Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Review of Industrial Organization 1/2023

02-09-2022

Measuring the Power of Regulatory Regimes

Author: Dennis L. Weisman

Published in: Review of Industrial Organization | Issue 1/2023

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

The power of a regulatory regime (PRR) measures the strength of the incentives for cost-reducing innovation. A static PRR metric is derived that is a function of: the regulated firm’s share of profits; the ratchet effect; and the Arrow effect. The analysis reveals that the dynamic PRR is significantly lower than the static PRR even for long-lived regulatory regimes. A key finding is that the literature may significantly overstate the PRR. This may help explain why the empirical findings with regard to the efficiency gains from price cap regulation do not offer unequivocal validation of the prevailing theory.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
Schumpeter (1942, pp. 104–106) contends that innovation is incompatible with the model of perfect competition and therefore should not inform the practice of economic regulation. He further observes that “perfect competition is and always has been temporarily suspended whenever anything new is being introduced—automatically or by measures devised for the purpose—even in otherwise perfectly competitive conditions” (p. 105). See also McNulty (1968).
 
2
Laffont and Tirole (1993, p. 11) provide three discrete characterizations of the power of regulatory incentive schemes: Cost-of-Service regulation is categorized as having “very low” power; incentive regulation (inclusive of cost and profit sharing) is characterized as having “intermediate” power; and price-cap regulation in which the regulated firm is the residual claimant is characterized as having “very high” power. Weisman (2019b) defines the power of the regulatory regime as the ratio of the regulated firm’s investment in cost-reducing effort and the first-best level of cost-reducing effort. See also Laffont and Tirole (1993, p. 40, Table 2).
 
3
Prices adjust over time in competitive markets to reflect industry innovation. A firm that implements a novel cost-reducing innovation may be able to sustain a supra-normal price–cost margin until that innovation is replicated across the industry which results in a downward price adjustment. This implies that—at least in a dynamic competitive framework—firms do not have ideal incentives to innovate because they are not the residual claimants for their efficiency gains. Moreover, if this cost-reducing innovation is sufficiently unique, the innovator may be granted a patent that specifies a certain period of time before the information that is related to the innovation must be shared and the innovation can be replicated.
 
4
PCR is commonly characterized as a fixed-priced contract because the price cap for the regulated firm is invariant (fixed) with respect to its performance for the duration of the regulatory regime (Laffont and Tirole, 1993, p. 40). Specifically, the regulated firm is typically limited in its ability to pass through cost increases in the form of rate increases, which mitigates the moral hazard problem that arises under RRR.
 
5
Similar issues arise with respect to capital investments if the regulator limits the returns on successful investments and forces the firm to bear the full financial consequences of unsuccessful investments. See Kolbe and Tye (1991) for further discussion of this important issue.
 
6
RRR is commonly characterized as a cost-plus contract because the rates that consumers pay tend to vary directly with the reported costs of the regulated firm. Specifically, the regulated firm is typically able to pass through a high proportion of cost increases in the form of rate increases (Laffont & Tirole, 1993, p. 40). Even under RRR, however, the regulated firm’s expenditures and capital investments are subject to prudence tests.
 
7
This is probably a more accurate characterization of the practice of PCR in Europe than in the United States. See, for example, Sappington and Weisman (2010) and Crew and Kleindorfer (1996).
 
8
These shared earnings may be used to effect various forms of redistribution (Posner, 1971). In the U.S. telecommunications industry, these shared earnings have been used to fund bill credits, rate refunds, and infrastructure improvements (Sappington and Weisman, 1996, Chapter 3). For example, in the U.S. telecommunications industry, shared earnings have been used to expand broadband infrastructure in rural areas to address “digital divide” concerns. The use of shared earnings for infrastructure improvements in other regulated industries—including electric power, natural gas, and water—is seemingly less common. From this perspective, shared earnings are a form of “consumer dividends” that regulators distribute to their constituencies in myriad ways. In addition, these “dividends” allow consumers to partake in the higher earnings of the regulated firm and therefore can serve to lessen the pressure on regulators to recontract when regulated firms report higher earnings (Sappington and Weisman, 1996, p. 334). The risk of regulatory recontracting and its effect on the power of the regulatory regime is explored in Sect. 5.
 
9
It can be shown that this metric is equivalent to the PRR metric that is employed in Weisman (2019b) when the latter is adjusted for output differences across regulatory regimes and effort costs are quadratic.
 
10
The regulator is typically not able to lower the price cap directly without breaching its commitment; but it can do so indirectly through entry-accommodation—policies that are advantageous to new entrants—that renders pricing below the cap a more profitable strategy for the regulated firm (Weisman, 2019a, 2019b). For example, under the provisions of the 1996 Telecommunication Act, incumbent providers are required to lease unbundled network elements to rivals at prices that are set by regulatory fiat and that allow competitors to resell their services at prescribed discounts (Kahn et al., 1999). The regulator can use these network element (input) prices and resale discounts to force the regulated firm to reduce retail prices below the price cap when its costs decrease. The ratchet effect can therefore arise even under pure PCR.
 
11
The Arrow effect (1962) recognizes that the firm’s incentive to undertake unit-cost reductions increases with output, ceteris paribus. See also Cabral and Riordan (1989).
 
12
In an unregulated setting, \(\rho\) is a measure of the share of cost savings that the market allows the innovating firm to retain. \(\rho = ( < ){\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} 1{\kern 1pt}\) for an unregulated monopolist (Cournot oligopolist) since s = 0, \({\kern 1pt} \frac{dp}{{dc}} > 0{\kern 1pt}\) and \(\frac{p - c}{p} = ( < )\frac{1}{\varepsilon }\) in equilibrium. For an unregulated monopolist, the ratchet and Arrow effects are perfectly offsetting, while the ratchet effect dominates the Arrow effect for a Cournot oligopolist. Finally, in the case of atomistic Cournot competition it can be shown that \(\rho \to {\kern 1pt} {\kern 1pt} 1{\kern 1pt} .\)
 
13
Weisman (2019b) considers the possibility that s endogenously influences the regulator’s choice of p. In that framework, the PRR can be higher under PCR with earnings sharing than under pure PCR.
 
14
See note 10 supra.
 
15
Under the PCR regimes that are commonly employed in the U.S., the firm’s prices are set to reflect prevailing costs at the start of the PCR regime, and then are permitted to increase, on average, at the rate of economy-wide retail price inflation (I), less an offset (X)— the “X factor”— for the remainder of the regime. Under this form of PCR, the X factor measures the extent to which productivity in the regulated industry is expected to increase more rapidly and industry input prices are expected to increase less rapidly than in the general economy (Bernstein & Sappington, 1999). Because the X factor is developed on the basis of a peer group of regulated firms, there is no guarantee that it delineates a “competitive” price trajectory. Rebasing therefore provides an additional competitive check (correction) on earnings. As the industry becomes more competitive, the length of the PCR regime increases along with the time between rebasing until it may no longer be necessary (Sappington & Weisman, 2010).
 
16
Earnings sharing enables consumers to share in realized efficiency gains throughout the PCR regime (Lyon, 1996; Schmalensee, 1989), albeit at the cost of lower overall efficiency gains (Cabral & Riordan, 1989; Weisman, 1993).
 
17
To address this issue, regulators in select jurisdictions have adopted efficiency-carryover mechanisms that allow the regulated firm to carry over a stipulated proportion of its excess (deficient) returns into the subsequent PCR regime. See, for example, Alberta Utilities Commission (2012, Section 9). These mechanisms would be expected to exhibit the same qualitative effect as increasing the duration of the regulatory regime.
 
18
Sappington (2002, pp. 251–2) discusses the factors that inform the length of time between regulatory reviews, while Armstrong et al. (1995) explore the optimal regulatory lag. There are similarities between the optimal regulatory lag and the optimal patent life (Scherer, 1972; Nordhaus, 1969, ch. 5): In both cases, the objective is to encourage firms to undertake innovation without subjecting consumers to supra-normal prices indefinitely. Nonetheless, there are also differences: Patents shield firms from competition pro tempore to encourage innovation by preventing instantaneous replication by rivals. Regulatory lag does not shield the regulated firm from competition as much as it emulates the competitive process. See note 3 supra. It does this by permitting the regulated firm that innovates successfully to retain the benefits of that innovation for a transitory period of time before they are appropriated by the regulator and passed on to consumers in the form of lower rates. I am grateful to Lawrence White for this observation.
 
19
The regulated firm and the competitive firm are assumed to employ identical discount rates. In addition, it is implicitly assumed that \(\rho = 1{\kern 1pt}\) for the benchmark competitive firm. See note 12 supra.
 
20
It is straightforward to show that \({\kern 1pt} \forall n \le l,{\kern 1pt}\) \(DAF(n,r,l) = 1\) only when n = l = 1 or n = l = ∞. Hence, except in degenerate cases, \(\rho^{D} < 1.\)
 
21
In order to properly emulate the competitive process, the regulator would opt not to reflect in current-period rates any firm-specific cost savings realized less than l periods prior. This may be referred to as sequential regulatory lag.
 
22
In an early survey of the performance of incentive regulation in the telecommunications industry, Kridel et al. (1996) report only modest efficiency gains in the transition from RRR to PCR. These early forms of incentive regulation were of relatively short duration and frequently incorporated earnings-sharing mechanisms. Uri (2001) reports similar lackluster efficiency gains from the early adoption of PCR. In subsequent years, these efficiency gains improved concomitantly with an increase in the length of the regulatory regime and the elimination of earnings sharing (Abel, 2000; Ai and Sappington, 2002; Eckenrod, 2006; Resende, 2000; Sappington and Weisman, 2010, pp. 236–239; Seo and Shin, 2011). Nonetheless, the overall empirical evidence on the efficiency gains associated with transitioning from RRR to PCR is best characterized as “mixed” (Sappington, 2002, pp. 278–282). The empirical evidence on performance-based regulation (PBR) in electric power is less comprehensive than that for telecommunications. However, Hellwig et al. (2020) report efficiency gains from high-powered incentives in German electricity networks. See also Crowley and Meitzen (2021) and Domah and Pollitt (2001). In general, the performance gains from adopting PCR are less dramatic than the theory would have predicted. This may be the case because the differences between RRR and PCR in practice are less pronounced than they are in theory (Laffont and Tirole, 1993, p. 19).
 
Literature
go back to reference Abel, J. (2000). The performance of the state telecommunications industry under price-cap regulation: An assessment of the empirical evidence. NRRI 00-14, Columbus, OH: The National Regulatory Research Institute. Abel, J. (2000). The performance of the state telecommunications industry under price-cap regulation: An assessment of the empirical evidence. NRRI 00-14, Columbus, OH: The National Regulatory Research Institute.
go back to reference Ai, C., & Sappington, D. (2002). The impact of state incentive regulation on the U.S. telecommunications industry. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 22(2), 133–160.CrossRef Ai, C., & Sappington, D. (2002). The impact of state incentive regulation on the U.S. telecommunications industry. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 22(2), 133–160.CrossRef
go back to reference Alberta Utilities Commission. (2012). Rate regulation initiative: Distribution performance-based regulation. Decision 2012-237. Alberta Utilities Commission. (2012). Rate regulation initiative: Distribution performance-based regulation. Decision 2012-237.
go back to reference Armstrong, M., Cowan, S., & Vickers, J. (1994). Regulatory reform. The MIT Press. Armstrong, M., Cowan, S., & Vickers, J. (1994). Regulatory reform. The MIT Press.
go back to reference Armstrong, M., Rees, R., & Vickers, J. (1995). Optimal regulatory lag under price cap regulation. Revista Espanola De Economia, 12, 93–116. Armstrong, M., Rees, R., & Vickers, J. (1995). Optimal regulatory lag under price cap regulation. Revista Espanola De Economia, 12, 93–116.
go back to reference Arrow, K. (1962). Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In The rate and direction of economic activity: Economic and social factors. NBER Conference No. 13. The National Bureau of Economic Research (pp. 609–626). Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ. Arrow, K. (1962). Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In The rate and direction of economic activity: Economic and social factors. NBER Conference No. 13. The National Bureau of Economic Research (pp. 609–626). Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.
go back to reference Bailey, E. (1974). Innovation and regulation. Journal of Public Economics, 3(3), 285–295.CrossRef Bailey, E. (1974). Innovation and regulation. Journal of Public Economics, 3(3), 285–295.CrossRef
go back to reference Bernstein, J., & Sappington, D. (1999). Setting the X factor in price-cap regulation plans. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 16(1), 5–25.CrossRef Bernstein, J., & Sappington, D. (1999). Setting the X factor in price-cap regulation plans. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 16(1), 5–25.CrossRef
go back to reference Bonbright, J. (1961). Principles of public utility rates. Columbia University Press.CrossRef Bonbright, J. (1961). Principles of public utility rates. Columbia University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Braeutigam, R., & Panzar, J. (1989). Diversification incentives under ‘price-based and ‘cost-based’ regulation. Rand Journal of Economics, 20(3), 373–391.CrossRef Braeutigam, R., & Panzar, J. (1989). Diversification incentives under ‘price-based and ‘cost-based’ regulation. Rand Journal of Economics, 20(3), 373–391.CrossRef
go back to reference Brennan, T. (1989). Regulating by capping prices. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 1, 133–147.CrossRef Brennan, T. (1989). Regulating by capping prices. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 1, 133–147.CrossRef
go back to reference Cabral, L., & Riordan, M. (1989). Incentives for cost reduction under price cap regulation. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 1, 93–102.CrossRef Cabral, L., & Riordan, M. (1989). Incentives for cost reduction under price cap regulation. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 1, 93–102.CrossRef
go back to reference Crew, M., & Kleindorfer, P. (1996). Incentive regulation in the United Kingdom and the United States: Some lessons. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 9(3), 211–225.CrossRef Crew, M., & Kleindorfer, P. (1996). Incentive regulation in the United Kingdom and the United States: Some lessons. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 9(3), 211–225.CrossRef
go back to reference Crowley, N., & Meitzen, M. (2021). Measuring the price impact of price-cap regulation among Canadian electricity distribution utilities. Utilities Policy, 72, 101275. Crowley, N., & Meitzen, M. (2021). Measuring the price impact of price-cap regulation among Canadian electricity distribution utilities. Utilities Policy, 72, 101275.
go back to reference Domah, P., & Pollitt, M. (2001). The restructuring and privatisation of electricity distribution and supply businesses in England and Wales: A social cost–benefit analysis. Fiscal Studies, 22, 107–146.CrossRef Domah, P., & Pollitt, M. (2001). The restructuring and privatisation of electricity distribution and supply businesses in England and Wales: A social cost–benefit analysis. Fiscal Studies, 22, 107–146.CrossRef
go back to reference Eckenrod, S. (2006). Incentive regulation in local telecommunications: The effects on price markups. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 30(2), 217–231.CrossRef Eckenrod, S. (2006). Incentive regulation in local telecommunications: The effects on price markups. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 30(2), 217–231.CrossRef
go back to reference Hellwig, M., Schober, D., & Cabral, L. (2020). Low-powered vs high-powered incentives: Evidence from German electricity networks. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 73, 1–30.CrossRef Hellwig, M., Schober, D., & Cabral, L. (2020). Low-powered vs high-powered incentives: Evidence from German electricity networks. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 73, 1–30.CrossRef
go back to reference Kahn, A. (1970). The economics of regulation: Economic principles (Vol. I). John Wiley and Sons. Kahn, A. (1970). The economics of regulation: Economic principles (Vol. I). John Wiley and Sons.
go back to reference Kahn, A. (1971). The economics of regulation: Institutional issues (Vol. II). Wiley. Kahn, A. (1971). The economics of regulation: Institutional issues (Vol. II). Wiley.
go back to reference Kahn, A., Tardiff, T., & Weisman, D. (1999). The 1996 telecommunications act at three years: An economic evaluation of its implementation by the FCC. Information Economics and Policy, 11, 319–365.CrossRef Kahn, A., Tardiff, T., & Weisman, D. (1999). The 1996 telecommunications act at three years: An economic evaluation of its implementation by the FCC. Information Economics and Policy, 11, 319–365.CrossRef
go back to reference Kolbe, L., & Tye, W. (1991). The Duquesne opinion: How much ‘hope’ is there for investors in regulated firms? Yale Journal on Regulation, 8(1), 113–157. Kolbe, L., & Tye, W. (1991). The Duquesne opinion: How much ‘hope’ is there for investors in regulated firms? Yale Journal on Regulation, 8(1), 113–157.
go back to reference Kridel, D., Sappington, D., & Weisman, D. (1996). The effects of incentive regulation in the telecommunications industry: A survey. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 9(3), 269–306.CrossRef Kridel, D., Sappington, D., & Weisman, D. (1996). The effects of incentive regulation in the telecommunications industry: A survey. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 9(3), 269–306.CrossRef
go back to reference Laffont, J., & Tirole, J. (1993). A theory of incentives in procurement and regulation. The MIT Press. Laffont, J., & Tirole, J. (1993). A theory of incentives in procurement and regulation. The MIT Press.
go back to reference Lyon, T. (1996). A model of sliding scale regulation. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 9(3), 227–247.CrossRef Lyon, T. (1996). A model of sliding scale regulation. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 9(3), 227–247.CrossRef
go back to reference McNulty, P. (1968). Economic theory and the meaning of competition. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 82(4), 639–656.CrossRef McNulty, P. (1968). Economic theory and the meaning of competition. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 82(4), 639–656.CrossRef
go back to reference Nordhaus, W. (1969). Invention, growth, and welfare: A theoretical treatment of technological change. The MIT Press. Nordhaus, W. (1969). Invention, growth, and welfare: A theoretical treatment of technological change. The MIT Press.
go back to reference Pint, E. (1992). Price-cap versus rate-of-return regulation in a stochastic cost model. Rand Journal of Economics, 23(4), 564–578.CrossRef Pint, E. (1992). Price-cap versus rate-of-return regulation in a stochastic cost model. Rand Journal of Economics, 23(4), 564–578.CrossRef
go back to reference Posner, R. (1971). Taxation by regulation. Bell Journal of Economics, 2, 22–50. Posner, R. (1971). Taxation by regulation. Bell Journal of Economics, 2, 22–50.
go back to reference Resende, M. (2000). Regulatory regimes and efficiency in U.S. local telephony. Oxford Economic Papers, 52(3), 447–470.CrossRef Resende, M. (2000). Regulatory regimes and efficiency in U.S. local telephony. Oxford Economic Papers, 52(3), 447–470.CrossRef
go back to reference Sappington, D. (1994). Designing incentive regulation. Review of Industrial Organization, 9(3), 245–272.CrossRef Sappington, D. (1994). Designing incentive regulation. Review of Industrial Organization, 9(3), 245–272.CrossRef
go back to reference Sappington, D. (2002). Price regulation. In M. Cave, S. Majumdar, & I. Vogelsang (Eds.), Handbook of telecommunications economics (pp. 225–293). Amsterdam: North-Holland. Sappington, D. (2002). Price regulation. In M. Cave, S. Majumdar, & I. Vogelsang (Eds.), Handbook of telecommunications economics (pp. 225–293). Amsterdam: North-Holland.
go back to reference Sappington, D., & Weisman, D. (1996). Designing incentive regulation for the telecommunications industry. MIT Press. Sappington, D., & Weisman, D. (1996). Designing incentive regulation for the telecommunications industry. MIT Press.
go back to reference Sappington, D., & Weisman, D. (2010). Price cap regulation: What have we learned from twenty-five years of experience in the telecommunications industry? Journal of Regulatory Economics, 38, 227–257.CrossRef Sappington, D., & Weisman, D. (2010). Price cap regulation: What have we learned from twenty-five years of experience in the telecommunications industry? Journal of Regulatory Economics, 38, 227–257.CrossRef
go back to reference Scherer, F. (1972). Nordhaus’ theory of optimal patent life: A geometric reinterpretation. The American Economic Review, 62(3), 422–427. Scherer, F. (1972). Nordhaus’ theory of optimal patent life: A geometric reinterpretation. The American Economic Review, 62(3), 422–427.
go back to reference Schmalensee, R. (1989). Good regulatory regimes. Rand Journal of Economics, 20(3), 417–436.CrossRef Schmalensee, R. (1989). Good regulatory regimes. Rand Journal of Economics, 20(3), 417–436.CrossRef
go back to reference Schumpeter, J. (1942). Capitalism, socialism and democracy. Harper & Brothers. Schumpeter, J. (1942). Capitalism, socialism and democracy. Harper & Brothers.
go back to reference Seo, D., & Shin, J. (2011). The impact of incentive regulation on productivity in the US telecommunications industry: A stochastic frontier approach. Information Economics and Policy, 23, 3–11.CrossRef Seo, D., & Shin, J. (2011). The impact of incentive regulation on productivity in the US telecommunications industry: A stochastic frontier approach. Information Economics and Policy, 23, 3–11.CrossRef
go back to reference Shleifer, A. (1985). A theory of yardstick competition. Rand Journal of Economics, 16(3), 319–327.CrossRef Shleifer, A. (1985). A theory of yardstick competition. Rand Journal of Economics, 16(3), 319–327.CrossRef
go back to reference Uri, N. (2001). Productivity change, technical progress, and efficiency improvements in telecommunications. Review of Industrial Organization, 18, 283–300.CrossRef Uri, N. (2001). Productivity change, technical progress, and efficiency improvements in telecommunications. Review of Industrial Organization, 18, 283–300.CrossRef
go back to reference Weisman, D. (1993). Superior regulatory regimes in theory and practice. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 5(4), 355–366.CrossRef Weisman, D. (1993). Superior regulatory regimes in theory and practice. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 5(4), 355–366.CrossRef
go back to reference Weisman, D. (2019a). Regulatory takings without confiscatory returns. Yale Journal on Regulation Bulletin, 36, 170–195. Weisman, D. (2019a). Regulatory takings without confiscatory returns. Yale Journal on Regulation Bulletin, 36, 170–195.
go back to reference Weisman, D. (2019b). The power of regulatory regimes reexamined. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 56(2–3), 125–148.CrossRef Weisman, D. (2019b). The power of regulatory regimes reexamined. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 56(2–3), 125–148.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Measuring the Power of Regulatory Regimes
Author
Dennis L. Weisman
Publication date
02-09-2022
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Review of Industrial Organization / Issue 1/2023
Print ISSN: 0889-938X
Electronic ISSN: 1573-7160
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-022-09879-6

Other articles of this Issue 1/2023

Review of Industrial Organization 1/2023 Go to the issue