Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Constitutional Political Economy 4/2008

01.12.2008 | Original Paper

The origins and evolution of democracy: an exercise in history from a constitutional economics approach

verfasst von: Sebastian Coll

Erschienen in: Constitutional Political Economy | Ausgabe 4/2008

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

In this article the conditions for the rise and fall of representative regimes are explored. High citizen mobility and unexploited opportunities for investment create the need of reassuring factor owners against the tax hunger of the State. This may lead to the emergence of representative institutions of government, a process that reverts when those conditions disappear. Factors that facilitate or restrain the mobility of citizenry are identified, mainly in the domain of military technology. Thus, a number of interrelations between production and war technologies, political development and economic performance are revealed, giving rise to an interpretation of historical evolution.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
Again, Tullock (1987a) has to be credited as the first author in having made this distinction. The point has been further elaborated by Wintrobe (1990, 1998), whose “tinpot” dictator would correspond to Olson’s bandit king. On the other hand, Wintrobe’s insights on the process of a modern dictatorship’s decline don’t include a model of its replacement by a democracy. Nor did Tullock (1987a, b).
 
2
Taken in its broadest sense, the term tax rate could include the risk of expropriation as well.
 
3
Bates (1987, pp. 41–42). Italics in the original.
 
4
Anthropologist Birdsell (1973) has shown that the tribal stage is subject to the same dynamics of continuous division as prevailing in the society of bands whenever a critical size of population is reached. With sustained increase in population, the repeated division of the tribe should eventually come to an end, just the same as that in the prior band society and due to the same reasons.
 
5
To give but two examples, see Service (1975) as well as the articles collected by Claessen and Skalnik (1978).
 
6
Since I resort to a graphical solution of the model, I voluntarily avoid any attempt to further specify the function of Y to t and G. For a half hearted attempt, see Mueller (2003, ch. 18).
 
7
The point has been raised before by Friedman (1977), Rogowski (1998) and by other authors as cited in the first section of this paper.
 
8
See Fleck and Hanssen (2002) on classical Greece.
 
9
On the relationship between the problem of control and the economic organization, see Alchian and Demsetz (1972). Turning again to medieval peasants, another condition for the effectiveness of the stick alone was their concentration for work, which facilitated the control of their effort. This seems to be an explanation of the manorial system and the lords’ preference for labour surplus vs. product surplus extraction more convincing than the ones proposed by North and Thomas (1973) and by their critics.
 
10
Friedman (1977) mentions another alternative: the combination of several states into one in order to increase migration costs for traders. He cites some historical cases in which this occurred, and his list could be extended to account for the imperial expansion of former state-cities. However, the success of these attempts is often subject to the hazards of war. Hence, I tend to think that the “parliamentarian” solution is more common, at least in the short run. Once a parliament has been created, the possibility of restricting the movement of even agricultural labourers may be somewhat hampered. This observation could help to answer the questions of why serfdom was not generalised again in Europe after the Black Death restored the scarcity of agricultural manpower, or why the agricultural labourers could move freely in the scarcely populated British colonies of Northern America or Australia. However, one should not exaggerate the extent of freedom in cases like these: one has to take into account also the high numbers of slaves, intended servants and coerced convicts living in the latter territories.
 
11
With precedents dating back to Hume and Kant, that relationship has been outlined by Jones (1988) and by Baechler et al. (1989). The more recent attempt I know of is the collective book edited by Bernholz and Vaubel (2004).
 
12
See Dudley (1990, 1991, 1997). This author highlights also the effect on taxes, though not on political representation.
 
13
A further effect of gunpowder on internal politics resides in that, the more territory in the hands of the King as a result of the working of the two preceding factors, the lower became the probability for a given city to be close to the border and, hence, the lesser its ability to transfer its loyalty to another monarch. This factor acts as a feedback which reinforced the process of territorial concentration.
 
14
As François put it gracefully: “My cousin [Charles V] and I agree in everything: we both want Milan”. Milan meant dominion on the route through the Alps, which was tantamount to European hegemony.
 
15
At least for an author, Latzko (1993), it is even dubious that we can speak at all about economies of scale in warfare prior to the invention of firearms.
 
