Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Review of Industrial Organization 2/2020

11-06-2020

The Gravity of Intermediate Goods

Authors: Paola Conconi, Glenn Magerman, Afrola Plaku

Published in: Review of Industrial Organization | Issue 2/2020

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

One of the puzzles of the gravity literature is the persistent effect of distance on trade flows, despite the dramatic fall in trade costs during the last few decades (Disdier and Head in Rev Econ Stat 90(1):37–48, 2008). A possible reason for the “distance puzzle” is that trade in intermediate goods—which has risen dramatically during this period due to the emergence of global value chains—may be more sensitive to distance than trade in final goods. Using a dataset of bilateral import flows that covers 5000 products and more than 200 countries over the 1998–2011 period, we show that intermediate goods are indeed more sensitive to distance than are final goods and that differentiated inputs exhibit the highest distance elasticity. The results are robust to including different sets of controls, and using different samples and econometric methodologies. They suggest that sourcing inputs from nearby countries helps final good producers to coordinate with their suppliers, monitor their production, and ensure the timely delivery of inputs that need to be tailored to their needs.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Footnotes
1
Our analysis builds on earlier studies that have estimated gravity regressions at the product or sectoral level (e.g., Anderson and Yotov 2010; Imbs and Mejean 2017).
 
2
Final goods thus comprise both capital and consumption goods. We drop from our analysis those goods that are considered “mixed’ in the BEC classification.
 
4
From Eq. (1), the effect of intermediates on imports is \(\frac{\partial ln (\textit{Imports}_{ijk})}{\textit{Intermediate}_k} = \beta _1 \times ln{(Distance)}_{ij} + \beta _2\). It is straightforward to verify that this effect becomes negative when the distance between countries i and j is above a certain threshold. In the specification of column 1 of Table 2, this threshold is around 2500 km, implying that countries that are further apart trade more in final goods than in intermediate goods.
 
5
Raw materials correspond to 575 HS6 codes in our sample. Of these, 379 are intermediate goods: some are homogeneous (e.g., oil, fertilizers, copper), while others are differentiated (e.g., glass containers, live animals, plants and parts, including seeds and fruits). The remaining products are final goods: some are homogeneous (e.g., frozen fish fillets, frozen shrimps and prawns), while others are differentiated (e.g., fish meat, mackerel).
 
6
For example, if we included zeros in column 1 of Table 8, they would account for almost 98% of the sample (the number of observations would increase from 4,785,880 to 222,746,370). We have nevertheless tried to reproduce Tables 8, 9 and 10, with the inclusion of zeros in the dependent variable. The results confirm that intermediate goods are more sensitive to distance than are final goods—particularly when eliminating raw materials. However, the role of product differentiation is less clear-cut (intermediate goods are more sensitive to distance than only two of the three other categories of products).
 
