Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Review of Industrial Organization 2/2020

03-06-2020

Technology Adoption, Vertical Coordination in Value Chains, and FDI in Developing Countries: Panel Evidence from the Dairy Sector in India (Punjab)

Authors: Saule Burkitbayeva, Emma Janssen, Johan Swinnen

Published in: Review of Industrial Organization | Issue 2/2020

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

(Global) value chains have contributed to agricultural technology adoption in transition countries and food export commodities in developing countries through various forms of vertical coordination, often associated with FDI. Adoption of modern technologies in agriculture is crucial for improving the productivity and welfare of poor farmers. Much less is known about how (global) value chains do (not) affect technology transfer and/or adoption in staple food chains in developing countries, and the role that FDI plays. Our paper analyses the role of value chains and FDI in farm-level technology adoption with the use of panel data from representative farm surveys in 2008 and 2015 (a period of rapid growth) in the dairy sector in India (Punjab). We find important increases in the adoption of some technologies among traditional and poor dairy farms. However, the role of vertical coordination in value chains in stimulating technology adoption among these traditional dairy farmers seems to be minor, both for domestic and for FDI companies. At the same time a sub-sector of dynamic modern dairy farms has emerged. These farms are much larger, use only modern technology, and are fully integrated in vertically coordinated value chains that support these modern farms’ management and investments.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
Explanations in the literature for the failure of technology adoption include imperfections in credit, information, and labor markets: access to credit and information (Banerjee and Duflo 2014; Bardhan and Udry 1991; Feder et al. 1985; Feder and Umali 1993); the importance of learning through social interactions or extension services (Cameron 1999; Munshi 2004; Bandiera and Rasul 2006; Conley and Udry 2010; Genius et al. 2013); and labor constraints (Moser and Barrett 2006). Another reason for the farmer to not adopt the technology is when there is uncertainty about whether this investment will be rewarded. One possibility is buyer holdup at the time of delivery (Klein et al. 1978). Examples are late payments, renegotiation of prices at product delivery, and the absence of transparent and reliable quality evaluation procedures (which could lead to inappropriately rejecting produce) (Barrett et al. 2012; Cungu et al. 2008; Saenger et al. 2014).
 
2
Such interlinked contracts are well known in the traditional development literature for basic input provisions (Bardhan 1989; Bell and Srinivasan 1989).
 
3
India has also used these arguments in trade negotiations—both within the World Trade Organization (Jha 2003) and in bilateral negotiations (Mondal et al. 2012)—to keep the dairy sector largely off the negotiation table (Goswami 2007).
 
4
This conceptual framework draws on the models developed in Vandemoortele et al. (2012), Swinnen et al. (2015) and Swinnen and Kuijpers (2019).
 
5
Here, we keep the definition of “technology” general. Later we consider different types of technology.
 
6
We ignore the possibility that there is a trade-off between quantity and quality. Such trade off may well exist for given technologies and for some technological innovations. However, many of the technologies that are relevant in our analysis increase both quantity and quality, or at least increase one without reducing the other.
 
7
See Swinnen and Vandeplas (2010) for more details.
 
8
Here, we assume that this sharing rule β is determined through ex-ante bargaining. Swinnen and Kuijpers (2019) show how the ex post division of surplus depends on contract enforcement and holdup opportunities.
 
9
Although side-selling by farmers potentially affects the occurrence of technology transfer in a slightly different way than technology diversion, it is conceptually similar (see Swinnen et al. 2015). We have not included this to reduce the complexity of the analysis. The extended analysis for side-selling can be obtained from the authors.
 
10
We relax this assumption in the section where we look at different types of technologies.
 
11
Note that in this model τ and V0 are “sunk” costs, which is why they do not directly show up in the buyer and farmer‘s payoffs. These costs will be reflected in the buyer and farmer‘s participation constraints.
 
12
Note that there may also be buyer hold-up of the contract. For example, the buyer may want to renegotiate the contract and refuse to pay the farmer the agreed share of the value at product delivery. Instead, he may offer to pay only as much as the farmer’s best alternative at that moment (e.g. the value of the produce when sold on the local market). We do not model this here and refer to Swinnen and Kuijpers (2019) for a formal analysis.
 