16
Though Dudley seems to be right in classifying the Roman military technology as one leading to increasing returns to scale, the fact remains that the Romans often crushed armies that outnumbered them by far. There is no puzzle, however, if those enemies used an inferior technology, as it seems to have been the case.
 
17
This point has been stressed by several historians of warfare and civilisation, from whom has been taken by Dudley. See in English McNeill (1963, 1976). Dudley credits Altheim (1952) with the merit.
 
18
A paradoxical feature of Roman politics is the continuity and spread of (nearly) democratic forms of government at the municipal level. However, in so far as the Pax Romana greatly reduced the cost of migrations between cities inside the Empire, this is what we had to expect according to our proposition. Now then, the power of cities to oppose an increase of imperial taxes remained low, also in accord to it.
 
19
In the meantime, confiscation of the fortunes of partisans of the Ancien Régime may serve to calm the thirst of redistribution, if needed.
 
20
I explicitly renounce to offer here one more review on the question of whether the founding fathers of US Constitution reflected in it their own economic interests or not. The pioneering study on this subject is that of Beard (1913). The most recent contribution to my knowledge, including a thorough review to all prior work, is McGuire (2003).
 
21
As with the case of the autocrat, McGuire and Olson (1996), as well as Niskanen (2003) have preceded us in this path. Here, too, our explanation differs from theirs to some extent.
 
22
By applying the rule of the chain one can be obtained from the other. If we prefer, we can consider them as one, and resort to another condition that has to be met. Since G = Y · t, his condition can be stated as Y/G = 1/t. This has an immediate application to the graphical method that we have chosen to follow in this contribution.
 
23
See Schofield (2004) for a detailed account of fiscal innovation under the Tudors. Regarding the power of the English Parliament, acknowledging of the principle “Redress before Supply” meant a substantial difference with respect to those existing in other countries.
 
24
The role of the Parliament as the cashier of the Army and its further consequences has been stressed by Tullock (1987a, b). For this author, however, the ultimate causes of the power of the Parliament in the English case remain “mysterious” (p. 183). Other factors pertaining to our list seem to have been at work as well. The question of how to pay war debts was present at least in the 1688 episode, which, in other respects, resembled those of the 1640s.
 
25
He also mentions that the initial strategy of the American representatives in Britain, trying to create division between King and Parliament and among parties inside the latter, proved wrong, given the good harmony between the two key institutions that existed under George III: frustration of this seemingly costless strategy eventually led the Americans to choose the more costly way of war. As another factor, Reid contends that the groups more damaged by the British measures to some extent alleviated the cost of Revolution to the rest of the population by taking on their shoulders the task of government.
 
26
How exactly it was related is a question more difficult to elucidate. In our simplified model, low taxation provides an incentive to work and to invest. Complexities of real life had led historians and economists to highlight other ways of influence, as are: more secure property rights including intellectual property; less room for rent seeking, and enhanced independence of the judiciary. Even a cursory explanation of these mechanisms and reference to the authors that have proposed them would demand more room than is available in this contribution.
 
27
See, for an instance, Holcombe (2002). Public beneficence existed at the time, nonetheless.
 
28
See Downs (1957), as well as Meltzer and Richard (1981, 1983). Regarding the synchrony between general enfranchisement and extensive redistribution, this is most apparent in Europe. It seems likely that abundance of land and the resulting higher incomes per capita have delayed the distributional struggle in North America with respect to Europe.
 
29
The citizen under the veil of ignorance wouldn’t know whether she is bound to be rich or poor in the future. If only for this reason, and provided that the marginal utility of money is decreasing, she may feel adequate to redistribute some rent from rich to poor through the fiscal system. For a pure utilitarian, how much is to be distributed would be the outcome of a balance between, on one hand, the utility of the transfer in case of being a pauper multiplied by the expected probability of become impoverished, and, on the other, the disutility of paying the taxes necessary to sustain the paupers by the probability of being among those who have to pay. From the social welfare function perspective the optimum is identical.
 
30
For the reasons explained in the precedent footnote, almost any person, when placed behind the veil of ignorance, would be favourable to some transfer to the orphan, the disabled, the homeless or the involuntarily unemployed. Now then, if the transfers, established through imperfect political markets, exceed those resulting from application of the above stated criterion, they may constitute an invitation for the worker to remain unemployed or to convert himself into the victim of a provoked accident, for the people not to buy houses, or to convert the foundation of a mono-parental family into a career.
 
