Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Policy Sciences 2/2015

01-06-2015

Foreign aid, economic globalization, and pollution

Authors: Sijeong Lim, Victor Menaldo, Aseem Prakash

Published in: Policy Sciences | Issue 2/2015

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This paper explores how trade and foreign direct investment (FDI) condition the effect of foreign aid on environmental protection in aid-recipient countries. We suggest that (1) environmental protection should be viewed as a public good and (2) all else equal, resource flows from abroad (via aid, trade, and FDI) influence governments’ incentives to provide public goods. (3) Because these resources shape governments’ incentives differently, their interactive effects should be examined. We begin with the assumption that developing country governments seek some optimal level of environmental protection, a level conditioned by their factor-intensive growth phase. We hypothesize that at low levels of export receipts or FDI inflows from the developed world, foreign aid is associated with superior environmental protection. This is because foreign aid, as an environmentally neutral addition to revenue, allows recipient governments to partially relax the trade-off between economic growth and environmental protection. As levels of export receipts or FDI inflows from the developed world increase, however, the salutary effect of foreign aid will diminish and eventually be reversed. This is because foreign aid mitigates the recipient government’s dependence on traders and investors in the developed world, and concomitantly reduces their pro-environmental policy leverage. Our analysis of 88 aid recipients, for the period 1980–2005, lends support to our argument.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
While environmental groups have actively lobbied multilateral organizations such as the World Bank, and the Bank has instituted policies such as the Strategic Environmental Assessment and Environmental Impact Assessment (Gutner 2002; Nielson and Tierney 2003; Park 2005), such groups nonetheless tend to lack the leverage that would lead donors to prioritize environmental issues over other goals. A recent empirical study also suggests that aid is largely “environmentally neutral” (Hicks et al. 2008).
 
2
As the salience of FDI originating from developing countries such as China and India increases, the pro-environmental pressures of FDI on the host economy might diminish. However, in the time period of our study, 1980–2005, the bulk of FDI received by developing countries originated from the North. According to Aykut and Ratha (2004), by the end of 1990s, over two thirds of the total FDI inflows to the developing world originated from the high income countries.
 
4
We believe that our characterization of foreign aid as a free addition to recipient government’s coffers holds even for earmarked aid or in-kind aid. There is a literature suggesting that aid earmarked for the provision of specific public goods such as schools and hospitals is largely fungible, and can produce fiscal displacement. Feyzioglu et al. (1998), for instance, find that developing-country governments receiving loans for agriculture, education, and energy can reduce public investments in these sectors. Farag et al. (2009) find that an increase in donor funding for health is associated with a proportionate decrease in government health spending. Foreign aid, even when it is earmarked for a specific purpose, still enables governments to divert resources elsewhere, according to their own priorities (Waddington 2004).
 
5
We also evaluated other dependent variables such as biochemical Oxygen demand (BOD), as a proxy for water pollution, and NO2 (Nitrous Oxide). Data for both of these pollutants is available for a smaller number of countries, and for much limited time period (from mid and late 1990s for most countries). Hence, we did not include these analyses in our study. While the data on CO2 intensity is widely available, we do not use the CO2 indicator because it is not a regulated pollutant in developing countries during most of the period covered in our study, and therefore is not appropriate as a proxy for the government’s commitment to environmental protection.
 
6
Fisher type Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) panel unit root tests conducted with several different lag length selections (1–5 years) reject the null hypothesis of a unit root.
 
7
In using the OECD foreign aid dataset, we treat all reported missing values as truly missing (and thus exclude them from the analysis).
 
8
Exports to donor countries were calculated using bilateral trade data from the Correlates of War Project (COW 2008). We treat all reported missing values as truly missing (and thus exclude them from the analysis), and accept all reported zeros as true zeros. Donor countries refer to the members of the Development Assistance Committee (DAC) in the OECD. Greece, Portugal, South Korea, and Spain are excluded due to their very recent membership into the DAC.
 
