Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Constitutional Political Economy 2/2018

15-02-2018 | Original Paper

Medieval representative assemblies: collective action and antecedents of limited government

Authors: Alexander William Salter, Andrew T. Young

Published in: Constitutional Political Economy | Issue 2/2018

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Medieval monarchs in Western Europe responded to financial and military pressures by instituting representative assemblies. Three estates (classes; orders) were represented in these assemblies: clergy, nobility, and burghers. In the late medieval and early modern periods, some states tended towards absolutism (e.g., France); others towards constitutional monarchy (e.g., England). The German historian Otto Hintze conjectured that two-chamber assemblies were more likely to resist monarchical encroachments on their political authority than three-chamber assemblies. We argue that the two- versus three-chamber distinction is coincidental to what was truly relevant: whether chambers were estate-based or had mixed representation from multiple estates. We provide a comparative institutional analysis that emphasizes political bargaining and the costs of expressing special versus common interests. This analysis suggests that mixed representation assemblies, all else equal, provided a stronger check on absolutism than their estate-based counterparts. We also provide historical case studies of France and England that lend insights into why an estate-based Estates General arose in the former, while a mixed representation Parliament arose in the latter.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Footnotes
1
Charles Tilly (1990) linked the growth in medieval and early-modern European state capacity to monarchs’ needs to finance military spending, something which Besley and Persson (2009, p. 1218) characterize as “an archetypal public good representing broadly common interests for citizens.” (Alternatively, Gennaioli and Voth (2015) note that war was often the “sport of kings” and more aptly characterized as a private good.) Ertman (1997) emphasizes the relative ability of different early-modern European nation states to develop merit-based bureaucracies; Charron et al. (2012) subsequently argue the early development of such bureaucracies is more fundamental to accounting for variation in modern-day governance quality in OECD countries than are countries’ legal origins (La Porta et al. 2008). Regarding recent history, Johnson (1982), Amsden (1989), Wade (1990), and Evans (1995) attribute the economic growth successes in East Asia to governments with high state capacity; Herbst (2000) and Centeno (2002) argue that low state capacity is a source of development failure in Africa and Latin America, respectively.
 
2
Admitting this is not to deny that investments in fiscal and legal capacity can be complementary. For example, a state that provides rule of law and opportunities for wealth creation to its citizens (high legal capacity) will likely face less resistance to/avoidance of its efforts to collect taxes; hence higher returns to its existing fiscal capacity.
 
3
We also take as a historical given that, more general, representative assemblies uniquely arose in Europe. Stasavage (2016) provides an excellent review of the large literature exploring why this may have been the case.
 
4
Stasavage (2010) and Van Zanden et al. (2012) construct these original datasets on assembly activity. Abramson and Boix (2014) study employs data from both of those datasets. Bologna Pavlik and Young (2017) report evidence, based on the Stasavage (2010) data, that medieval/early-modern representative assembly experiences robustly correlate with present-day income levels and measures of the rule of law.
 
5
Young (2016) illustrates those collective action problems with the historical example of the roving Visigothic confederacy in the fourth and fifth centuries as it transitioned towards the stationary Visigothic Kingdom. Young (2017a) explores the constitutional political economy of the Visigothic and other barbarian settlements in the twilight of the Western Roman Empire.
 
6
We use the term polycentric in the sense of Ostrom et al. (1961) and Ostrom (2010): a system of governance with multiple decision-making centers that are formally independent of each other but, together, may function in an interdependent system of relationships. See also Aligica and Tarko (2014).
 
7
E.g., a noble lorded over a realm constituted by his own demesnes and benefices bestowed upon his vassals. The lord was a governance provider for his vassals. Those vassals, in return, owed military service and a share of the produce from their benefices. Providing security and justice to the overall realm, then, generated returns for the lord and vassals alike.
 
8
The feudal hierarchy emanated down from monarchs in a cascade of overlapping jurisdictions. A monarch was lord over a realm that included benefices bestowed upon his vassals; his vassals were principle nobles who bestowed benefices upon their own vassals; etc.
 