31
This picture does not differ much from the predictions that can be made from the median voter models. Meltzer and Richard (1981) have shown that a considerable degree of vertical redistribution is possible even when the political decisions reflect the preferences of the median voter. The adverse consequences of this redistribution on growth could be big, but the outcome on social welfare wouldn’t be as adverse. Niskanen (2003) comes to more pessimistic predictions while attached to the median voter theory.
 
32
Again, McGuire and Olson (1996), as well as Niskanen (2003) have preceded us in the building of an equilibrium model of redistributive democracy. Again, however, our model differs somewhat from theirs.
 
33
For an extensive treatment, see Tullock (1989).
 
34
See, among others, Olson (1982, 1983), Choi (1983), Tang and Hedley (1998), Heckelman (2000), Coates and Heckelman (2003a, b), and Knack (2003).
 
35
Assessment of the relationships between public sector growth and the growth of income is plagued by serious econometric problems, though most contributions conclude that there is an inverse correlation. Among the immense literature published since the early 1980s, two papers that honestly acknowledge for these problems and attempt to solve them are De la Fuente (1997) and Fölster and Henrekson (1999). On the relationship between regulation and growth, see for instance Gwartney et al. (2004), Doucouliagos and Ulubasoglu (2006), Dawson (2006), and Weede (2006).
 
36
Practically limited to the contributions mentioned in footnote 32.
 
37
This is an implication of the communicable character of knowledge. The point has been extensively developed by growth economics and constitutes the cornerstone of the endogenous growth models.
 
38
This could be one of the reasons why the empirical literature that tries to measure the impact of distributional coalitions on economic growth hasn’t found big differences in the rates of growth of different countries, even when these appear to be subject to different pressures stemming from those coalitions (See references in footnote 34). Another reason could be that, as a result, the international differences in the extent to which governments pursue distributional goals aren’t so big after all. The same problem could affect the empirical literature that tries to assess the negative impact of public sector growth on overall economic growth (See references in footnote 35).
 
39
The number of contributions comparing the economic performance of democracies and dictatorships in our present World has increased quickly during the last years. Though the conclusion of this literature is mainly sceptical, this serves to illustrate the vulnerability of democracy to interest groups, as well as the fact that when an autocracy establishes in once democratic countries (usually with the applause of a part of the electorate), its behaviour may present important differences with that of more traditional autocracies, and resemble that of democracies in many respects… at least, as long as it allows for migration of people. As a sample, see Sirowy and Inkeles (1990), Przeworski and Limongi (1993), Farr et al. (1998), Wu and Davis (1999), Ali and Crain (2001, 2002), Tavares and Wacziarg (2001), Plümper and Martin (2003), and Mueller (2003, ch. 18).
 