9
FDI flow data is from the World Bank Development Indicators (WBDI); FDI stock data is from the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD). Both FDI indicators are expressed as a percentage of GDP, and the correlation between the two is 0.41. We treat all reported missing values as truly missing (and thus exclude them from the analysis), and accept all reported zeros as true zeros.
 
10
Outward FDI from China has become an important phenomenon only in the recent years. Chinese FDI stock by the end of 2006 only accounted for 0.85 % of the world’s total FDI (Yang 2008).
 
11
Total trade data are from the WBDI.
 
12
The data are from Haber and Menaldo (2011).
 
13
The data are from the WBDI. The industry value added indicator comprises value added in the mining, manufacturing, construction, and energy (electricity, water, and gas) sectors.
 
14
The data are from Polity IV (2010).
 
15
The data are from the WBDI.
 
16
We test for remaining serial correlation across our LDV models, and do not find any remaining serial correlation. Although our main models are partial adjustment models, we also estimate a more general Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ADL) specification as a robustness check.
 
17
\(LRM_{Aid} + LRM_{Interacton.term} \times \, Globalization \, Flows.\)
 
18
Exports and FDI tend to be highly correlated. By including both in our model, we are estimating only their unique (non-overlapping) effects on pollution intensities. It makes little sense to drop either of them because that would lead to an under-specified model. Nevertheless, because of this collinearity, the results we present should be viewed as conservative estimates.
 
19
In different geographic regions and time periods, we find cases where developing countries receiving high levels of globalization flows from the North (i.e., levels close to or above the cut points we estimate) also receive increasing amounts of foreign aid. Among the cases are Singapore (during the early 1980s), Congo, Angola, and Cambodia (all during the mid 1990s), and the Czech Republic in the early 2000s.
 
20
The data are from WBDI. Total natural resources rents are the sum of oil rents, natural gas rents, coal rents (hard and soft), mineral rents, and forest rents.
 
21
The negative coefficient estimate of natural resource rent may be attributable to the fact that SO2 is an industrial pollutant. Its major emission sources include power plants, locomotives, ships, and other industrial processes. Resource extraction processes in resource rich developing countries generate trivial amounts of SO2, and therefore involve fewer SO2 emissions compared to manufacturing intensive production in countries at the same level of income. And although refineries produce sizable quantities of SO2, the world’s largest refineries are located in the US and South Korea, not in the oil exporting countries of the developing world.
 
22
Environmental aid is the segment of the ODA dedicated (committed) to environmental protection based on the classification of OECD’s Creditor Reporting System (CRS).
 
23
Unlike other models where the coefficient estimates for the lower order aid term were negative, this term is not statistically significant in Model 7. That is, aid does not reduce pollution even when FDI levels are low. Why so? This might be the result of controlling for environmental aid, but might also be attributable to the fact that Model 7 only covers the period between 1996–2005 due to the limited availability of disaggregated aid data. While Model 7 controls for Export to Donors, the average export from the South to the North in mid 1990s and 2000s is already much greater than that in the 1980s. Thus when only the later period is included in the analysis, even the observations with low FDI levels might be considerably globalized in terms of exports. If so, the lower order aid term can no longer capture the marginal effect of aid at little or no globalization flows.
 
24
This technique also addresses the possibility that, in our previous models, Nickell bias is distorting our results due to the correlation between the lagged dependent variable and country fixed effects.
 
25
As we have a relatively long time dimension (the maximum is 26 years), to prevent instrument proliferation we use instruments at these lag depths rather than using all available lags (Roodman 2009b).
 
26
In our earlier models, the Polity 2 Score was included as a control variable. The coefficient estimates of this variable (which capture the average marginal effect of regime type on pollution intensity) were insignificant.
 
27
Rather than introducing three-way-interaction terms, we conduct split sample analyses to allow the effects of independent and control variables to vary by regime type as well.
 