9
For example, if a lord attempted to expropriate resources from a vassal above and beyond his feudal obligations, the vassal could appeal to the lord’s lord (e.g., a principle noble or monarch) who was an overarching governance provider. Serfs were limited by being legally tied to their lords' lands and their ability to "vote with their feet" may have been quite limited until the Black Death (mid-1300 s) decreased the labor-to-land ratio and increased their de facto bargaining power. However, North and Thomas (1971, 1973) argue that Western European serfs had meaningful opportunities to "illegally steal away to seek asylum on another manor or, somewhat later, in one of the growing number of medieval towns" throughout the High Middle Ages (1971, p. 788). Note also that the legal maxim, city air makes you free, developed prior to the Black Death; a serf that managed to reside within a chartered city for a year and a day became a free individual (Young 2017b).
 
10
Literary references to a tripartite system of estates can be found dating back to at least the eleventh century (Duby 1980[1978]).
 
11
A number of scholars have emphasized the rough balance of power between medieval monarchs and political powerful estates: e.g., Weber 1978 [1922]; Hintze 1975 [1931]; Baechler 1975; Berman 1983; Downing 1988, 1989, 1992; Anderson 1991; Raico 1994; Finer 1997; Stark 2011, chs. 14–16.
 
12
Medieval cities were important sources of wealth and administrative human capital to both monarchs and the nobility. As such, they had political bargaining power to play alternative lords off one another.
 
13
The credible commitment story appears consistent with the weakness of European monarchs (relative to those of China and the Middle East) and their lack of effective, centralized bureaucracies (e.g, Wickham 2009; North 1990; Brennan and Buchanan 2006). Tridmas (2016) moves beyond the constitutional exchange theories of the rise of representative government to explore the reasons that monarchs may eventually withdraw from active governance.
 
14
Quoted and translated by Ertman (1997, p. 21).
 
15
Hintze employed the somewhat confusing terminology of estate-based and territorially based to refer to, respectively, three-chamber and two-chamber assemblies. This terminology incorrectly suggests that representation in three-chamber assemblies was not at all territorially based. In truth, both types of assemblies drew representation from the various territories of a monarch’s realm. For a stylized example, both a three-chamber and two-chamber assembly might have drawn one noble, one clergyman, and one burgher from each territory. However, in the case of the three-chamber (estate-based) assembly, all nobles, clergymen, and burghers would have met in their respective chambers.
 
16
Buchanan and Tullock (1962, ch. 16) is an early analysis of how assembly structure relates to coalitions of representatives being able to exert control of chambers, logroll across them, and rent seek.
 
17
While aggressive military campaigning could generate benefits in the form of plunder and new lands it is unlikely that those benefits would be enjoyed broadly. Members of the second estate would have captured most of the benefits, expecting to keep much of what they plundered as compensation for their military services.
 
18
See Fukuyama (2011, ch. 13) for an overview; also Bisson (2009, pp. 197–212), Southern (1992 [1953], ch. 3), and Wickham (2016, pp. 113–117).
 
19
In this case, powers were granted to the effective monarch. As Mayor of the Palace, Charles ruled for puppet Merovingian monarchs until, after the death of King Theuderic IV, he continued his rule with an empty throne. His son, Pippin III, subsequently assumed the Frankish throne. See Sect. 5 below.
 
20
Decision-making rules were sometimes different for the different chambers of a single assembly. For example, in Catalonia the chambers of the clergy and cities each operated based on majority rule while the nobility required unanimity (Lord 1930, p. 37; Myers 1975, p. 64). Alternatively, in Aragon each of the four estates operated based on a unanimity rule (Myers 1975, p. 32); this was also the case, at least while considering taxes, for the assembly of Castile, the Holy Roman Empire’s Reichstag, the Dutch Republic, and the Swiss Riksdag (Lord 1930, p. 37).
 
21
Though political scientists and political economists have long recognized the phenomenon of logrolling, Tullock (1959) and Buchanan and Tullock’s (1962) are the seminal works that spawned the modern literature on the subject. Important theoretical and empirical that followed include Tullock (1970), Riker and Brams (1973), Ferejohn (1986), Stratmann (1992, 1995), and Carrubba and Volden (2000) For reviews of that subsequent literature see Miller (1977) and Mueller (2003, ch. 5).
 
22
Askoy provides evidence based on European Union legislative proposals that is consistent with this argument.
 
23
When not referenced otherwise specifically, many factual details regarding the Carolingians are drawn from Riché (1993 [1983]).
 
24
In 747 Carloman decided (whether voluntarily or not we will never know) to withdraw from secular politics and join the clergy in Rome.
 