40
See Tideman and Tullock (1976), Hylland and Zeckhauser (1979), and Tideman (1997).
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2005). Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2005). Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Alchian, A., & Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, information costs, and economic organization. American Economic Review, LXII, 777–795. Alchian, A., & Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, information costs, and economic organization. American Economic Review, LXII, 777–795.
Zurück zum Zitat Ali, A. M., & Crain, W. M. (2001). Political regimes, economic freedom, institutions and growth. Journal of Public Finance and Public Choice (PFPC)/Economia delle scelte pubbliche, XIX, 3–21. Ali, A. M., & Crain, W. M. (2001). Political regimes, economic freedom, institutions and growth. Journal of Public Finance and Public Choice (PFPC)/Economia delle scelte pubbliche, XIX, 3–21.
Zurück zum Zitat Ali, A. M., & Crain, W. M. (2002). Institutional distortions, economic freedom, and growth. Cato Journal, 21, 415–426. Ali, A. M., & Crain, W. M. (2002). Institutional distortions, economic freedom, and growth. Cato Journal, 21, 415–426.
Zurück zum Zitat Altheim, F. (1952). Niedergang der Alten Welt. Eine Untersuchung der Ursachen. Frankfurt. Altheim, F. (1952). Niedergang der Alten Welt. Eine Untersuchung der Ursachen. Frankfurt.
Zurück zum Zitat Baechler, J., Hall, J. A., & Mann, M. (Eds.). (1989). Europe and the rise of capitalism. Oxford: Blackwell. Baechler, J., Hall, J. A., & Mann, M. (Eds.). (1989). Europe and the rise of capitalism. Oxford: Blackwell.
Zurück zum Zitat Bates, R. H. (1987). The centralization of African societies. In Essays on the political economy of rural Africa (pp. 21–57). Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Bates, R. H. (1987). The centralization of African societies. In Essays on the political economy of rural Africa (pp. 21–57). Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Beard, C. A. (1965 [1913]). An economic interpretation of the Constitution of the United States. New York: Free Press. Beard, C. A. (1965 [1913]). An economic interpretation of the Constitution of the United States. New York: Free Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Bernholz, P., & Vaubel, R. (Eds.). (2004). Political competition, innovation and growth in the history of Asian civilizations. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Bernholz, P., & Vaubel, R. (Eds.). (2004). Political competition, innovation and growth in the history of Asian civilizations. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Zurück zum Zitat Birdsell, J. B. (1973). A basic demographic unit. Current Anthropology, XIV, 337–356.CrossRef Birdsell, J. B. (1973). A basic demographic unit. Current Anthropology, XIV, 337–356.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Blum, U., & Dudley, L. H. (1989). A structural approach to structural change: The making of the French hexagon. Journal of Economic History, XLIX, 657–675.CrossRef Blum, U., & Dudley, L. H. (1989). A structural approach to structural change: The making of the French hexagon. Journal of Economic History, XLIX, 657–675.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Boix, C. (2003). Democracy and redistribution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Boix, C. (2003). Democracy and redistribution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Carneiro, R. (1970). A theory of the origin of the state. Science, 169, 733–738.CrossRef Carneiro, R. (1970). A theory of the origin of the state. Science, 169, 733–738.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Childe, V. G. (1936). Man makes itself. New York: New American Library, Mentor Books. Childe, V. G. (1936). Man makes itself. New York: New American Library, Mentor Books.
Zurück zum Zitat Choi, K. (1983). A statistical test of Olson’s model. In Mueller (Ed.), pp. 57–78. Choi, K. (1983). A statistical test of Olson’s model. In Mueller (Ed.), pp. 57–78.
Zurück zum Zitat Claessen, H. J. M., & Skalnik, P. (Eds.). (1978). The early state. The Hague: Mouton. Claessen, H. J. M., & Skalnik, P. (Eds.). (1978). The early state. The Hague: Mouton.
Zurück zum Zitat Coates, D., & Heckelman, J. C. (2003a). Absolute and relative effects of interest groups on the economy. In Coates & Heckelman (Eds.), Collective choice: Essays in honour of Mancur Olson. Berlin: Springer Verlag. Coates, D., & Heckelman, J. C. (2003a). Absolute and relative effects of interest groups on the economy. In Coates & Heckelman (Eds.), Collective choice: Essays in honour of Mancur Olson. Berlin: Springer Verlag.
Zurück zum Zitat Coates, D., & Heckelman, J. C. (2003b). Interest groups and investment: A further test of Olson hypothesis. Public Choice, 117, 333–340.CrossRef Coates, D., & Heckelman, J. C. (2003b). Interest groups and investment: A further test of Olson hypothesis. Public Choice, 117, 333–340.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dawson, J. W. (2006). Regulation, investment, and growth across countries. Cato Journal, 26, 489–509. Dawson, J. W. (2006). Regulation, investment, and growth across countries. Cato Journal, 26, 489–509.