13
See, e.g., World Bank (2005) in transition countries and Maertens et al. (2011) in developing countries.
 
14
More formally, using parameter σ to represent the share of the gross surplus that is obtained in the contract period, the net surplus of technology adoption is \({\text{S}} =\upsigma\left( {{\text{V}}_{\uptau} - {\text{V}}_{0} } \right) -\uptau + \frac{{\upmu(1 - \sigma )}}{{1 +\updelta}}\left( {{\text{V}}_{\uptau} - {\text{V}}_{0} } \right):\) where μ represents the probability that the remaining gross surplus from the technology transfer is realized in the future (with 0 ≤ μ ≤ 1); and δ represents the discount rate. It follows that the surplus requires a larger value to be positive and grows slower with increasing value.
 
15
Our concept of “technology specificity” is obviously related to “asset specificity” in the transaction cost literature (e.g., Williamson 1985).
 
16
It was revealed that bottled water, milk and soft drinks contained dramatically high pesticide residue levels (Umali-Deininger and Sur 2007).
 
17
In 2006, Indian policy makers, pressured by civil society protests, drafted the Food Safety and Standards Act (FSSA). The Act determines which actor in the supply chain bears responsibility when food safety regulations are not complied with (Article 27 of FSSA 2006). For milk traders this implies that they are liable for any adulterants (e.g., water, oil, skimmed milk powder, soda) that is added to the milk, even if the responsibility for adulteration lies with their suppliers—unless they can specifically identify the culprit (Squicciarini and Vandeplas 2013). These regulations extend to informal traders including street hawkers and itinerant vendors. Opponents of the Act claim that poor street vendors will be unable to comply with the food standards that have been imposed. Despite the existence of the FSSA, a wide number of procedures, guidelines and mechanisms are yet to be framed by the Food Safety and Standards Authority of India (FSSAI).
 
18
Cross-breeding practices in India date back to mid 19th century (Sinha 1951). Cross-breeding on a large scale, however, began only in 1963 with the introduction of the Intensive Cattle Development Project (ICDP) as part of the Special Development programme during the Third Five-Year Plan period (Rao et al. 1995). Since then, the share of cross-bred cows in cattle milk production has been increasing steadily and reached 53% in 2011 (Kumar et al. 2013).
 
19
The north-west (Amritsar and Gurdaspur), the north-east (Hoshiarpur, Jalandhar, Kapurthala and Nawanshahar), the south-west (Bathinda, Faridkot, Ferozepur, Moga and Muktsar), the south-east (Mansa, Patiala, and Sangrur), and the central region (Fatehgarh Sahib, Ludhiana, and Ropar) (see Fig. 5).
 
20
Table 2 includes all dairy farmers in the sample. Table 10 in the Appendix shows the same table including only those dairy farms that had DA in both 2008 and 2015.
 
21
The index of hygienic practices is the average of the compliance levels for various sanitary practice indicators before and during milking which are demonstrated in Table 4.
 
22
Figures 7, 8, 10, and 12 include all dairy farmers in the sample. Figures 13, 14, 15 and 16 in the Appendix show the same graphs but include only those dairy farms that had DA in both 2008 and 2015.
 
23
In our survey, following Janssen and Swinnen (2019), we distinguished among four different types of concentrate feed: (a) grains and grain bran; (b) oilseeds and oilcakes; (c) mixed concentrated feed; and d) other concentrates, which includes salts and mineral mixtures. While grains, oilseeds/oilcakes, and salts/mineral mixtures are all part of a balanced diet, the mixed concentrates usually contain all these elements and are therefore the best indicator of whether a dairy farm has adopted enhanced feeding practices. In Punjab, different types of mixed concentrated feed can be found: First, branded pre-mixed feed with different compositions that are combined in such way that fulfill the requirements of different types of animals (cross-bred/desi) as well as match the status of the DA (pregnant, in milk, dry) can be purchased (if available). Second, there is unbranded pre-mixed feed with varying composition. The survey data does not allow us to distinguish between these two types of concentrated feed, so they are both classified as mixed feed. Finally, some dairy farmers also mix their own concentrates, although this is done by only a small minority in our sample.
 
24
Note that the provision of monetary funds in formal value chains is not provided by the processing firm themselves but rather by the managers of the collection centers who act like money lenders.
 
25
To verify that the Fixed Effects model is appropriate, we conduct the following steps: First we perform a Hausman test to decide between a FE and a Random Effects (RE) model. Next, we check if the assumption of strict exogeneity of explanatory variables holds by comparing outcomes of FE and first difference estimators (FD). The two estimators yield similar results, which means that explanatory variables do not correlate with past, current and future error terms. In short, the results showed that the FE model is preferred for studying both the adoption of improved hygienic practices and of cross-bred cows. The different models are presented in Tables 11 and 12 in the Appendix.
 