25
The Great Schism between the Western and Eastern Churches would not occur until 1054. However, even in the early medieval period the competition between the Roman papacy and patriarchy of Constantinople for spiritual authority was an important one. On the relationships between early Carolingians and the Church see Riché (1993 [1983], pp. 293–295), Pirenne (2001 [1937], pp. 221–224), and Wickham (2009, pp. 376–377).
 
Literature
go back to reference Abramson, S., & Boix, C. (2014). The roots of the Industrial Revolution: Political institutions or (historically embedded) know-how? Princeton University Working Paper. Abramson, S., & Boix, C. (2014). The roots of the Industrial Revolution: Political institutions or (historically embedded) know-how? Princeton University Working Paper.
go back to reference Acemoglu, D., Garcia-Jimeno, C., & Robinson, J. A. (2015). State capacity and economic development: A network approach. American Economic Review, 105, 2364–2409.CrossRef Acemoglu, D., Garcia-Jimeno, C., & Robinson, J. A. (2015). State capacity and economic development: A network approach. American Economic Review, 105, 2364–2409.CrossRef
go back to reference Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2005). Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth. In E. Duflo, A. Banerjee (Eds.), Handbook of economic growth (Vol. 1A, pp. 385–472) Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2005). Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth. In E. Duflo, A. Banerjee (Eds.), Handbook of economic growth (Vol. 1A, pp. 385–472)
go back to reference Acemoglu, D., Moscona, J., & Robinson, J. A. (2016). State capacity and American technology: Evidence from the 19th century. American Economic Review (forthcoming). Acemoglu, D., Moscona, J., & Robinson, J. A. (2016). State capacity and American technology: Evidence from the 19th century. American Economic Review (forthcoming).
go back to reference Acemoglu, D., Ticchi, D., & Vindigni, A. (2011). Emergence and persistence of inefficient states. Journal of the European Economic Association, 9, 177–208.CrossRef Acemoglu, D., Ticchi, D., & Vindigni, A. (2011). Emergence and persistence of inefficient states. Journal of the European Economic Association, 9, 177–208.CrossRef
go back to reference Aksoy, D. (2012). Institutional arrangements and logrolling: Evidence from the European Union. American Political Science Review, 56, 538–552.CrossRef Aksoy, D. (2012). Institutional arrangements and logrolling: Evidence from the European Union. American Political Science Review, 56, 538–552.CrossRef
go back to reference Aligica, P. D., & Tarko, V. (2014). Institutional resilience and economic systems: lessons from Elinor Ostrom’s work. Comparative Economic Studies, 56, 52–76.CrossRef Aligica, P. D., & Tarko, V. (2014). Institutional resilience and economic systems: lessons from Elinor Ostrom’s work. Comparative Economic Studies, 56, 52–76.CrossRef
go back to reference Anderson, J. L. (1991). Explaining long-term economic change. London: Macmillian.CrossRef Anderson, J. L. (1991). Explaining long-term economic change. London: Macmillian.CrossRef
go back to reference Asbridge, T. (2004). The first crusade: A new history. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Asbridge, T. (2004). The first crusade: A new history. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Baechler, J. (1975). The origins of capitalism. Oxford: Basil Blackwell. Baechler, J. (1975). The origins of capitalism. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
go back to reference Benson, B. L. (1989). The spontaneous evolution of commercial law. Southern Economic Journal, 55, 644–661.CrossRef Benson, B. L. (1989). The spontaneous evolution of commercial law. Southern Economic Journal, 55, 644–661.CrossRef
go back to reference Berman, H. J. (1983). Law and revolution: The Formation of the Western Legal Tradition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Berman, H. J. (1983). Law and revolution: The Formation of the Western Legal Tradition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
go back to reference Besley, T., & Persson, T. (2009). The origins of state capacity: Property rights, taxation, and politics. American Economic Review, 99, 1218–1244.CrossRef Besley, T., & Persson, T. (2009). The origins of state capacity: Property rights, taxation, and politics. American Economic Review, 99, 1218–1244.CrossRef
go back to reference Besley, T., & Persson, T. (2010). State capacity, conflict, and development. Econometrica, 78, 1–34.CrossRef Besley, T., & Persson, T. (2010). State capacity, conflict, and development. Econometrica, 78, 1–34.CrossRef