Zurück zum Zitat De la Fuente, A. (1997). Fiscal policy and growth in the OECD. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research. Discussion Paper no. 1775. De la Fuente, A. (1997). Fiscal policy and growth in the OECD. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research. Discussion Paper no. 1775.
Zurück zum Zitat Domar, E. (1970). The causes of slavery and serfdom: A hypothesis. Journal of Economic History, XXX, 18–32. Domar, E. (1970). The causes of slavery and serfdom: A hypothesis. Journal of Economic History, XXX, 18–32.
Zurück zum Zitat Doucouliagos, C., & Ulubasoglu, M. A. (2006). Economic freedom and economic growth: Does specification make a difference? European Journal of Political Economy, 22, 60–81.CrossRef Doucouliagos, C., & Ulubasoglu, M. A. (2006). Economic freedom and economic growth: Does specification make a difference? European Journal of Political Economy, 22, 60–81.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper & Row. Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper & Row.
Zurück zum Zitat Drake, P. W., & McCubbins, M. D. (1998a). The origins of liberty. In Drake & McCubbins (Eds.), pp. 3–12. Drake, P. W., & McCubbins, M. D. (1998a). The origins of liberty. In Drake & McCubbins (Eds.), pp. 3–12.
Zurück zum Zitat Drake, P. W., & McCubbins, M. D. (Eds.). (1998b). The origins of liberty: Political and economic liberalization in the modern world. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Drake, P. W., & McCubbins, M. D. (Eds.). (1998b). The origins of liberty: Political and economic liberalization in the modern world. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Dudley, L. H. (1990). Structural change and interdependent bureaucracies: Was Rome’s failure economic or military? Explorations in Economic History, 27, 232–248.CrossRef Dudley, L. H. (1990). Structural change and interdependent bureaucracies: Was Rome’s failure economic or military? Explorations in Economic History, 27, 232–248.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dudley, L. H. (1991). The word and the sword. How techniques of information and violence have shaped our world. Oxford: Blackwell. Dudley, L. H. (1991). The word and the sword. How techniques of information and violence have shaped our world. Oxford: Blackwell.
Zurück zum Zitat Dudley, L. H. (1997). Communications and economic growth. European Economic Review, 43, 595–619.CrossRef Dudley, L. H. (1997). Communications and economic growth. European Economic Review, 43, 595–619.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Farr, W. K., Lord, R. A., & Wolfenbarger, J. L. (1998). Economic freedom, political freedom, and economic wellbeing: A causality analysis. Cato Journal, 18, 247–262. Farr, W. K., Lord, R. A., & Wolfenbarger, J. L. (1998). Economic freedom, political freedom, and economic wellbeing: A causality analysis. Cato Journal, 18, 247–262.
Zurück zum Zitat Fölster, S., & Henrekson, M. (1999). Growth and the public sector: A critique of the critics. European Journal of Political Economy, 15, 337–358.CrossRef Fölster, S., & Henrekson, M. (1999). Growth and the public sector: A critique of the critics. European Journal of Political Economy, 15, 337–358.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Friedman, D. (1977). A theory of the size and shape of nations. Journal of Political Economy, 85, 59–77.CrossRef Friedman, D. (1977). A theory of the size and shape of nations. Journal of Political Economy, 85, 59–77.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Greif, A., Milgrom, P., & Weingast, B. (1994). Coordination, commitment and enforcement. The case of the merchant guild. Journal of Political Economy, 102, 745–777.CrossRef Greif, A., Milgrom, P., & Weingast, B. (1994). Coordination, commitment and enforcement. The case of the merchant guild. Journal of Political Economy, 102, 745–777.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gwartney, J. D., Holcombe, R. G., & Lawson, R. A. (2004). Economic freedom, institutional quality, and cross-country differences in income and growth. Cato Journal, 24, 205–233. Gwartney, J. D., Holcombe, R. G., & Lawson, R. A. (2004). Economic freedom, institutional quality, and cross-country differences in income and growth. Cato Journal, 24, 205–233.
Zurück zum Zitat Heckelman, J. C. (2000). Consistent estimates of the impact of special interest groups on economic growth. Public Choice, 104, 319–327.CrossRef Heckelman, J. C. (2000). Consistent estimates of the impact of special interest groups on economic growth. Public Choice, 104, 319–327.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Heller, W. B., Keefer, P., & McCubbins, M. D. (1998). Political structure and economic liberalization. Conditions and cases from the developing world. In Drake & McCubbins (Eds.), pp. 146–178. Heller, W. B., Keefer, P., & McCubbins, M. D. (1998). Political structure and economic liberalization. Conditions and cases from the developing world. In Drake & McCubbins (Eds.), pp. 146–178.