28
\({\text{SO}}_{2} {\text{Intensity}}_{it} = \phi_{1} {\text{SO}}_{2} {\text{Intensity}}_{i,t - 1} + \gamma_{1} {\text{Aid}}_{it} + \gamma_{2} {\text{Aid}}_{i,t - 1} + \gamma_{3} {\text{Globalization Flow}}_{it} \, + \, \gamma_{4} {\text{Globalization Flow}}_{i,t - 1} + \gamma_{5} {\text{Aid}} \times {\text{Globalization Flow}}_{it} + \gamma_{6} {\text{Aid}} \times {\text{Globalization Flo}}w_{i,t - 1} + \, x_{it} \beta_{1} + {\text{x}}_{i,t - 1} \beta_{2} + \alpha_{i} + \tau_{t} + \varepsilon_{it}.\)
 
Literature
go back to reference Ahlquist, J. S., & Prakash, A. (2010). FDI and the costs of contract enforcement in developing countries. Policy Sciences, 43(2), 181–200.CrossRef Ahlquist, J. S., & Prakash, A. (2010). FDI and the costs of contract enforcement in developing countries. Policy Sciences, 43(2), 181–200.CrossRef
go back to reference Alesina, A., & Dollar, D. (2000). Who gives foreign aid to whom and why? Journal of Economic Growth, 5(1), 33–63.CrossRef Alesina, A., & Dollar, D. (2000). Who gives foreign aid to whom and why? Journal of Economic Growth, 5(1), 33–63.CrossRef
go back to reference Antweiler, W., Copeland, B. R., & Taylor, M. S. (2001). Is free trade good for the environment? American Economic Review, 91(4), 877–908.CrossRef Antweiler, W., Copeland, B. R., & Taylor, M. S. (2001). Is free trade good for the environment? American Economic Review, 91(4), 877–908.CrossRef
go back to reference Arvin, B. M., & Lew, B. (2009). Foreign aid and ecological outcomes in poorer countries: An empirical analysis. Applied Economics Letters, 16, 295–299.CrossRef Arvin, B. M., & Lew, B. (2009). Foreign aid and ecological outcomes in poorer countries: An empirical analysis. Applied Economics Letters, 16, 295–299.CrossRef
go back to reference Aykut, D., & Ratha, D. (2004). South-South FDI flows: How big are they? In United Nations Conference on Trade and Development Division on Investment, Technology and Enterprise Development, 13(1), 149. 2004. Aykut, D., & Ratha, D. (2004). South-South FDI flows: How big are they? In United Nations Conference on Trade and Development Division on Investment, Technology and Enterprise Development, 13(1), 149. 2004.
go back to reference Bernauer, T., & Koubi, V. (2009). Effects of political institutions on air quality. Ecological Economics, 68(5), 1355–1365.CrossRef Bernauer, T., & Koubi, V. (2009). Effects of political institutions on air quality. Ecological Economics, 68(5), 1355–1365.CrossRef
go back to reference Brambor, T., Clark, W., & Golder, M. (2006). Understanding interaction models: Improving empirical analyses. Political Analysis, 14(1), 63–82.CrossRef Brambor, T., Clark, W., & Golder, M. (2006). Understanding interaction models: Improving empirical analyses. Political Analysis, 14(1), 63–82.CrossRef
go back to reference Cao, X., & Prakash, A. (2010). Trade competition and domestic pollution: A panel study, 1980–2003. International Organization, 64(03), 481–503.CrossRef Cao, X., & Prakash, A. (2010). Trade competition and domestic pollution: A panel study, 1980–2003. International Organization, 64(03), 481–503.CrossRef
go back to reference Castro, R., & Hammond, B. (2009). The architecture of aid for the environment: A ten-year statistical perspective. CFP Working Paper Series No 3. Concessional Finance and Global Partnerships Vice Presidency, The World Bank Group. Castro, R., & Hammond, B. (2009). The architecture of aid for the environment: A ten-year statistical perspective. CFP Working Paper Series No 3. Concessional Finance and Global Partnerships Vice Presidency, The World Bank Group.
go back to reference Caves, R. E. (1996). Multinational enterprise and economic analysis (2nd ed.). New York and Melbourne: Cambridge University Press. Caves, R. E. (1996). Multinational enterprise and economic analysis (2nd ed.). New York and Melbourne: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Coria, J., & Sterner, T. (2010). Tradable permits in developing countries: Evidence from air pollution in Chile. The Journal of Environment & Development, 19(2), 145–170.CrossRef Coria, J., & Sterner, T. (2010). Tradable permits in developing countries: Evidence from air pollution in Chile. The Journal of Environment & Development, 19(2), 145–170.CrossRef
go back to reference Dauvergne, P. (2001). The Rise of Environmental Super Power? Evaluating Japanese environmental aid to South East Asia. In J. Maswood (Ed.), Japan and East Asian regionalism (pp. 51–67). London and New York: Routledge. Dauvergne, P. (2001). The Rise of Environmental Super Power? Evaluating Japanese environmental aid to South East Asia. In J. Maswood (Ed.), Japan and East Asian regionalism (pp. 51–67). London and New York: Routledge.
go back to reference De Boef, S., & Keele, L. (2008). Taking time seriously. American Journal of Political Science, 52(1), 184–200.CrossRef De Boef, S., & Keele, L. (2008). Taking time seriously. American Journal of Political Science, 52(1), 184–200.CrossRef
go back to reference Djankov, S., Montalvo, J. G., & Reynal-Querol, M. (2008). The curse of aid. Journal of Economic Growth, 13(3), 169–194.CrossRef Djankov, S., Montalvo, J. G., & Reynal-Querol, M. (2008). The curse of aid. Journal of Economic Growth, 13(3), 169–194.CrossRef
go back to reference Driscoll, J. C., & Kraay, A. C. (1998). Consistent covariance matrix estimation with spatially dependent panel data. Review of Economics and Statistics, 80(4), 549–560.CrossRef Driscoll, J. C., & Kraay, A. C. (1998). Consistent covariance matrix estimation with spatially dependent panel data. Review of Economics and Statistics, 80(4), 549–560.CrossRef
go back to reference Dunning, J. H. (1993) Multinational Enterprises and the Global Economy. Wokingham, England: Addision-Wesley. Dunning, J. H. (1993) Multinational Enterprises and the Global Economy. Wokingham, England: Addision-Wesley.
go back to reference Egels-Zandén, N. (2007). Suppliers’ compliance with MNCs’ codes of conduct: Behind the scenes at Chinese toy suppliers. Journal of Business Ethics, 75(1), 45–62.CrossRef Egels-Zandén, N. (2007). Suppliers’ compliance with MNCs’ codes of conduct: Behind the scenes at Chinese toy suppliers. Journal of Business Ethics, 75(1), 45–62.CrossRef
go back to reference Eskeland, G., & Harrison, A. (2003). Moving to greener pastures? Multinationals and the pollution haven hypothesis. Journal of Development Economics, 70(1), 1–23.CrossRef Eskeland, G., & Harrison, A. (2003). Moving to greener pastures? Multinationals and the pollution haven hypothesis. Journal of Development Economics, 70(1), 1–23.CrossRef
go back to reference Farag, M., Nandakumar, A. K., Wallack, S. S., Gaumer, G., & Hodgkin, D. (2009). Does funding from donors displace government spending for health in developing countries? Health Affairs, 28(4), 1045–1055.CrossRef Farag, M., Nandakumar, A. K., Wallack, S. S., Gaumer, G., & Hodgkin, D. (2009). Does funding from donors displace government spending for health in developing countries? Health Affairs, 28(4), 1045–1055.CrossRef
go back to reference Ferejohn, J. (1986). Incumbent performance and electoral control. Public Choice, 50(1), 5–25.CrossRef Ferejohn, J. (1986). Incumbent performance and electoral control. Public Choice, 50(1), 5–25.CrossRef
go back to reference Ferejohn, J. (1999). Accountability and authority: Toward a theory of political accountability. In A. Przeworski, S. Stokes, & B. Manin (Eds.), Democracy, accountability, and representation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Ferejohn, J. (1999). Accountability and authority: Toward a theory of political accountability. In A. Przeworski, S. Stokes, & B. Manin (Eds.), Democracy, accountability, and representation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Feyzioglu, T., Swaroop, V., & Zhu, M. (1998). A panel data analysis of the fungibility of foreign aid. The World Bank Economic Review, 12(1), 29–58.CrossRef Feyzioglu, T., Swaroop, V., & Zhu, M. (1998). A panel data analysis of the fungibility of foreign aid. The World Bank Economic Review, 12(1), 29–58.CrossRef
