welfare among the class of mechanisms that are incentive compatible, individually rational, and budget balance. We discuss more about the second-best mechanism in Sects. 1.1 and 2.
 
4
The central limit theorem states that the distribution of sum of iid random variables is approximately a normal distribution. The Berry-Esseen theorem further specifies how close the normal approximation is.
 
5
For example, it would be difficult to derive such a result based on the proof method in Hellwig (2003). We provide a discussion on this issue in Appendix B.
 
7
There is another notion of “large economy” in the literature that considers a continuum of agents and each agent is negligible compared to the population (Bierbrauer 2009, 2014; Bierbrauer and Hellwig 2015, 2016).
 
8
Hellwig (2003) also identifies the \(\sqrt{n}\)-rate in the context of Bayesian incentive compatibility. Our results are focused on the dominant-strategy incentive compatibility. One take-away here is that the weaker notion of Bayesian incentive compatibility does not relax this bound. This notion of equivalence between Bayesian incentive compatibility and dominant-strategy incentive compatibility represented by the requirement on the growth rate of cost can be seen as a complement to the theoretical results in Gershkov et al (2013).
 
9
This moment can come from any increasing and continuous transformation of the valuation. See Sect. 3.
 
10
In Sect. 3.3, we provide a more formal discussion of the qualitative difference between a moment and the distribution by using results in the information theory.
 
11
These papers examine the model of independent valuations. It is also possible to allow for correlated valuations while maintaining the moment restrictions on the marginal distributions. See Brooks and Du (2021); Zhang (2021).
 
12
Other works regarding the asymptotic efficiency of auctions in the independent private value setting include Swinkels (2001); Feldman et al (2016).
 
13
Other works on asymptotic approximation of the optimal revenue using robust auctions include Segal (2003), Neeman (2003), Goldberg et al (2006), Dhangwatnotai et al (2015). See also Hartline (2016, Chapter 5) for a comprehensive treatment of prior-independent mechanism design.
 
14
In Sect. 3, we discuss why the support is assumed to be in this form.
 
15
We can relax the assumptions that \({\bar{v}}\) is finite and that f is bounded away from zero. We only need to assume that the appropriate moments exist. However, that makes the exposition inconvenient.
 
16
In this paper, we use upper case letters to denote random variables and lower case letters to denote realizations or reported values.
 
17
We use the notion “budget balance” as in Kuzmics and Steg (2017) and Börgers (2015). It is also termed “feasible” or “subsidy-free” in the literature. Some literature uses the term “budget balance” to refer to the more stringent case where the total payment exactly equals the cost.
 
18
This definition of social welfare is standard in the literature. From the social planner’s perspective, the production cost does not enter into welfare because it does not directly affect agents’ utility. The cost only plays a role through the budget constraint.
 
19
See, for example, Myerson and Satterthwaite (1983) and Mailath and Postlewaite (1990).
 
20
The valuations explored in Kunimoto and Zhang (2021) are discrete. However, this aspect does not impact the results qualitatively, as both discrete and continuous distributions can be addressed using the general measure theory. Specifically, discrete probability measures have density functions with respect to the counting measure, enabling the computation of virtual valuations accordingly.
 
21
They refer to the “regret ratio” in this paper as “competitive ratio.”
 
22
This definition is equivalent to Definition 3.8 in Börgers (2015).
 
23
Since F is supported on \([0,{\bar{v}}]\), we have \(\int _{0}^{{\bar{v}}} (1-F(v)) dv = {\mathbb {E}}[V_i]\), \({\mathbb {E}}[\psi (V_i)] = {\mathbb {E}}[V_i] - \int _{0}^{{\bar{v}}} (1-F(v)) dv\) = 0. See the end of Sect. 3.2 for a discussion of the support.
 
24
See Eq. (12) and the discussion before it.
 
25
A similar intuition can be found in the proof of Proposition 3 in Hellwig (2003). Here, we provide a more detailed discussion regarding the rate of the threshold \(\alpha _n\).
 
26
However, we can extend our analysis to allow for a point mass at 0 in the distribution F. In that case, the density f is the Radon-Nykodim derivative of the probability measure F with respect to the measure \(L + \delta _0\), where L is the Lebesgue measure on \({\mathbb {R}}_+\) and \(\delta _0\) is the Dirac measure at 0. This underlying measure is \(\sigma\)-finite, and hence our analysis applies.
 
27
We are grateful to a referee for pointing this out.
 
28
For every random variable X and increasing functions \(g_1\) and \(g_2\), the random variables \(g_1(X)\) and \(g_2(X)\) are positively correlated (see, e.g., Thorisson 1995).
 
29
To see this, note that the definition of \(\psi\) implies \(d\log (1-F(v)) / dv = -1/(v-\psi (v))\).
 
30
See, for example, Stone (1980). If the density f is differentiable, then the optimal rate of convergence is \(m^{-1/3}\). Please refer to that paper for the exact definition of optimal convergence rates.
 
31
The optimal uniform convergence rate of density estimators is derived in Stone (1983).
 
32
To obtain a crude estimate, we can use Lemma 7 in the Appendix, which indicates that the expected total payment from the pivot mechanism is at most \(O\left( n^{1/4}\right)\). Therefore, the pivot mechanism runs a growing budget deficit if the cost grows faster than that rate.
 
33
Notice that, however, the cost cannot grow exactly at the \(\sqrt{n}\)-rate, because in that case we would need the adjustment term \(\alpha _n\) to also decrease at the \(\sqrt{n}\)-rate to balance the budget, leading to an inefficient allocation decision.
 
34
As we clarify in Appendix B, while the result in Hellwig (2003) are correct, the proof is slightly flawed. On the other hand, Kleinberg and Yuan (2013) only provide a heuristic (but informal) argument with the uniform distribution to explain why the optimal revenue grows at the \(\sqrt{n}\)-rate.
 
35
The nature of the assumption on the growth rate of \(c_n\) is essentially about the production technology and how the marginal cost decreases with the number of agents. See Roberts (1976) for a discussion on the relationship between the cost of a public good and the number of consumers.
 
36
The first five notations are standard. The expression \(d_n = O_\varepsilon (e_n)\) means that \(d_n\) is asymptotically bounded above by \(e_n\) divided by some (sufficiently small) power of n. The expression \(d_n = \omega _{\varepsilon }(e_n)\) means that \(d_n\) asymptotically dominates \(e_n\) divided by any power of n.
 
Literature
go back to reference Bierbrauer FJ, Hellwig MF (2015) Public good provision in large economies. In: Working paper, Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods Bierbrauer FJ, Hellwig MF (2015) Public good provision in large economies. In: Working paper, Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods
go back to reference Feldman M, Immorlica N, Lucier B, et al (2016) The price of anarchy in large games. In: Proceedings of the forty-eighth annual ACM symposium on theory of computing. Association for computing machinery, New York, STOC ’16, pp 963–976. https://doi.org/10.1145/2897518.2897580 Feldman M, Immorlica N, Lucier B, et al (2016) The price of anarchy in large games. In: Proceedings of the forty-eighth annual ACM symposium on theory of computing. Association for computing machinery, New York, STOC ’16, pp 963–976. https://​doi.​org/​10.​1145/​2897518.​2897580
go back to reference Gershkov A, Goeree JK, Kushnir A et al (2013) On the equivalence of bayesian and dominant strategy implementation. Econometrica 81(1):197–220CrossRef Gershkov A, Goeree JK, Kushnir A et al (2013) On the equivalence of bayesian and dominant strategy implementation. Econometrica 81(1):197–220CrossRef
go back to reference Kleinberg R, Yuan Y (2013) On the ratio of revenue to welfare in single-parameter mechanism design. In: Proceedings of the fourteenth ACM conference on electronic commerce. Association for computing machinery, New York, EC ’13, pp 589-602. https://doi.org/10.1145/2492002.2482584 Kleinberg R, Yuan Y (2013) On the ratio of revenue to welfare in single-parameter mechanism design. In: Proceedings of the fourteenth ACM conference on electronic commerce. Association for computing machinery, New York, EC ’13, pp 589-602. https://​doi.​org/​10.​1145/​2492002.​2482584
go back to reference Wilson R (1987) Game-theoretic analyses of trading processes. Advances in economic theory. Fifth world congress. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 33–70CrossRef Wilson R (1987) Game-theoretic analyses of trading processes. Advances in economic theory. Fifth world congress. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 33–70CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Strength in numbers: robust mechanisms for public goods with many agents
Authors
Jin Xi
Haitian Xie
Publication date
07-06-2023
Publisher
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Published in
Social Choice and Welfare / Issue 3/2023
Print ISSN: 0176-1714
Electronic ISSN: 1432-217X
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-023-01466-2

Other articles of this Issue 3/2023

Social Choice and Welfare 3/2023 Go to the issue

Premium Partner