Zurück zum Zitat Hickson, C. R., & Thompson, E. E. (1991). A new theory of guilds and european economic development. Explorations in Economic History, 28, 127–168.CrossRef Hickson, C. R., & Thompson, E. E. (1991). A new theory of guilds and european economic development. Explorations in Economic History, 28, 127–168.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Holcombe, R. G. (2002). From liberty to democracy: The transformation of American government. Ann Arbor, MI: Michigan University Press. Holcombe, R. G. (2002). From liberty to democracy: The transformation of American government. Ann Arbor, MI: Michigan University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Hylland, A., & Zeckhauser, R. (1979). A mechanism for selecting public goods when preferences must be elicited. Harvard University. John Fitzgerald Kennedy School of Government. Discussion Paper No. 70D. Hylland, A., & Zeckhauser, R. (1979). A mechanism for selecting public goods when preferences must be elicited. Harvard University. John Fitzgerald Kennedy School of Government. Discussion Paper No. 70D.
Zurück zum Zitat Jones, E. L. (1988). The European miracle: Environment, economies and geopolitics in the history of Europe and Asia. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Jones, E. L. (1988). The European miracle: Environment, economies and geopolitics in the history of Europe and Asia. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Knack, S. (2003). Groups, growth and trust: Cross-country evidence on the Olson and Putnam hypotheses. Public Choice, 117, 341–335.CrossRef Knack, S. (2003). Groups, growth and trust: Cross-country evidence on the Olson and Putnam hypotheses. Public Choice, 117, 341–335.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kydland, F. E., & Prescott, E. C. (1977). Rules rather than discretion: The inconsistency of optimal plans. Journal of Political Economy, 85, 473–491.CrossRef Kydland, F. E., & Prescott, E. C. (1977). Rules rather than discretion: The inconsistency of optimal plans. Journal of Political Economy, 85, 473–491.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kydland, F. E., & Prescott, E. C. (1980). Dynamic optimal taxation, rational expectations and optimal control. Journal of Economic Dynamic and Control, 2, 79–91.CrossRef Kydland, F. E., & Prescott, E. C. (1980). Dynamic optimal taxation, rational expectations and optimal control. Journal of Economic Dynamic and Control, 2, 79–91.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Latzko, D. A. (1993). The concept of military economies of scale. Explorations in Economic History, 30, 470–484.CrossRef Latzko, D. A. (1993). The concept of military economies of scale. Explorations in Economic History, 30, 470–484.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat McGuire, R. A. (2003). To form a more perfect union: A new economic interpretation of the United States constitution. Oxford: Oxford University Press. McGuire, R. A. (2003). To form a more perfect union: A new economic interpretation of the United States constitution. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat McGuire, R. A., & Olson, M. (1996). The economics of autocracy and majority rule. The invisible hand and the use of force. Journal of Economic Literature, XXXIV, 72–96. McGuire, R. A., & Olson, M. (1996). The economics of autocracy and majority rule. The invisible hand and the use of force. Journal of Economic Literature, XXXIV, 72–96.
Zurück zum Zitat McNeill, W. H. (1963). The rise of the west: A history of the human community. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. McNeill, W. H. (1963). The rise of the west: A history of the human community. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Zurück zum Zitat McNeill, W. H. (1976). Plagues and peoples. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. McNeill, W. H. (1976). Plagues and peoples. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Meltzer, A. H., & Richard, S. F. (1981). A rational theory of the size of government. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 914–927.CrossRef Meltzer, A. H., & Richard, S. F. (1981). A rational theory of the size of government. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 914–927.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Meltzer, A. H., & Richard, S. F. (1983). Test of a rational theory of the size of government. Public Choice, 41, 403–418.CrossRef Meltzer, A. H., & Richard, S. F. (1983). Test of a rational theory of the size of government. Public Choice, 41, 403–418.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mueller, D. C. (Ed.). (1983). The political economy of growth. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Mueller, D. C. (Ed.). (1983). The political economy of growth. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Mueller, D. C. (2003). Public choice III. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Mueller, D. C. (2003). Public choice III. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Niskanen, W. A. (2003). Autocratic, democratic, and optimal government: Fiscal choice and economic outcomes. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Niskanen, W. A. (2003). Autocratic, democratic, and optimal government: Fiscal choice and economic outcomes. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Zurück zum Zitat North, D. C. (1966). Growth and welfare in the American past. A new economic history. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. North, D. C. (1966). Growth and welfare in the American past. A new economic history. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