Literature
go back to reference Alfaro, L., Antràs, P., Conconi, P., & Chor, D. (2019). Internalizing global value chains: A firm-level analysis. Journal of Political Economy, 127(2), 508–559.CrossRef Alfaro, L., Antràs, P., Conconi, P., & Chor, D. (2019). Internalizing global value chains: A firm-level analysis. Journal of Political Economy, 127(2), 508–559.CrossRef
go back to reference Amiti, M., & Konings, J. (2007). Trade liberalization, intermediate inputs, and productivity: Evidence from Indonesia. American Economic Review, 97(5), 1611–1638.CrossRef Amiti, M., & Konings, J. (2007). Trade liberalization, intermediate inputs, and productivity: Evidence from Indonesia. American Economic Review, 97(5), 1611–1638.CrossRef
go back to reference Anderson, J. E., & Yotov, Y. (2010). The changing incidence of geography. American Economic Review, 100(5), 2157–2186.CrossRef Anderson, J. E., & Yotov, Y. (2010). The changing incidence of geography. American Economic Review, 100(5), 2157–2186.CrossRef
go back to reference Antràs, P. (2016). Global production: Firms, contracts and trade structure. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRef Antràs, P. (2016). Global production: Firms, contracts and trade structure. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Antràs, P., & Chor, D. (2013). Organizing the global value chain. Econometrica, 81(6), 2127–2204.CrossRef Antràs, P., & Chor, D. (2013). Organizing the global value chain. Econometrica, 81(6), 2127–2204.CrossRef
go back to reference Antràs, P., Fort, T. C., & Tintelnot, F. (2017). The margins of global sourcing: Theory and evidence from US firms. American Economic Review, 107(9), 2514–64.CrossRef Antràs, P., Fort, T. C., & Tintelnot, F. (2017). The margins of global sourcing: Theory and evidence from US firms. American Economic Review, 107(9), 2514–64.CrossRef
go back to reference Baldwin, R. (2013). Global supply chains: Why they emerged, why they matter, and where they are going. In D. K. Elms & P. Low (Eds.), Global value chains in a changing world. World Trade Organization. Baldwin, R. (2013). Global supply chains: Why they emerged, why they matter, and where they are going. In D. K. Elms & P. Low (Eds.), Global value chains in a changing world. World Trade Organization.
go back to reference Baldwin, R., & Taglioni, D. (2011). Gravity chains: Estimating bilateral trade flows when parts and components trade is important. NBER Working Paper No. 16672. Baldwin, R., & Taglioni, D. (2011). Gravity chains: Estimating bilateral trade flows when parts and components trade is important. NBER Working Paper No. 16672.
go back to reference Bergstrand, J., & Egger, P. (2010). A general equilibrium theory for estimating gravity equations of bilateral FDI, final goods trade and intermediate goods trade. In S. Brakman & P. Van Bergeijk (Eds.), The gravity model in international trade: Advances and applications. New York: Cambridge University Press. Bergstrand, J., & Egger, P. (2010). A general equilibrium theory for estimating gravity equations of bilateral FDI, final goods trade and intermediate goods trade. In S. Brakman & P. Van Bergeijk (Eds.), The gravity model in international trade: Advances and applications. New York: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Bernard, A. B., Jensen, J. B., Redding, S. J., & Schott, P. K. (2007). Firms in international trade. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21(3), 105–130.CrossRef Bernard, A. B., Jensen, J. B., Redding, S. J., & Schott, P. K. (2007). Firms in international trade. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21(3), 105–130.CrossRef
go back to reference Berthelon, M., & Freund, C., (2004). On the conservation of distance in international trade. Journal of International Economics, 75(2), 310–320.CrossRef Berthelon, M., & Freund, C., (2004). On the conservation of distance in international trade. Journal of International Economics, 75(2), 310–320.CrossRef
go back to reference Blaum, J., Lelarge, C., & Peters, M. (2018). The gains from input trade with heterogeneous importers. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 10(4), 77–127. Blaum, J., Lelarge, C., & Peters, M. (2018). The gains from input trade with heterogeneous importers. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 10(4), 77–127.
go back to reference Cairncross, F. (1997). The death of distance: How the communications revolution will change our lives. London: Orion Business Books. Cairncross, F. (1997). The death of distance: How the communications revolution will change our lives. London: Orion Business Books.
go back to reference Combes, P.-P., Mayer, T., & Thisse, J.-F. (2008). Economic geography: The integration of regions and nations. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRef Combes, P.-P., Mayer, T., & Thisse, J.-F. (2008). Economic geography: The integration of regions and nations. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Conconi, P., Garcìa-Santana, M., Puccio, L., & Venturini, R. (2018). From final goods to inputs: The protectionist effect of rules of origin. American Economic Review, 108(8), 2335–2365.CrossRef Conconi, P., Garcìa-Santana, M., Puccio, L., & Venturini, R. (2018). From final goods to inputs: The protectionist effect of rules of origin. American Economic Review, 108(8), 2335–2365.CrossRef
go back to reference Disdier, A.-C., & Head, K. (2008). The puzzling persistence of the distance effect on bilateral trade. Review of Economics and Statistics, 90(1), 37–48.CrossRef Disdier, A.-C., & Head, K. (2008). The puzzling persistence of the distance effect on bilateral trade. Review of Economics and Statistics, 90(1), 37–48.CrossRef
go back to reference Glaeser, E. L., & Kohlhase, J. E. (2003). Cities, regions and the decline of transport costs. Papers in Regional Science, 83(1), 197–228.CrossRef Glaeser, E. L., & Kohlhase, J. E. (2003). Cities, regions and the decline of transport costs. Papers in Regional Science, 83(1), 197–228.CrossRef
go back to reference Goldberg, P. K., Khandelwal, A. K., Pavcnik, N., & Topalova, P. (2010). Imported intermediate inputs and domestic product growth: Evidence from India. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125(4), 1727–1767.CrossRef Goldberg, P. K., Khandelwal, A. K., Pavcnik, N., & Topalova, P. (2010). Imported intermediate inputs and domestic product growth: Evidence from India. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125(4), 1727–1767.CrossRef
go back to reference Imbs, J., & Mejean, I. (2017). Trade elasticities. Review of International Economics, 25(2), 383–402.CrossRef Imbs, J., & Mejean, I. (2017). Trade elasticities. Review of International Economics, 25(2), 383–402.CrossRef
go back to reference Johnson, R. C., & Noguera, G. (2012). Accounting for intermediates: Production sharing and trade in value added. Journal of International Economics, 86(2), 224–236.CrossRef Johnson, R. C., & Noguera, G. (2012). Accounting for intermediates: Production sharing and trade in value added. Journal of International Economics, 86(2), 224–236.CrossRef
go back to reference Leamer, E. E., & Levinsohn, J. (1995). International trade theory: The evidence. In G. Grossman & K. Rogoff (Eds.), Handbook of international economics (Vol. 3). Amsterdam: North-Holland. Leamer, E. E., & Levinsohn, J. (1995). International trade theory: The evidence. In G. Grossman & K. Rogoff (Eds.), Handbook of international economics (Vol. 3). Amsterdam: North-Holland.
go back to reference Miroudot, S., Lanz, R., & Ragoussis, A. (2009). Trade in intermediate goods and services. OECD Trade Policy Papers No. 93. Miroudot, S., Lanz, R., & Ragoussis, A. (2009). Trade in intermediate goods and services. OECD Trade Policy Papers No. 93.
go back to reference Nunn, N. (2007). Relationship-specificity, incomplete contracts and the pattern of trade. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(2), 569–600.CrossRef Nunn, N. (2007). Relationship-specificity, incomplete contracts and the pattern of trade. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(2), 569–600.CrossRef
go back to reference Rauch, J. E. (1999). Networks versus markets in international trade. Journal of International Economics, 48(1), 7–35.CrossRef Rauch, J. E. (1999). Networks versus markets in international trade. Journal of International Economics, 48(1), 7–35.CrossRef
go back to reference Santos Silva, J., & Tenreyro, S. (2006). The log of gravity. Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(4), 641–658.CrossRef Santos Silva, J., & Tenreyro, S. (2006). The log of gravity. Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(4), 641–658.CrossRef
go back to reference Santos Silva, J., & Tenreyro, S. (2011). Further simulation evidence on the performance of the poisson-PML estimator. Economics Letters, 112(2), 220–222.CrossRef Santos Silva, J., & Tenreyro, S. (2011). Further simulation evidence on the performance of the poisson-PML estimator. Economics Letters, 112(2), 220–222.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
The Gravity of Intermediate Goods
Authors
Paola Conconi
Glenn Magerman
Afrola Plaku
Publication date
11-06-2020
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Review of Industrial Organization / Issue 2/2020
Print ISSN: 0889-938X
Electronic ISSN: 1573-7160
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-020-09762-2

Other articles of this Issue 2/2020

Review of Industrial Organization 2/2020 Go to the issue