go back to reference Frank, A. G. (1967). Capitalism and underdevelopment in Latin America. New York: Monthly Review Press. Frank, A. G. (1967). Capitalism and underdevelopment in Latin America. New York: Monthly Review Press.
go back to reference Galetovic, A., & Sanhueza, R. (2000). Citizens, autocrats, and plotters: A model and new evidence on coups d’état. Economics and Politics, 12(2), 183–204.CrossRef Galetovic, A., & Sanhueza, R. (2000). Citizens, autocrats, and plotters: A model and new evidence on coups d’état. Economics and Politics, 12(2), 183–204.CrossRef
go back to reference Gallego, M., & Pitchik, C. (2004). An economic theory of leadership turnover. Journal of Public Economics, 88(12), 2361–2382.CrossRef Gallego, M., & Pitchik, C. (2004). An economic theory of leadership turnover. Journal of Public Economics, 88(12), 2361–2382.CrossRef
go back to reference Gibson, C. C., Andersson, K., Ostrom, E., & Shivakumar, S. (2005). The samaritan’s dilemma. C. C. Gibson (Ed.). New York (NY): Oxford University Press. Gibson, C. C., Andersson, K., Ostrom, E., & Shivakumar, S. (2005). The samaritan’s dilemma. C. C. Gibson (Ed.). New York (NY): Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Gleditsch, K. S., & Ward, M. D. (2006). Diffusion and the international context of democratization. International Organization, 60(4), 911.CrossRef Gleditsch, K. S., & Ward, M. D. (2006). Diffusion and the international context of democratization. International Organization, 60(4), 911.CrossRef
go back to reference Greenhill, B., Mosley, L., & Prakash, A. (2009). Trade and labor rights: A panel study, 1986–2002. American Political Science Review, 103(4), 669–690.CrossRef Greenhill, B., Mosley, L., & Prakash, A. (2009). Trade and labor rights: A panel study, 1986–2002. American Political Science Review, 103(4), 669–690.CrossRef
go back to reference Grieg-Gran, M., Porras, I., & Wunder, S. (2005). How can market mechanisms for forest environmental services help the poor? Preliminary lessons from Latin America. World Development, 33(9), 1511–1527.CrossRef Grieg-Gran, M., Porras, I., & Wunder, S. (2005). How can market mechanisms for forest environmental services help the poor? Preliminary lessons from Latin America. World Development, 33(9), 1511–1527.CrossRef
go back to reference Grossman, G., & Kreuger, A. B. (1995). Economic growth and the environment. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(2), 353–375.CrossRef Grossman, G., & Kreuger, A. B. (1995). Economic growth and the environment. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(2), 353–375.CrossRef
go back to reference Gutner, T. L. (2002). Banking on the environment: Multilateral development banks and their environmental performance in Central and Eastern Europe. MA: MIT Press. Gutner, T. L. (2002). Banking on the environment: Multilateral development banks and their environmental performance in Central and Eastern Europe. MA: MIT Press.
go back to reference Haber, S., & Menaldo, V. (2011). Do natural resources fuel authoritarianism? A reappraisal of the resource curse. American Political Science Review, 105(1), 1–26.CrossRef Haber, S., & Menaldo, V. (2011). Do natural resources fuel authoritarianism? A reappraisal of the resource curse. American Political Science Review, 105(1), 1–26.CrossRef
go back to reference Hamilton, K., & Clemens, M. (1999). Genuine savings rates in developing countries. The World Bank Economic Review, 13(2), 333–356.CrossRef Hamilton, K., & Clemens, M. (1999). Genuine savings rates in developing countries. The World Bank Economic Review, 13(2), 333–356.CrossRef
go back to reference Henisz, W. J. (2010). Political constraint index (POLCON). Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania. Henisz, W. J. (2010). Political constraint index (POLCON). Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania.
go back to reference Hibbs, D. (2000). Bread and peace voting in U.S. presidential elections. Public Choice, 104, 149–180.CrossRef Hibbs, D. (2000). Bread and peace voting in U.S. presidential elections. Public Choice, 104, 149–180.CrossRef
go back to reference Hibbs, D. (2001). The politicization of growth theory. Kyklos, 54, 265–286.CrossRef Hibbs, D. (2001). The politicization of growth theory. Kyklos, 54, 265–286.CrossRef
go back to reference Hicks, R. L., Parks, B. C., Roberts, J. T., & Tierney, M. J. (2008). Greening aid? Understanding the environmental impact of development assistance. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Hicks, R. L., Parks, B. C., Roberts, J. T., & Tierney, M. J. (2008). Greening aid? Understanding the environmental impact of development assistance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Jaffe, A. B., Peterson, S. R., Portney, P. R., & Stavins, R. N. (1995). Environmental regulation and the competitiveness of US manufacturing: What does the evidence tell us? Journal of Economic Literature, 33, 132–163. Jaffe, A. B., Peterson, S. R., Portney, P. R., & Stavins, R. N. (1995). Environmental regulation and the competitiveness of US manufacturing: What does the evidence tell us? Journal of Economic Literature, 33, 132–163.
go back to reference King, A. A., & Shaver, J. M. (2001). Are aliens green? Assessing foreign establishments’ environmental conduct in the United States. Strategic Management Journal, 22(11), 1069–1085.CrossRef King, A. A., & Shaver, J. M. (2001). Are aliens green? Assessing foreign establishments’ environmental conduct in the United States. Strategic Management Journal, 22(11), 1069–1085.CrossRef
go back to reference Knack, S. (2001). Aid dependence and the quality of governance: Cross-country empirical tests. Southern Economic Journal, 68(2), 310–329.CrossRef Knack, S. (2001). Aid dependence and the quality of governance: Cross-country empirical tests. Southern Economic Journal, 68(2), 310–329.CrossRef
go back to reference Lebovic, J. H., & Voeten, E. (2009). The cost of shame: international organizations and foreign aid in the punishing of human rights violators. Journal of Peace Research, 46(1), 79–97.CrossRef Lebovic, J. H., & Voeten, E. (2009). The cost of shame: international organizations and foreign aid in the punishing of human rights violators. Journal of Peace Research, 46(1), 79–97.CrossRef
go back to reference Levinson, A. (2010). Offshoring pollution: Is the U.S. increasingly importing polluting goods? Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 4(1), 63–83.CrossRef Levinson, A. (2010). Offshoring pollution: Is the U.S. increasingly importing polluting goods? Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 4(1), 63–83.CrossRef
go back to reference Li, Q., & Reuveny, R. (2006). Democracy and environmental degradation. International Studies Quarterly, 50(4), 935–956. 27. Li, Q., & Reuveny, R. (2006). Democracy and environmental degradation. International Studies Quarterly, 50(4), 935–956. 27.
go back to reference Lundsgaarde, E., Breunig, C., & Prakash, A. (2007). Trade versus Aid? donor generosity in the era of globalization. Policy Sciences, 40(2), 157–179.CrossRef Lundsgaarde, E., Breunig, C., & Prakash, A. (2007). Trade versus Aid? donor generosity in the era of globalization. Policy Sciences, 40(2), 157–179.CrossRef
go back to reference Madsen, P. M. (2009). Does corporate investment drive a race to the bottom in environmental protection? A reexamination of the effect of environmental regulation on investment. Academy of Management Journal, 52(6), 1297–1318.CrossRef Madsen, P. M. (2009). Does corporate investment drive a race to the bottom in environmental protection? A reexamination of the effect of environmental regulation on investment. Academy of Management Journal, 52(6), 1297–1318.CrossRef
go back to reference Nielson, D., & Tierney, M. (2003). Delegation to international organizations: Agency theory and world bank environmental reform. International Organization, 57(2), 241–276.CrossRef Nielson, D., & Tierney, M. (2003). Delegation to international organizations: Agency theory and world bank environmental reform. International Organization, 57(2), 241–276.CrossRef
go back to reference Park, S. (2005). How transnational environmental advocacy networks socialize international financial institutions. Global Environmental Politics, 5(4), 95–119.CrossRef Park, S. (2005). How transnational environmental advocacy networks socialize international financial institutions. Global Environmental Politics, 5(4), 95–119.CrossRef
go back to reference Pauly, L., & Reich, S. (1997). National structures and multinational corporate behaviors. International Organization, 51(1), 1–30.CrossRef Pauly, L., & Reich, S. (1997). National structures and multinational corporate behaviors. International Organization, 51(1), 1–30.CrossRef
go back to reference Perkins, R., & Neumayer, E. (2012). Does the ‘California effect’ operate across borders? Journal of European Public Policy, 19(2), 217–237.CrossRef Perkins, R., & Neumayer, E. (2012). Does the ‘California effect’ operate across borders? Journal of European Public Policy, 19(2), 217–237.CrossRef
go back to reference Prakash, A., & Potoski, M. (2006). Racing to the bottom? Globalization, environmental governance, and ISO 14001. American Journal of Political Science, 50(2), 347–361.CrossRef Prakash, A., & Potoski, M. (2006). Racing to the bottom? Globalization, environmental governance, and ISO 14001. American Journal of Political Science, 50(2), 347–361.CrossRef
go back to reference Prakash, A., & Potoski, M. (2007). Investing up: FDI and the cross-country diffusion of ISO 14001 management systems. International Studies Quarterly, 51(3), 723–744.CrossRef Prakash, A., & Potoski, M. (2007). Investing up: FDI and the cross-country diffusion of ISO 14001 management systems. International Studies Quarterly, 51(3), 723–744.CrossRef
go back to reference Rivera, J., & Oh, C. H. (2013). Environmental regulations and multinational corporations’ foreign market entry investments. Policy Studies Journal, 41(2), 243–272.CrossRef Rivera, J., & Oh, C. H. (2013). Environmental regulations and multinational corporations’ foreign market entry investments. Policy Studies Journal, 41(2), 243–272.CrossRef
go back to reference Rogoff, K. (1990). Equilibrium political budget cycles. American Economic Review, 80, 21–36. Rogoff, K. (1990). Equilibrium political budget cycles. American Economic Review, 80, 21–36.
go back to reference Roodman, D. (2009a). A note on the theme of too many instruments. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 71(1), 135–158.CrossRef Roodman, D. (2009a). A note on the theme of too many instruments. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 71(1), 135–158.CrossRef
go back to reference Roodman, D. (2009b). How to do xtabond2: An introduction to difference and system GMM inStata. Stata Journal, 9(1), 86. Roodman, D. (2009b). How to do xtabond2: An introduction to difference and system GMM inStata. Stata Journal, 9(1), 86.
go back to reference Ross, M. (1996). Conditionality and logging reform in the tropics. In R. O. Keohane & M. A. Levy (Eds.), Institutions for environmental aid (pp. 167–197). MA: MIT Press. Ross, M. (1996). Conditionality and logging reform in the tropics. In R. O. Keohane & M. A. Levy (Eds.), Institutions for environmental aid (pp. 167–197). MA: MIT Press.
go back to reference Saikawa, E. (2013). Policy diffusion of emission standards is there a race to the top? World Politics, 65(01), 1–33.CrossRef Saikawa, E. (2013). Policy diffusion of emission standards is there a race to the top? World Politics, 65(01), 1–33.CrossRef
go back to reference Spilker, G. (2012). Globalization, political institutions, and the environment in developing countries. Routledge. Spilker, G. (2012). Globalization, political institutions, and the environment in developing countries. Routledge.
go back to reference Stern, D. I. (2005). Global sulfur emissions from 1850 to 2000. Chemosphere, 58(2), 163–175.CrossRef Stern, D. I. (2005). Global sulfur emissions from 1850 to 2000. Chemosphere, 58(2), 163–175.CrossRef
go back to reference Tiebout, C. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. The Journal of Political Economy, 64(5), 416–424.CrossRef Tiebout, C. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. The Journal of Political Economy, 64(5), 416–424.CrossRef
go back to reference Tsebelis, G. (1995). Decision making in political systems: Veto players in presidentialism, parliamentarism, multicameralism and multipartyism. British Journal of Political Science, 25(3), 289–325.CrossRef Tsebelis, G. (1995). Decision making in political systems: Veto players in presidentialism, parliamentarism, multicameralism and multipartyism. British Journal of Political Science, 25(3), 289–325.CrossRef
go back to reference Vogel, D. (1995). Trading up. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Vogel, D. (1995). Trading up. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
go back to reference Waddington, C. (2004). Does earmarked donor funding make it more or less likely that developing countries will allocate their resources towards programmes that yield the greatest health benefits? Bulletin of the World Health Organization, 82, 703–708. Waddington, C. (2004). Does earmarked donor funding make it more or less likely that developing countries will allocate their resources towards programmes that yield the greatest health benefits? Bulletin of the World Health Organization, 82, 703–708.
go back to reference Wagner, D. (2003). Aid and trade-an empirical study. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 17(2), 153–173.CrossRef Wagner, D. (2003). Aid and trade-an empirical study. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 17(2), 153–173.CrossRef
go back to reference Yang, C. (2008). Corporate social responsibility and china overseas extractive industry operations: Achieving sustainable natural resource extraction. Foundation for Environmental Security and Sustainability (FESS) Issue Brief. Yang, C. (2008). Corporate social responsibility and china overseas extractive industry operations: Achieving sustainable natural resource extraction. Foundation for Environmental Security and Sustainability (FESS) Issue Brief.
go back to reference Younas, J., & Bandyopadhyay, S. (2009). Do donors care about declining trade revenue from liberalization? An analysis of bilateral aid allocation. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 91(3), 141–151. Younas, J., & Bandyopadhyay, S. (2009). Do donors care about declining trade revenue from liberalization? An analysis of bilateral aid allocation. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 91(3), 141–151.
go back to reference Zaheer, S. (1995). Overcoming the liability of foreignness. Academy of Management Journal, 38(2), 341–343.CrossRef Zaheer, S. (1995). Overcoming the liability of foreignness. Academy of Management Journal, 38(2), 341–343.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Foreign aid, economic globalization, and pollution
Authors
Sijeong Lim
Victor Menaldo
Aseem Prakash
Publication date
01-06-2015
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Policy Sciences / Issue 2/2015
Print ISSN: 0032-2687
Electronic ISSN: 1573-0891
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11077-014-9205-6

Other articles of this Issue 2/2015

Policy Sciences 2/2015 Go to the issue