Zurück zum Zitat North, D. C. (1981). Structure and change in economic history. New York: W. W. Norton & Company. North, D. C. (1981). Structure and change in economic history. New York: W. W. Norton & Company.
Zurück zum Zitat North, D. C., & Thomas, R. P. (1973). The rise of the western world. A new economic history (900–1700). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. North, D. C., & Thomas, R. P. (1973). The rise of the western world. A new economic history (900–1700). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat North, D. C., & Weingast, B. R. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. Journal of Economic History, XLIX, 803–832. Also reprinted in Drake & McCubbins (Eds.) (1998), pp. 16–47. North, D. C., & Weingast, B. R. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. Journal of Economic History, XLIX, 803–832. Also reprinted in Drake & McCubbins (Eds.) (1998), pp. 16–47.
Zurück zum Zitat Olson, M. (1982). The rise and decline of nations. Economic growth, stagflation, and social rigidities. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Olson, M. (1982). The rise and decline of nations. Economic growth, stagflation, and social rigidities. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Olson, M. (1983). The political economy of comparative growth rates. In Mueller (Ed.), pp. 7–52. Olson, M. (1983). The political economy of comparative growth rates. In Mueller (Ed.), pp. 7–52.
Zurück zum Zitat Olson, M. (1993). Dictatorship, democracy, and development. American Political Science Review, 87, 567–576.CrossRef Olson, M. (1993). Dictatorship, democracy, and development. American Political Science Review, 87, 567–576.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Oppenheimer, F. (1926). The state: Its history and development viewed sociologically. New York: Vanguard Press. Oppenheimer, F. (1926). The state: Its history and development viewed sociologically. New York: Vanguard Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Plümper, T., & Martin, C. W. (2003). Democracy, government spending, and economic growth: A political-economic explanation of the Barro-effect. Public Choice, 117, 27–50.CrossRef Plümper, T., & Martin, C. W. (2003). Democracy, government spending, and economic growth: A political-economic explanation of the Barro-effect. Public Choice, 117, 27–50.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Przeworski, A., & Limongi, F. (1993). Political regimes and economic growth. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7, 51–70. Przeworski, A., & Limongi, F. (1993). Political regimes and economic growth. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7, 51–70.
Zurück zum Zitat Reid, J. D. (1978). Economic burden: Spark to the American revolution? Journal of Economic History, XXXVIII, 81–100.CrossRef Reid, J. D. (1978). Economic burden: Spark to the American revolution? Journal of Economic History, XXXVIII, 81–100.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rogowski, R. (1998). Democracy, capital, skill, and country size. Effects of asset mobility and regime monopoly on the odds of democratic rule. In Drake & McCubbins (Eds.), pp. 48–69. Rogowski, R. (1998). Democracy, capital, skill, and country size. Effects of asset mobility and regime monopoly on the odds of democratic rule. In Drake & McCubbins (Eds.), pp. 48–69.
Zurück zum Zitat Sánchez Molinero, J. M. (2000). The origins of the state: From reciprocity to coercive power. Constitutional Political Economy, 11, 231–253.CrossRef Sánchez Molinero, J. M. (2000). The origins of the state: From reciprocity to coercive power. Constitutional Political Economy, 11, 231–253.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Service, E. (1975). Origins of the state and civilization. The process of cultural evolution. New York: Norton. Service, E. (1975). Origins of the state and civilization. The process of cultural evolution. New York: Norton.
Zurück zum Zitat Schofield, R. (2004). Taxation under the early Tudors, 1485–1547. Oxford: Blackwell. Schofield, R. (2004). Taxation under the early Tudors, 1485–1547. Oxford: Blackwell.