26
There exists no consensus on the econometric technique that should be used to estimate a model with a binary dependent variable in a panel setting. We follow Angrist and Pischke (2009) in using a Linear Probability Model. The LPM offers econometric advantages over a logit model when running estimations on panel data as using a logit model in this setting will give rise to the incidental parameter problem and lead to inconsistent parameter estimation, especially when T is small. However, as a robustness check, we estimate: (i) a probit model with FE and (ii) a correlated random effects probit model that was proposed by Mundlak (1978). This correlated random effects model relaxes the strong assumption of RE models that time-invariant unobserved heterogeneity is not correlated with the independent variables. Concretely, time averages of the time-varying explanatory variables are added for each dairy farm as a set of controls. As such, we are estimating the effect of changes in the time-varying explanatory variables while keeping the time average fixed (Wooldridge 2004). The results for all three models are similar and can be found in the Appendix Table 13.
 
Literature
go back to reference Angrist, J. D., & Pischke, J. S. (2009). Mostly harmless econometrics: An empiricist’s companion. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Angrist, J. D., & Pischke, J. S. (2009). Mostly harmless econometrics: An empiricist’s companion. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Bandiera, O., & Rasul, I. (2006). Social networks and technology adoption in Northern Mozambique. The Economic Journal, 116(514), 869–902. Bandiera, O., & Rasul, I. (2006). Social networks and technology adoption in Northern Mozambique. The Economic Journal, 116(514), 869–902.
go back to reference Banerjee, A. V., & Duflo, E. (2014). Do firms want to borrow more? Testing credit constraints using a directed lending program. The Review of Economic Studies, 81(2), 572–607. Banerjee, A. V., & Duflo, E. (2014). Do firms want to borrow more? Testing credit constraints using a directed lending program. The Review of Economic Studies, 81(2), 572–607.
go back to reference Bardhan, P. (1989). The economic theory of agrarian institutions clarendon. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Bardhan, P. (1989). The economic theory of agrarian institutions clarendon. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Bardhan, P., & Udry, C. (1991). Development microeconomics. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Bardhan, P., & Udry, C. (1991). Development microeconomics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Barrett, C. B., Maren, E. B., Bellemare, M. F., Michelson, H. C., Narayanan, S., & Walker, T. F. (2012). Smallholder participation in contract farming: Comparative evidence from five countries. World Development, 40(4), 715–730. Barrett, C. B., Maren, E. B., Bellemare, M. F., Michelson, H. C., Narayanan, S., & Walker, T. F. (2012). Smallholder participation in contract farming: Comparative evidence from five countries. World Development, 40(4), 715–730.
go back to reference Bell, C., & Srinivasan, T. N. (1989). Interlinked transactions in rural markets: An empirical study of Andhra Pradesh, Bihar and Punjab. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 51(1), 73–83. Bell, C., & Srinivasan, T. N. (1989). Interlinked transactions in rural markets: An empirical study of Andhra Pradesh, Bihar and Punjab. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 51(1), 73–83.
go back to reference Bellemare, M. F. (2012). As you sow, so shall you reap: The welfare impacts of contract farming. World Development, 40(7), 1418–1434. Bellemare, M. F. (2012). As you sow, so shall you reap: The welfare impacts of contract farming. World Development, 40(7), 1418–1434.
go back to reference Birthal, P. S., Chand, R., Joshi, P. K., Saxena, R., Rajkhowa, P., Khan, M. T., et al. (2017). Formal versus informal: Efficiency, inclusiveness and financing of dairy value chains in Indian Punjab. Journal of rural studies, 54, 288–303. Birthal, P. S., Chand, R., Joshi, P. K., Saxena, R., Rajkhowa, P., Khan, M. T., et al. (2017). Formal versus informal: Efficiency, inclusiveness and financing of dairy value chains in Indian Punjab. Journal of rural studies, 54, 288–303.
go back to reference Birthal, P. S., & Jha, A. K. (2005). Review on emerging trends in India’s livestock economy: Implications for development policy. The Indian Journal of Animal Sciences, 75(10), 1227–1232. Birthal, P. S., & Jha, A. K. (2005). Review on emerging trends in India’s livestock economy: Implications for development policy. The Indian Journal of Animal Sciences, 75(10), 1227–1232.
go back to reference Bolwig, S., Gibbon, P., & Jones, S. (2009). The economics of smallholder organic contract farming in tropical Africa. World Development, 37(6), 1094–1104. Bolwig, S., Gibbon, P., & Jones, S. (2009). The economics of smallholder organic contract farming in tropical Africa. World Development, 37(6), 1094–1104.
go back to reference CAG. (2017). Performance audit on implementation of food safety and standards act. Report No.37 of 2017, Union Government. CAG. (2017). Performance audit on implementation of food safety and standards act. Report No.37 of 2017, Union Government.
go back to reference Cameron, L. A. (1999). The importance of learning in the adoption of high-yielding variety seeds. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 81(1), 83–94. Cameron, L. A. (1999). The importance of learning in the adoption of high-yielding variety seeds. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 81(1), 83–94.
go back to reference Chand, R. (1999). Emerging crisis in Punjab agriculture: Severity and options for future. Economic and Political Weekly, 34(13), A2–A10. Chand, R. (1999). Emerging crisis in Punjab agriculture: Severity and options for future. Economic and Political Weekly, 34(13), A2–A10.
go back to reference Conley, T. G., & Udry, C. R. (2010). Learning about a new technology: Pineapple in Ghana. The American Economic Review, 100(1), 35–69. Conley, T. G., & Udry, C. R. (2010). Learning about a new technology: Pineapple in Ghana. The American Economic Review, 100(1), 35–69.
go back to reference Cungu, A., Gow, H., Swinnen, J. F. M., & Vranken, L. (2008). Investment with weak contract enforcement: Evidence from Hungary during transition. European Review of Agricultural Economic, 35(1), 75–91. Cungu, A., Gow, H., Swinnen, J. F. M., & Vranken, L. (2008). Investment with weak contract enforcement: Evidence from Hungary during transition. European Review of Agricultural Economic, 35(1), 75–91.
go back to reference Cunningham, K. (2010). Rural and urban linkages: Operation flood’s role in India’s dairy development. IFPRI discussion paper 00924. Cunningham, K. (2010). Rural and urban linkages: Operation flood’s role in India’s dairy development. IFPRI discussion paper 00924.
go back to reference Dries, L., Germenji, E., Noev, N., & Swinnen, J. F. M. (2009). Farmers, vertical coordination, and the restructuring of dairy supply chains in Central and Eastern Europe. World Development, 37(11), 1742–1758. Dries, L., Germenji, E., Noev, N., & Swinnen, J. F. M. (2009). Farmers, vertical coordination, and the restructuring of dairy supply chains in Central and Eastern Europe. World Development, 37(11), 1742–1758.
go back to reference Dries, L., & Swinnen, J. F. M. (2004). Foreign direct investment, vertical integration, and local suppliers: Evidence from the Polish dairy sector. World Development, 32(9), 1525–1544. Dries, L., & Swinnen, J. F. M. (2004). Foreign direct investment, vertical integration, and local suppliers: Evidence from the Polish dairy sector. World Development, 32(9), 1525–1544.
go back to reference Evenson, R. E., & Gollin, D. (2003). Assessing the impact of the Green Revolution, 1960 to 2000. Science, 300(5620), 758–762. Evenson, R. E., & Gollin, D. (2003). Assessing the impact of the Green Revolution, 1960 to 2000. Science, 300(5620), 758–762.
go back to reference FAO (2010). Status of and prospects for smallholder milk production—A global perspective, by T.Hemme and J. Otte. Rome FAO (2010). Status of and prospects for smallholder milk productionA global perspective, by T.Hemme and J. Otte. Rome
go back to reference FAO. (2012). Balanced feeding for improving livestock productivity—Increase in milk production and nutrient use efficiency and decrease in methane emission, by M.R. Garg. FAO Animal Production and Health Paper No. 173. Rome, Italy. FAO. (2012). Balanced feeding for improving livestock productivityIncrease in milk production and nutrient use efficiency and decrease in methane emission, by M.R. Garg. FAO Animal Production and Health Paper No. 173. Rome, Italy.
go back to reference Feder, G., Just, R. E., & Zilberman, D. (1985). Adoption of agricultural innovations in developing countries: A survey. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 33(2), 255–298. Feder, G., Just, R. E., & Zilberman, D. (1985). Adoption of agricultural innovations in developing countries: A survey. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 33(2), 255–298.
go back to reference Feder, G., & Umali, D. (1993). The adoption of agricultural innovations: A review. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 43(3–4), 215–239. Feder, G., & Umali, D. (1993). The adoption of agricultural innovations: A review. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 43(3–4), 215–239.
go back to reference Genius, M., Koundouri, P., Nauges, C., & Tzouvelekas, V. (2013). Information transmission in irrigation technology adoption and diffusion: Social learning, extension services and spatial effects. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 96(1), 328–344. Genius, M., Koundouri, P., Nauges, C., & Tzouvelekas, V. (2013). Information transmission in irrigation technology adoption and diffusion: Social learning, extension services and spatial effects. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 96(1), 328–344.
go back to reference Goswami, B. (2007). Can Indian dairy cooperatives survive in the new economic order? Paper presented at the WTO Public Forum “How can the WTO help harness globalization”. Geneva, Switzerland. Goswami, B. (2007). Can Indian dairy cooperatives survive in the new economic order? Paper presented at the WTO Public Forum “How can the WTO help harness globalization”. Geneva, Switzerland.
go back to reference Gow, H. R., Streeter, D. H., & Swinnen, J. F. M. (2000). How private contract enforcement mechanisms can succeed where public institutions fail: The Case of Juhocukor A.S. Agricultural Economics, 23(3), 253–265. Gow, H. R., Streeter, D. H., & Swinnen, J. F. M. (2000). How private contract enforcement mechanisms can succeed where public institutions fail: The Case of Juhocukor A.S. Agricultural Economics, 23(3), 253–265.
go back to reference Gow, H. R., & Swinnen, J. F. M. (2001). Private enforcement capital and contract enforcement in transition economies. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 83(3), 686–690. Gow, H. R., & Swinnen, J. F. M. (2001). Private enforcement capital and contract enforcement in transition economies. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 83(3), 686–690.
go back to reference Janssen, E., & Swinnen, J. F. M. (2019). Technology adoption and value chains in developing countries: Evidence from dairy in India. Food Policy, 83, 327–336. Janssen, E., & Swinnen, J. F. M. (2019). Technology adoption and value chains in developing countries: Evidence from dairy in India. Food Policy, 83, 327–336.
go back to reference Jha, B. (2003). India’s dairy sector in the emerging trade order. IEG Working Paper E/243/2004. Jha, B. (2003). India’s dairy sector in the emerging trade order. IEG Working Paper E/243/2004.
go back to reference Jones, S., & Gibbon, P. (2011). Developing Agricultural markets in sub-Saharan Africa: Organic cocoa in rural Uganda. Journal of Development Studies, 47(10), 1595–1618. Jones, S., & Gibbon, P. (2011). Developing Agricultural markets in sub-Saharan Africa: Organic cocoa in rural Uganda. Journal of Development Studies, 47(10), 1595–1618.
go back to reference Klein, B., Robert, G. C., & Alchian, A. A. (1978). Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process. The Journal of Law and Economics, 21(2), 297–326. Klein, B., Robert, G. C., & Alchian, A. A. (1978). Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process. The Journal of Law and Economics, 21(2), 297–326.
go back to reference Kuijpers, R., & Swinnen, J. F. M. (2016). Value chains and technology transfer to agriculture in developing and emerging economies. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 98, 1403–1418. Kuijpers, R., & Swinnen, J. F. M. (2016). Value chains and technology transfer to agriculture in developing and emerging economies. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 98, 1403–1418.
go back to reference Kumar, A., Joshi, P. K., Kumar, P., & Parappurathu, S. (2014). Trends in the consumption of milk and milk products in India: Implications for self-sufficiency in milk production. Food Security, 6(5), 719. Kumar, A., Joshi, P. K., Kumar, P., & Parappurathu, S. (2014). Trends in the consumption of milk and milk products in India: Implications for self-sufficiency in milk production. Food Security, 6(5), 719.
go back to reference Kumar, A., Parappurathu, S., & Joshi, P. K. (2013). Structural transformation in dairy sector of India. Agricultural Economics Research Review, 26(2), 209–2019. Kumar, A., Parappurathu, S., & Joshi, P. K. (2013). Structural transformation in dairy sector of India. Agricultural Economics Research Review, 26(2), 209–2019.
go back to reference Kumar, A., Roy, D., Joshi, P. K., Tripathi, G. & Adhikari, R. P. (2016). Impact of contract farming on profits and yield of smallholder farms in Nepal: An evidence from lentil cultivation. Annual meeting, July 31–August 2, 2016, Boston, Massachusetts. Agricultural and Applied Economics Association. Kumar, A., Roy, D., Joshi, P. K., Tripathi, G. & Adhikari, R. P. (2016). Impact of contract farming on profits and yield of smallholder farms in Nepal: An evidence from lentil cultivation. Annual meeting, July 31–August 2, 2016, Boston, Massachusetts. Agricultural and Applied Economics Association.
go back to reference Kumar, A., Wright, I. A., & Singh, D. K. (2011). Adoption of food safety practices in milk production: Implications for dairy farmers in India. Journal of International Food & Agribusiness Marketing, 23(4), 330–344. Kumar, A., Wright, I. A., & Singh, D. K. (2011). Adoption of food safety practices in milk production: Implications for dairy farmers in India. Journal of International Food & Agribusiness Marketing, 23(4), 330–344.
go back to reference Maertens, M., Colen, L., & Swinnen, J. F. M. (2011). Globalisation and poverty in senegal: A worst case scenario? European Review of Agricultural Economics, 38(1), 31–54. Maertens, M., Colen, L., & Swinnen, J. F. M. (2011). Globalisation and poverty in senegal: A worst case scenario? European Review of Agricultural Economics, 38(1), 31–54.
go back to reference Maertens, M., & Swinnen, J. F. M. (2009). Trade, standards, and poverty: Evidence from Senegal. World Development, 37(1), 161–178. Maertens, M., & Swinnen, J. F. M. (2009). Trade, standards, and poverty: Evidence from Senegal. World Development, 37(1), 161–178.
go back to reference Maertens, M., & Vande Velde, K. (2017). Contract-farming in staple food chains: The case of rice in Benin. World Development, 95, 73–87. Maertens, M., & Vande Velde, K. (2017). Contract-farming in staple food chains: The case of rice in Benin. World Development, 95, 73–87.
go back to reference Minten, B., & Reardon, T. (2008). Food prices, quality, and quality’s pricing in supermarkets vs traditional markets in developing countries. Review of Agricultural Economics, 30(3), 480–490. Minten, B., & Reardon, T. (2008). Food prices, quality, and quality’s pricing in supermarkets vs traditional markets in developing countries. Review of Agricultural Economics, 30(3), 480–490.
go back to reference Minten, B., Reardon, T. & Vandeplas, A. (2009). Linking urban consumers and rural farmers in India: A comparison of traditional and modern food supply chains. IFPRI discussion papers 883. International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI). Minten, B., Reardon, T. & Vandeplas, A. (2009). Linking urban consumers and rural farmers in India: A comparison of traditional and modern food supply chains. IFPRI discussion papers 883. International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI).
go back to reference Minten, B., Tamru, S., Engida, E., & Kuma, T. (2016). Transforming staple food value chains in Africa: The case of teff in Ethiopia. The Journal of Development Studies, 52(5), 627–645. Minten, B., Tamru, S., Engida, E., & Kuma, T. (2016). Transforming staple food value chains in Africa: The case of teff in Ethiopia. The Journal of Development Studies, 52(5), 627–645.
go back to reference Mo, D., Huang, J., Jia, X., Luan, H., Rozelle, S., & Swinnen, J. F. M. (2012). Checking into China’s cow hotels: Have policies following the milk scandal changed the structure of the dairy sector? Journal of Dairy Science, 95(5), 2282–2298. Mo, D., Huang, J., Jia, X., Luan, H., Rozelle, S., & Swinnen, J. F. M. (2012). Checking into China’s cow hotels: Have policies following the milk scandal changed the structure of the dairy sector? Journal of Dairy Science, 95(5), 2282–2298.
go back to reference Mondal, B., Sirohi, S. & Thorat, V. (2012). Impact of ASEAN-India free trade agreement on Indian dairy trade: A quantitative approach. MPRA working paper 40790. Mondal, B., Sirohi, S. & Thorat, V. (2012). Impact of ASEAN-India free trade agreement on Indian dairy trade: A quantitative approach. MPRA working paper 40790.
go back to reference Moser, C. M., & Barrett, C. B. (2006). The Complex dynamics of smallholder technology adoption: The case of SRI in Madagascar. Agricultural Economics, 35(3), 373–388. Moser, C. M., & Barrett, C. B. (2006). The Complex dynamics of smallholder technology adoption: The case of SRI in Madagascar. Agricultural Economics, 35(3), 373–388.
go back to reference Mundlak, Y. (1978). On the pooling of time series and cross section data. Econometrica, 46, 69–85. Mundlak, Y. (1978). On the pooling of time series and cross section data. Econometrica, 46, 69–85.
go back to reference Munshi, K. (2004). Social learning in a heterogeneous population: Technology diffusion in the Indian Green Revolution. Journal of Development Economics, 73(1), 185–213. Munshi, K. (2004). Social learning in a heterogeneous population: Technology diffusion in the Indian Green Revolution. Journal of Development Economics, 73(1), 185–213.
go back to reference Nagrale, B. G., Datta, K. K., & Chauhan, A. K. (2015). An analysis of constraints faced by dairy farmers in Vidarbha region of Maharashtra. Indian Journal of Dairy Science, 68(4), 390–394. Nagrale, B. G., Datta, K. K., & Chauhan, A. K. (2015). An analysis of constraints faced by dairy farmers in Vidarbha region of Maharashtra. Indian Journal of Dairy Science, 68(4), 390–394.
go back to reference Rao, S. V. N., Venkatasubramanian, V., & De Wit, J. (1995). Consequences of crossbreeding programme in India. Economic and Political Weekly, 30(39), A112–A116. Rao, S. V. N., Venkatasubramanian, V., & De Wit, J. (1995). Consequences of crossbreeding programme in India. Economic and Political Weekly, 30(39), A112–A116.
go back to reference Reardon, T., Barrett, C. B., Berdegue, J. A., & Swinnen, J. F. M. (2009). Agrifood industry transformation and small farmers in developing countries. World Development, 37(11), 1717–1727. Reardon, T., Barrett, C. B., Berdegue, J. A., & Swinnen, J. F. M. (2009). Agrifood industry transformation and small farmers in developing countries. World Development, 37(11), 1717–1727.
go back to reference Reardon, T., & Timmer, C. P. (2014). Five Inter-linked transformations in the Asian agrifood economy: Food security implications. Global Food Security, 3(2), 108–117. Reardon, T., & Timmer, C. P. (2014). Five Inter-linked transformations in the Asian agrifood economy: Food security implications. Global Food Security, 3(2), 108–117.
go back to reference Saenger, C., Maximo, T., & Qaim, M. (2014). Impact of third-party contract enforcement in agricultural markets—A field experiment in Vietnam. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 96(4), 1220–1238. Saenger, C., Maximo, T., & Qaim, M. (2014). Impact of third-party contract enforcement in agricultural markets—A field experiment in Vietnam. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 96(4), 1220–1238.
go back to reference Sheahan, M., & Barrett, C. B. (2014). Understanding the agricultural input landscape in sub-Saharan Africa: Recent plot, household, and community-level evidence. The World Bank. Sheahan, M., & Barrett, C. B. (2014). Understanding the agricultural input landscape in sub-Saharan Africa: Recent plot, household, and community-level evidence. The World Bank.
go back to reference Sinha, B. N. (1951). Taylor cows of Patna. Indian Veterinary Journal, 27, 272–276. Sinha, B. N. (1951). Taylor cows of Patna. Indian Veterinary Journal, 27, 272–276.
go back to reference Squicciarini, M., & Vandeplas, A. (2010). The dairy sector of Andhra Pradesh: Findings from a company survey. No. TAPSIM deliverable D5.3, LICOS, KU Leuven, Belgium. Squicciarini, M., & Vandeplas, A. (2010). The dairy sector of Andhra Pradesh: Findings from a company survey. No. TAPSIM deliverable D5.3, LICOS, KU Leuven, Belgium.
go back to reference Squicciarini, M., & Vandeplas, A. (2013). Food safety standards for domestic and international markets: The case of dairy. In F. Brouwer & P. K. Joshi (Eds.), International trade and poverty; the future of Indian agriculture. Oxfordshire: CABI Publications. Squicciarini, M., & Vandeplas, A. (2013). Food safety standards for domestic and international markets: The case of dairy. In F. Brouwer & P. K. Joshi (Eds.), International trade and poverty; the future of Indian agriculture. Oxfordshire: CABI Publications.
go back to reference Staal, S. J., Nin Pratt, A. & Jabbar, M. (2008). Dairy development for the resource poor. Part 3: Pakistan and India Dairy Development Case Studies. PPLPI Working paper No.44-3. International Livestock Research Institute and Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations. Staal, S. J., Nin Pratt, A. & Jabbar, M. (2008). Dairy development for the resource poor. Part 3: Pakistan and India Dairy Development Case Studies. PPLPI Working paper No.44-3. International Livestock Research Institute and Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations.
go back to reference Swinnen, J. F. M., Deconinck, K., Vandemoortele, T., & Vandeplas, A. (2015). Quality standards, value chains and international development. New York: Cambridge University Press. Swinnen, J. F. M., Deconinck, K., Vandemoortele, T., & Vandeplas, A. (2015). Quality standards, value chains and international development. New York: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Swinnen, J., & Kuijpers, R. (2019). Value chain innovations for technology transfer in developing and emerging economies: Conceptual issues, typology, and policy implications. Food Policy, 83, 298–309. Swinnen, J., & Kuijpers, R. (2019). Value chain innovations for technology transfer in developing and emerging economies: Conceptual issues, typology, and policy implications. Food Policy, 83, 298–309.
go back to reference Swinnen, J. F., & Vandeplas, A. (2010). Market power and rents in global supply chains. Agricultural Economics, 41, 109–120. Swinnen, J. F., & Vandeplas, A. (2010). Market power and rents in global supply chains. Agricultural Economics, 41, 109–120.
go back to reference Umali-Deininger, D., & Sur, M. (2007). Food safety in a globalizing world: Opportunities and challenges for India. Agricultural Economics, 37(s1), 135–147. Umali-Deininger, D., & Sur, M. (2007). Food safety in a globalizing world: Opportunities and challenges for India. Agricultural Economics, 37(s1), 135–147.
go back to reference Van Campenhout, B., Minten, B., & Swinnen, J. (2019). Domestic versus export-led agricultural transformation: Evidence from Uganda’s dairy value chain. IFPRI Discussion Paper 1883 Van Campenhout, B., Minten, B., & Swinnen, J. (2019). Domestic versus export-led agricultural transformation: Evidence from Uganda’s dairy value chain. IFPRI Discussion Paper 1883
go back to reference Van Herck, K., Swinnen, J. F. M., & Deconinck, K. (2012). How the east was won: Supply chain restructuring in the Eastern European beer market. German Journal of Agricultural Economics, 61(670-2016-45941), 213–222. Van Herck, K., Swinnen, J. F. M., & Deconinck, K. (2012). How the east was won: Supply chain restructuring in the Eastern European beer market. German Journal of Agricultural Economics, 61(670-2016-45941), 213–222.
go back to reference Vandemoortele, T., Rozelle, S., Swinnen, J., & Xiang, T. (2012). Quality and inclusion of producers in value chains: a theoretical note. Review of Development Economics, 16(1), 122–136. Vandemoortele, T., Rozelle, S., Swinnen, J., & Xiang, T. (2012). Quality and inclusion of producers in value chains: a theoretical note. Review of Development Economics, 16(1), 122–136.
go back to reference Vandeplas, A., Minten, B., & Swinnen, J. F. M. (2013). Multinationals vs cooperatives: The income and efficiency effects of supply chain governance in India. Journal of Agricultural Economics, 64(1), 217–244. Vandeplas, A., Minten, B., & Swinnen, J. F. M. (2013). Multinationals vs cooperatives: The income and efficiency effects of supply chain governance in India. Journal of Agricultural Economics, 64(1), 217–244.
go back to reference Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Simon and Schuster. Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Simon and Schuster.
go back to reference Wooldridge, J. M. (2004). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. London: The MIT Press. Wooldridge, J. M. (2004). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. London: The MIT Press.
go back to reference World Bank. (2005). The dynamics of vertical coordination in agrifood chains in Eastern Europe and Central Asia. Washington, DC: World Bank. World Bank. (2005). The dynamics of vertical coordination in agrifood chains in Eastern Europe and Central Asia. Washington, DC: World Bank.
go back to reference Zilberman, D., Lu, L., & Reardon, T. (2019). Innovation-induced food supply chain design. Food Policy, 83, 289–297. Zilberman, D., Lu, L., & Reardon, T. (2019). Innovation-induced food supply chain design. Food Policy, 83, 289–297.
Metadata
Title
Technology Adoption, Vertical Coordination in Value Chains, and FDI in Developing Countries: Panel Evidence from the Dairy Sector in India (Punjab)
Authors
Saule Burkitbayeva
Emma Janssen
Johan Swinnen
Publication date
03-06-2020
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Review of Industrial Organization / Issue 2/2020
Print ISSN: 0889-938X
Electronic ISSN: 1573-7160
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-020-09763-1

Other articles of this Issue 2/2020

Review of Industrial Organization 2/2020 Go to the issue