go back to reference Besley, T., & Persson, T. (2011). Pillars of prosperity: The political economics of development clusters. New Haven, CT: Princeton University Press.CrossRef Besley, T., & Persson, T. (2011). Pillars of prosperity: The political economics of development clusters. New Haven, CT: Princeton University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Bisson, T. N. (2009). The crisis of the twelfth century: Power, lordship, and the origins of European government. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRef Bisson, T. N. (2009). The crisis of the twelfth century: Power, lordship, and the origins of European government. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Bloch, M. (1968a [1939]). Feudal society: Volume 1—the growth of ties of dependence. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Bloch, M. (1968a [1939]). Feudal society: Volume 1—the growth of ties of dependence. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
go back to reference Bloch, M. (1968b [1940]). Feudal society: Volume 2—social classes and political organization. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Bloch, M. (1968b [1940]). Feudal society: Volume 2—social classes and political organization. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
go back to reference Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. M. (2006). The power to tax: Analytical foundations of fiscal constitution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. M. (2006). The power to tax: Analytical foundations of fiscal constitution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Brown, A. L. (1989). The governance of late medieval England (pp. 1272–1461). London: Edward Arnold. Brown, A. L. (1989). The governance of late medieval England (pp. 1272–1461). London: Edward Arnold.
go back to reference Buchanan, J. M. (1975). The limits of liberty: Between anarchy and leviathan. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Buchanan, J. M. (1975). The limits of liberty: Between anarchy and leviathan. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
go back to reference Buchanan, J. M., & Congleton, R. D. (2003 [1998]). Politics by principle, not interest: Towards nondiscriminatory democracy. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund. Buchanan, J. M., & Congleton, R. D. (2003 [1998]). Politics by principle, not interest: Towards nondiscriminatory democracy. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.
go back to reference Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent: Logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRef Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent: Logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Cam, H. M. (1953). The theory and practice of representation in medieval England. History, 38, 11–26.CrossRef Cam, H. M. (1953). The theory and practice of representation in medieval England. History, 38, 11–26.CrossRef
go back to reference Campbell, J. (1986a). Observations on English government from the tenth to the twelfth centuries. In Essays in Anglo-Saxon history. London: Hambledon Press. Campbell, J. (1986a). Observations on English government from the tenth to the twelfth centuries. In Essays in Anglo-Saxon history. London: Hambledon Press.
go back to reference Campbell, J. (1986b). The significance of the Anglo-Norma state in the administrative history of Western Europe. In Essays in Anglo-Saxon history. London: Hambledon Press. Campbell, J. (1986b). The significance of the Anglo-Norma state in the administrative history of Western Europe. In Essays in Anglo-Saxon history. London: Hambledon Press.
go back to reference Carrubba, C. J., & Volden, C. (2000). Coalitional politics and logrolling in legislative institutions. Journal of Politics, 59, 469–496.CrossRef Carrubba, C. J., & Volden, C. (2000). Coalitional politics and logrolling in legislative institutions. Journal of Politics, 59, 469–496.CrossRef
go back to reference Coll, S. (2008). The origins and evolution of democracy: An exercise in history from a constitutional economic approach. Constitutional Political Economy, 19(4), 313–355.CrossRef Coll, S. (2008). The origins and evolution of democracy: An exercise in history from a constitutional economic approach. Constitutional Political Economy, 19(4), 313–355.CrossRef
go back to reference Congleton, R. D. (2001). On the durability of king and council: The continuum between dictatorship and democracy. Constitutional Political Economy, 12(3), 193–215.CrossRef Congleton, R. D. (2001). On the durability of king and council: The continuum between dictatorship and democracy. Constitutional Political Economy, 12(3), 193–215.CrossRef
go back to reference Congleton, R. D. (2007). From royal to parliamentary rule without revolution: The economics of constitutional exchange within divided governments. European Journal of Political Economy, 23, 261–284.CrossRef Congleton, R. D. (2007). From royal to parliamentary rule without revolution: The economics of constitutional exchange within divided governments. European Journal of Political Economy, 23, 261–284.CrossRef
go back to reference Congleton, R. D. (2011). Perfecting Parliament: Constitutional Reform, Liberalism, and the Rise of Western Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Congleton, R. D. (2011). Perfecting Parliament: Constitutional Reform, Liberalism, and the Rise of Western Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Congleton, R. D. (2013). On the inevitability of divided government and a complete separation of powers. Constitutional Political Economy, 24(3), 177–198.CrossRef Congleton, R. D. (2013). On the inevitability of divided government and a complete separation of powers. Constitutional Political Economy, 24(3), 177–198.CrossRef
go back to reference de Figueiredo, R. J. P., Jr., & Weingast, B. R. (2005). Self-enforcing federalism. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 21, 103–135.CrossRef de Figueiredo, R. J. P., Jr., & Weingast, B. R. (2005). Self-enforcing federalism. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 21, 103–135.CrossRef
go back to reference de Jong, M. (2005). Charlemagne’s church. In J. Story (Ed.), Charlemagne: Empire and society (pp. 103–135). New York, NY: Manchester University Press. de Jong, M. (2005). Charlemagne’s church. In J. Story (Ed.), Charlemagne: Empire and society (pp. 103–135). New York, NY: Manchester University Press.
go back to reference Downing, B. M. (1988). Constitutionalism, warfare, and political change in early modern Europe. Theory and Society, 17, 7–56.CrossRef Downing, B. M. (1988). Constitutionalism, warfare, and political change in early modern Europe. Theory and Society, 17, 7–56.CrossRef
go back to reference Downing, B. M. (1989). Medieval origins of constitutional government in the West. Theory and Society, 18, 213–247.CrossRef Downing, B. M. (1989). Medieval origins of constitutional government in the West. Theory and Society, 18, 213–247.CrossRef
go back to reference Downing, B. M. (1992). the military revolution and political change: Origins of democracy and autocracy in early modern Europe. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Downing, B. M. (1992). the military revolution and political change: Origins of democracy and autocracy in early modern Europe. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Duby, G. (1980 [1978]). The three orders: feudal society imagined. (tr: Goldhammer, A.). Chicago, IL: Chicago University Press. Duby, G. (1980 [1978]). The three orders: feudal society imagined. (tr: Goldhammer, A.). Chicago, IL: Chicago University Press.
go back to reference Ertman, T. (1997). Birth of the Leviathan. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Ertman, T. (1997). Birth of the Leviathan. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Ferejohn, J. (1986). Logrolling in an institutional context: A case study of food stamps legislation. In G. Wright, L. Rieselbach, & L. Dodd (Eds.), European community decision making: Models, applications, and comparisons (pp. 223–253). New York, NY: Agathon Press. Ferejohn, J. (1986). Logrolling in an institutional context: A case study of food stamps legislation. In G. Wright, L. Rieselbach, & L. Dodd (Eds.), European community decision making: Models, applications, and comparisons (pp. 223–253). New York, NY: Agathon Press.
go back to reference Finer, S. (1997). The history of government, Vol. I–III. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Finer, S. (1997). The history of government, Vol. I–III. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Fukuyama, F. (2011). The origins of political order: From prehuman times to the French revolution. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux. Fukuyama, F. (2011). The origins of political order: From prehuman times to the French revolution. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.
go back to reference Gennaioli, N., & Voth, H.-J. (2015). State capacity and military conflict. Review of Economic Studies, 82, 1409–1448.CrossRef Gennaioli, N., & Voth, H.-J. (2015). State capacity and military conflict. Review of Economic Studies, 82, 1409–1448.CrossRef
go back to reference Glaeser, E., & Shleifer, A. (2002). Legal origins. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 1193–1229.CrossRef Glaeser, E., & Shleifer, A. (2002). Legal origins. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 1193–1229.CrossRef
go back to reference González de Lara, Y. G., Greif, A., & Jha, S. (2008). The administrative foundation of self- enforcing constitutions. American Political Science Review, 98, 105–109. González de Lara, Y. G., Greif, A., & Jha, S. (2008). The administrative foundation of self- enforcing constitutions. American Political Science Review, 98, 105–109.
go back to reference Greif, A. (2006). Institutions and the path to the modern economy: Lessons from medieval trade. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Greif, A. (2006). Institutions and the path to the modern economy: Lessons from medieval trade. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Heather, P. (2009). Empires and barbarians: The fall of Rome and the birth of Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Heather, P. (2009). Empires and barbarians: The fall of Rome and the birth of Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Hintze, O. (1970 [1930]). Typologie der standischen verfassungen des abendlandes. In, Staat und Verfassung: Gesammelte Abhandlungen zur Allgemeinen Verfassungsgeschichte. Göttingen, Germany: Vandenhoeck & Ruprecht. Hintze, O. (1970 [1930]). Typologie der standischen verfassungen des abendlandes. In, Staat und Verfassung: Gesammelte Abhandlungen zur Allgemeinen Verfassungsgeschichte. Göttingen, Germany: Vandenhoeck & Ruprecht.
go back to reference Hintze, O. (1975 [1931]). The preconditions of representative government in the context of world history. In Gilbert, P. (Ed.). The historical essays of otto hintze. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Hintze, O. (1975 [1931]). The preconditions of representative government in the context of world history. In Gilbert, P. (Ed.). The historical essays of otto hintze. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Hollister, C. W., & Baldwin, J. (1978). The rise of administrative kingship: Henry I and Philip Augustus. American Historical Review, 83, 867–905.CrossRef Hollister, C. W., & Baldwin, J. (1978). The rise of administrative kingship: Henry I and Philip Augustus. American Historical Review, 83, 867–905.CrossRef
go back to reference La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2008). The economic consequences of legal origins. Journal of Economic Literature, 46, 285–332.CrossRef La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2008). The economic consequences of legal origins. Journal of Economic Literature, 46, 285–332.CrossRef
go back to reference La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1997). Legal determinants of external finance. The Journal of Finance, 52, 1131–1150.CrossRef La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1997). Legal determinants of external finance. The Journal of Finance, 52, 1131–1150.CrossRef
go back to reference Leeson, P. T. (2011). Government, clubs, and constitutions. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 80, 301–308.CrossRef Leeson, P. T. (2011). Government, clubs, and constitutions. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 80, 301–308.CrossRef
go back to reference Lord, R. H. (1930). The parliaments of the Middle Ages and the early modern period. Catholic Historical Review, 16, 125–144. Lord, R. H. (1930). The parliaments of the Middle Ages and the early modern period. Catholic Historical Review, 16, 125–144.
go back to reference Loyn, H. R. (1984). The governance of Anglo Saxon England, 500–1087. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Loyn, H. R. (1984). The governance of Anglo Saxon England, 500–1087. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
go back to reference Mathisen, R. (1993). Roman aristocrats in barbarian Gaul: Strategies for survival in an age of transition. Austin: University of Texas Press. Mathisen, R. (1993). Roman aristocrats in barbarian Gaul: Strategies for survival in an age of transition. Austin: University of Texas Press.
go back to reference McCloskey, D. (2016). Bourgeois equality: How ideas, not capital or institutions, enriched the world. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. McCloskey, D. (2016). Bourgeois equality: How ideas, not capital or institutions, enriched the world. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
go back to reference Miller, N. R. (1977). Logrolling, vote-trading, and the paradox of voting: A game-theoretic overview. Public Choice, 30, 51–75.CrossRef Miller, N. R. (1977). Logrolling, vote-trading, and the paradox of voting: A game-theoretic overview. Public Choice, 30, 51–75.CrossRef
go back to reference Mittal, S., & Weingast, B. R. (2011). Self-enforcing constitutions: with an application to democratic stability in America’s first century. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 29, 278–302.CrossRef Mittal, S., & Weingast, B. R. (2011). Self-enforcing constitutions: with an application to democratic stability in America’s first century. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 29, 278–302.CrossRef
go back to reference Mueller, D. C. (2003). Public Choice III. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Mueller, D. C. (2003). Public Choice III. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Mundy, J. H., & Riesenberg, P. (1958). The medieval town. Malabar, FL: Robert E. Krieger Publishing Company. Mundy, J. H., & Riesenberg, P. (1958). The medieval town. Malabar, FL: Robert E. Krieger Publishing Company.
go back to reference Myers, A. R. (1975). Parliaments and estates in Europe to 1789. London: Thames & Hudson. Myers, A. R. (1975). Parliaments and estates in Europe to 1789. London: Thames & Hudson.
go back to reference North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference North, D. C., & Thomas, R. P. (1971). The rise and fall of the manorial system: A theoretical model. Journal of Economic History, 31(4), 777–803.CrossRef North, D. C., & Thomas, R. P. (1971). The rise and fall of the manorial system: A theoretical model. Journal of Economic History, 31(4), 777–803.CrossRef
go back to reference North, D. C., & Thomas, R. P. (1973). The rise of the western world: A new economic history. London: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef North, D. C., & Thomas, R. P. (1973). The rise of the western world: A new economic history. London: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference North, D., Wallis, J. J., & Weingast, B. R. (2009). Violence and social orders: A conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human history. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef North, D., Wallis, J. J., & Weingast, B. R. (2009). Violence and social orders: A conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human history. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference North, D. C., & Weingast, B. R. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. Journal of Economic History, 49, 803–832.CrossRef North, D. C., & Weingast, B. R. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. Journal of Economic History, 49, 803–832.CrossRef
go back to reference Ostrom, E. (2010). Beyond markets and states: Polycentric governance of complex economic systems. American Economic Review, 100, 641–672.CrossRef Ostrom, E. (2010). Beyond markets and states: Polycentric governance of complex economic systems. American Economic Review, 100, 641–672.CrossRef
go back to reference Ostrom, V., Tiebout, C. M., & Warren, R. (1961). The organization of government in metropolitan areas: A theoretical inquiry. American Political Science Review, 55, 831–842.CrossRef Ostrom, V., Tiebout, C. M., & Warren, R. (1961). The organization of government in metropolitan areas: A theoretical inquiry. American Political Science Review, 55, 831–842.CrossRef
go back to reference Pirenne, H. (2001 [1937]). Mohammed and charlemagne. Mineola, NY: Dover Books. Pirenne, H. (2001 [1937]). Mohammed and charlemagne. Mineola, NY: Dover Books.
go back to reference Qian, Y., & Weingast, B. R. (1997). Federalism as a commitment to preserving market incentives. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11, 83–92.CrossRef Qian, Y., & Weingast, B. R. (1997). Federalism as a commitment to preserving market incentives. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11, 83–92.CrossRef
go back to reference Raico, R. (1994). The theory of economic development and the ‘European miracle’. In Boettke (Ed.), The collapse of development planning. New York, NY: New York University Press. Raico, R. (1994). The theory of economic development and the ‘European miracle’. In Boettke (Ed.), The collapse of development planning. New York, NY: New York University Press.
go back to reference Riché, P. (1993 [1983]). The Carolingians: A Family who Forged Europe. (Allen, M. I., tr.) Philadelphia, PA: University of Pennsylvania Press. Riché, P. (1993 [1983]). The Carolingians: A Family who Forged Europe. (Allen, M. I., tr.) Philadelphia, PA: University of Pennsylvania Press.
go back to reference Riker, W., & Brams, S. (1973). Paradox of vote trading. American Political Science Review, 67, 1235–1247.CrossRef Riker, W., & Brams, S. (1973). Paradox of vote trading. American Political Science Review, 67, 1235–1247.CrossRef
go back to reference Russell, C. S. R. (1982). Monarchies, wars, and states in England, France, and Spain, c. 1580-1640. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 7, 205–220.CrossRef Russell, C. S. R. (1982). Monarchies, wars, and states in England, France, and Spain, c. 1580-1640. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 7, 205–220.CrossRef
go back to reference Salter, A. W. (2015a). Rights to the realm: reconsidering western political development. American Political Science Review, 109, 725–734.CrossRef Salter, A. W. (2015a). Rights to the realm: reconsidering western political development. American Political Science Review, 109, 725–734.CrossRef
go back to reference Salter, A. W. (2015b). Sovereignty as exchange of political property rights. Public Choice, 165, 79–96.CrossRef Salter, A. W. (2015b). Sovereignty as exchange of political property rights. Public Choice, 165, 79–96.CrossRef
go back to reference Southern, R. W. (1992 [1953]). The making of the middle ages. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Southern, R. W. (1992 [1953]). The making of the middle ages. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
go back to reference Stark, R. (2011). The Triumph of Christianity: How the Jesus Movement became the World’s Largest Religion. New York, NY: HarperCollins. Stark, R. (2011). The Triumph of Christianity: How the Jesus Movement became the World’s Largest Religion. New York, NY: HarperCollins.
go back to reference Stasavage, D. (2010). When distance mattered: Geographic scale and the development of European representative assemblies. American Political Science Review, 104, 625–643.CrossRef Stasavage, D. (2010). When distance mattered: Geographic scale and the development of European representative assemblies. American Political Science Review, 104, 625–643.CrossRef
go back to reference Stasavage, D. (2016). Representation and consent: Why they arose in Europe and not elsewhere. American Review of Political Science, 19, 145–162.CrossRef Stasavage, D. (2016). Representation and consent: Why they arose in Europe and not elsewhere. American Review of Political Science, 19, 145–162.CrossRef
go back to reference Stratmann, T. (1992). The effects of logrolling on congressional voting. American Economic Review, 82, 1162–1176. Stratmann, T. (1992). The effects of logrolling on congressional voting. American Economic Review, 82, 1162–1176.
go back to reference Stratmann, T. (1995). Logrolling in the U.S. Congress. Economic Inquiry, 33, 441–456.CrossRef Stratmann, T. (1995). Logrolling in the U.S. Congress. Economic Inquiry, 33, 441–456.CrossRef
go back to reference Tiebout, C. M. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy, 64, 416–424.CrossRef Tiebout, C. M. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy, 64, 416–424.CrossRef
go back to reference Tilly, C. (1990). Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 990-1990. Oxford: Blackwell. Tilly, C. (1990). Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 990-1990. Oxford: Blackwell.
go back to reference Tridmas, G. (2016). On the overthrow or endurance of kings. Constitutional Political Economy, 27(1), 41–65.CrossRef Tridmas, G. (2016). On the overthrow or endurance of kings. Constitutional Political Economy, 27(1), 41–65.CrossRef
go back to reference Tullock, G. (1959). Problems of majority voting. Journal of Political Economy, 67, 571–579.CrossRef Tullock, G. (1959). Problems of majority voting. Journal of Political Economy, 67, 571–579.CrossRef
go back to reference Tullock, G. (1970). A simple algebraic logrolling model. American Economic Review, 60, 419–426. Tullock, G. (1970). A simple algebraic logrolling model. American Economic Review, 60, 419–426.
go back to reference van Zanden, J., Buringh, E., & Bosker, M. (2012). The rise and decline of European parliaments, 1188-1789. Economic History Review, 65, 835–861.CrossRef van Zanden, J., Buringh, E., & Bosker, M. (2012). The rise and decline of European parliaments, 1188-1789. Economic History Review, 65, 835–861.CrossRef
go back to reference Vinogradoff, P. (1968 [1922]). Feudalism. Ch. 18 in (Gwatkin, Whitney, Tanner, Previté-Orton, eds.), The Cambridge Medieval History, Volume 3: Germany and the Western Empire. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press. Vinogradoff, P. (1968 [1922]). Feudalism. Ch. 18 in (Gwatkin, Whitney, Tanner, Previté-Orton, eds.), The Cambridge Medieval History, Volume 3: Germany and the Western Empire. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Wasson, E. A. (1998). The penetration of new wealth into the English governing class from the Middle Ages to the first world war. Economic History Review, 51, 25–48.CrossRef Wasson, E. A. (1998). The penetration of new wealth into the English governing class from the Middle Ages to the first world war. Economic History Review, 51, 25–48.CrossRef
go back to reference Weber, M. (1978 [1922]). Economy and Society (G. Roth, C. Wittich, eds.). New York, NY: Bedminster Press. Weber, M. (1978 [1922]). Economy and Society (G. Roth, C. Wittich, eds.). New York, NY: Bedminster Press.
go back to reference Weingast, B. R. (1993). Constitutions as governance structures: The political foundations of secure markets. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 1, 286–311. Weingast, B. R. (1993). Constitutions as governance structures: The political foundations of secure markets. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 1, 286–311.
go back to reference Weingast, B. R. (1995). The economic role of political institutions: Market-preserving federalism and economic development. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 11, 1–31. Weingast, B. R. (1995). The economic role of political institutions: Market-preserving federalism and economic development. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 11, 1–31.
go back to reference Wickham, C. (2009). The inheritance of Rome: Illuminating the dark ages 400–1000. London: Penguin Books. Wickham, C. (2009). The inheritance of Rome: Illuminating the dark ages 400–1000. London: Penguin Books.
go back to reference Wickham, C. (2016). Medieval Europe. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Wickham, C. (2016). Medieval Europe. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
go back to reference Young, A. T. (2016). What does it take for a roving bandit to settle down? Theory and an illustrative history of the Visigoths. Public Choice, 168, 75–102.CrossRef Young, A. T. (2016). What does it take for a roving bandit to settle down? Theory and an illustrative history of the Visigoths. Public Choice, 168, 75–102.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Medieval representative assemblies: collective action and antecedents of limited government
Authors
Alexander William Salter
Andrew T. Young
Publication date
15-02-2018
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Constitutional Political Economy / Issue 2/2018
Print ISSN: 1043-4062
Electronic ISSN: 1572-9966
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-018-9258-1

Other articles of this Issue 2/2018

Constitutional Political Economy 2/2018 Go to the issue