Zurück zum Zitat Sirowy, L., & Inkeles, A. (1990). The effects of democracy on economic growth and inequality: A review. Studies in Comparative International Development, 25, 126–157.CrossRef Sirowy, L., & Inkeles, A. (1990). The effects of democracy on economic growth and inequality: A review. Studies in Comparative International Development, 25, 126–157.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Spencer, H. (1967). The evolution of society. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Spencer, H. (1967). The evolution of society. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Tang, E. W. Y., & Hedley, R. A. (1998). Distributional coalitions, state strength, and economic growth: Toward a comprehensive theory of economic development. Public Choice, 96, 295–323.CrossRef Tang, E. W. Y., & Hedley, R. A. (1998). Distributional coalitions, state strength, and economic growth: Toward a comprehensive theory of economic development. Public Choice, 96, 295–323.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tavares, J., & Wacziarg, T. (2001). How democracy affects growth. European Economic Review, 45, 1341–1378.CrossRef Tavares, J., & Wacziarg, T. (2001). How democracy affects growth. European Economic Review, 45, 1341–1378.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Thiebout, C. M. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy, 64, 418–424. Thiebout, C. M. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy, 64, 418–424.
Zurück zum Zitat Tideman, T. N. (1997). Voting and the revelation of preferences for public activities. In D. C. Mueller (Ed.), Perspectives on public choice. A handbook (pp. 226–244). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Tideman, T. N. (1997). Voting and the revelation of preferences for public activities. In D. C. Mueller (Ed.), Perspectives on public choice. A handbook (pp. 226–244). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Tideman, T. N., & Tullock, G. (1976). A new and superior process for making social choices. Journal of Political Economy, 84, 1145–1159.CrossRef Tideman, T. N., & Tullock, G. (1976). A new and superior process for making social choices. Journal of Political Economy, 84, 1145–1159.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tsasavage, D. (2003). Public debt and the birth of the democratic state: France and Great Britain, 1688–1789. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Tsasavage, D. (2003). Public debt and the birth of the democratic state: France and Great Britain, 1688–1789. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Tullock, G. (1974). The social dilemma. The economics of war and revolution. Blacksburg, VA: Center for the Study of Public Choice. Tullock, G. (1974). The social dilemma. The economics of war and revolution. Blacksburg, VA: Center for the Study of Public Choice.
Zurück zum Zitat Tullock, G. (1987a). Autocracy. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Tullock, G. (1987a). Autocracy. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Zurück zum Zitat Tullock, G. (1987b). Autocracia. Revista del Instituto de Estudios Económicos, (2), 27–45. Tullock, G. (1987b). Autocracia. Revista del Instituto de Estudios Económicos, (2), 27–45.
Zurück zum Zitat Tullock, G. (1989). The economics of the special privilege and rent seeking. Boston: Kluwer Economic Publishers. Tullock, G. (1989). The economics of the special privilege and rent seeking. Boston: Kluwer Economic Publishers.
Zurück zum Zitat Weede, E. (2006). Economic freedom and development: New calculations and interpretations. Cato Journal, 26, 511–524. Weede, E. (2006). Economic freedom and development: New calculations and interpretations. Cato Journal, 26, 511–524.
Zurück zum Zitat Wintrobe, R. (1990). The tinpot and the totalitarian: An economic theory of dictatorship. American Political Science Review, 84, 849–872.CrossRef Wintrobe, R. (1990). The tinpot and the totalitarian: An economic theory of dictatorship. American Political Science Review, 84, 849–872.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wintrobe, R. (1998). The political economy of dictatorship. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Wintrobe, R. (1998). The political economy of dictatorship. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Wittfogel, K. A. (1957). Oriental despotism. New Haven: Yale University Press. Wittfogel, K. A. (1957). Oriental despotism. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Wu, W., & Davis, O. A. (1999). The two freedoms, economic growth and development: An empirical study. Public Choice, 100, 39–64.CrossRef Wu, W., & Davis, O. A. (1999). The two freedoms, economic growth and development: An empirical study. Public Choice, 100, 39–64.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
The origins and evolution of democracy: an exercise in history from a constitutional economics approach
verfasst von
Sebastian Coll
Publikationsdatum
01.12.2008
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Constitutional Political Economy / Ausgabe 4/2008
Print ISSN: 1043-4062
Elektronische ISSN: 1572-9966
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-008-9041-9

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 4/2008

Constitutional Political Economy 4/2008 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner