Skip to main content

2003 | Buch

A Primer on Nonmarket Valuation

herausgegeben von: Patricia A. Champ, Kevin J. Boyle, Thomas C. Brown

Verlag: Springer Netherlands

Buchreihe : The Economics of Non-Market Goods and Resources

insite
SUCHEN

Über dieses Buch

A Primer on Nonmarket Valuation is unique in its clear descriptions of the most commonly used nonmarket valuation techniques and their implementation. Individuals working for government agencies, attorneys involved with natural resource damage assessments, graduate students, and others will appreciate the non-technical and practical tone of this book.
The first section of the book provides the context and theoretical foundation of nonmarket valuation, along with practical data issues.
The middle two sections of the Primer describe the major stated and revealed nonmarket valuation techniques. For each technique, the steps involved in implementation are laid out and described. Both practitioners of nonmarket valuation and those who are new to the field will come away from these methods chapters with a thorough understanding of how to design, implement, and analyze a nonmarket valuation study.

Inhaltsverzeichnis

Frontmatter
Chapter 1. Economic Valuation: What and Why
Abstract
Consider the choices faced by those responsible for managing releases of water at the Glen Canyon Dam on the Colorado River. The size and timing of the releases determine the value of the hydroelectric power generated. But the pattern of the releases influences the nature and value of the recreational activities on Lake Powell above the dam and on the rivers in Glen Canyon and Grand Canyon below the dam. The release patterns also affect, in complex ways, the availability of suitable habitat for and the probabilities of the survival of several endangered species. Thus, managers face choices that involve tradeoffs.1 More hydroelectric power means reduced quality and quantity of recreation opportunities and, perhaps, reductions in the survival of some endangered species. It is necessary to reconcile the sometimes conflicting desires and interests of those affected by management decisions and to make wise choices concerning these trade-offs. To do so, resource managers require information on the value of hydroelectric power and the values that people place on various attributes and types of recreation on and along the Colorado River and on changes in the survival probabilities for endangered species.2
A. Myrick Freeman III
Chapter 2. Conceptual Framework for Nonmarket Valuation
Abstract
Serious practice of nonmarket valuation requires a working knowledge of the economic theory because it forms the basis for the explicit goals in any nonmarket valuation exercise. This chapter provides readers with the requisite theory to meaningfully apply the nonmarket valuation techniques.
Nicholas E. Flores
Chapter 3. Collecting Survey Data for Nonmarket Valuation
Abstract
The unique nature of environmental and natural resource amenities makes valuation a challenge in many respects. Prices reflect aggregate societal values for market goods but nonmarket goods lack an analogous indicator of value. Estimation of nonmarket values requires that the researcher either ask the public about their values for the good of interest or use existing data to infer the values. Either approach is sensitive to the quality of the data used for the estimation, which is why this chapter focuses on how to collect data for estimating nonmarket values. Understanding where such data come from and the procedures used to collect the data will make the descriptions of the nonmarket valuation techniques in Chapters 4–11 more meaningful.
Patricia A. Champ
Chapter 4. Introduction to Stated Preference Methods
Abstract
Stated preference approaches to nonmarket valuation rely on answers to carefully worded survey questions. Those answers—in the form of monetary amounts, choices, ratings, or other indications of preference—are scaled following an appropriate model of preference to yield a measure of value. Two common, and one not so common, stated preference methods are discussed in the next three chapters.
Thomas C. Brown
Chapter 5. Contingent Valuation in Practice
Abstract
Contingent valuation is a survey-based methodology for eliciting values people place on goods, services, and amenities. The first contingent valuation study was conducted by Davis (1963) to estimate the value of big game hunting in Maine. A decade later, Hammack and Brown (1974) applied contingent valuation to valuing waterfowl hunting. Simultaneously, an application to valuing visibility in the Four Corners region of the Southwest represented a turning point after which contingent valuation gained recognition as a methodology for estimating Hicksian surplus for public goods (Randall, Ives, and Eastman 1974). Contingent valuation filled a substantial void by providing a way to estimate values when markets do not exist and revealed preference methods are not applicable.
Kevin J. Boyle
Chapter 6. Attribute-Based Methods
Abstract
Stated preference methods of environmental valuation have been used by economists for decades where behavioral data have limitations. The contingent valuation method (Chapter 5) is the oldest stated preference approach, and hundreds of contingent valuation studies have been conducted. More recently, and especially over the last decade, a new class of stated preference methods has been developed, which we generically refer to as attribute-based methods (ABMs). As with contingent valuation, numerous ABM variants exist, employing, for example, different constructs for eliciting preferences. In this chapter, we describe the various ABMs currently used, explain how to construct an attribute-based experiment, and recommend methods for environmental valuation.
Thomas P. Holmes, Wiktor L. Adamowicz
Chapter 7. Multiple Good Valuation
With Focus on the Method of Paired Comparisons
Abstract
Assume for the moment that you are the supervisor of the Roosevelt National Forest (it’s located near our town of Fort Collins, Colorado). You have been asked by the Chief of the Forest Service how you would spend a specified increase in your budget. You could spend the increase on such projects as improved campgrounds, better roads for reaching the backcountry, reduction in forest fuels to lower the risk of wildfire, and watershed management to lower erosion and thereby improve fish habitat. You know your chances of getting an increase depend on how well you support your proposal. You can design options that use up the budget increase, but you don’t have good information about the benefits of, or even the public preferences for, the options. You know what the vocal interest groups want, but you would like your proposal to have some quantitative justification that reflects the values of the wider citizenry who care about the National Forest. You examined the economic analyses that had been done about forest resources in the area and found no studies for most of the major resources you manage. You don’t have time for separate valuation studies of each of the options. However, you could commission a single study directly comparing the values people place on the options-a multiple good valuation study. Furthermore, because the options cost the same amount, a preference ordering of the options is all you need to choose the best one. That option might then become the focus of an economic valuation study, which would allow a benefit-cost comparison.1
Thomas C. Brown, George L. Peterson
Chapter 8. Introduction to Revealed Preference Methods
Abstract
Revealed preference methods draw statistical inferences on values from actual choices people make within markets. Estimation of the values people place on environmental amenities and disamenities proceeds by specifying a theoretical framework and conducting data analyses from purchase decisions (prices paid and quantities purchased) according to this conceptual framework. Four commonly used revealed preference methods are discussed in the next three chapters (Chapter 9, travel cost; Chapter 10, hedonics; Chapter 11, defensive behavior and damage costs).
Kevin J. Boyle
Chapter 9. The Travel Cost Model
Abstract
The travel cost model is used to value recreational uses of the environment. For example, it may be used to value the recreation loss associated with a beach closure due to an oil spill or to value the recreation gain associated with improved water quality on a river. The model is commonly applied in benefit-cost analyses and in natural resource damage assessments where recreation values play a role. Since the model is based on observed behavior, it is used to estimate use values only.
George R. Parsons
Chapter 10. The Hedonic Method
Abstract
Heterogeneous or differentiated goods are products whose characteristics vary in such a way that there are distinct product varieties even though the commodity is sold in one market (e.g., cars, computers, houses). The variation in product variety gives rise to variations in product prices within each market. The hedonic method for non-market valuation relies on market transactions for these differentiated goods to determine the value of key underlying characteristics. For instance, by observing the price differential between two product varieties that vary only by one characteristic (e.g., two identical cars, but with one having more horsepower than the other), we indirectly observe the monetary trade-offs individuals are willing to make with respect to the changes in this characteristic. As such, the hedonic method is an “indirect” valuation method in which we do not observe the value consumers have for the characteristic directly, but infer it from observable market transactions.
Laura O. Taylor
Chapter 11. Defensive Behavior and Damage Cost Methods
Abstract
Suppose you wake up one morning and stumble into the kitchen to make coffee. You flip on the TV. While filling the coffee pot with tap water, you learn that your water supply is contaminated with Giardia lamblia. The newscaster reports that consuming contaminated water can lead to giardiasis, a common diarrheal illness that typically lasts a few days but can drag on for weeks. Infected persons may have to miss work or school or, in rare cases, may require hospitalization. Local authorities recommend boiling tap water before consuming it or finding alternate sources like bottled water. What do you do?
Mark Dickie
Chapter 12. Benefit Transfer
Abstract
Previous chapters of this book have described how to conduct an original nonmarket valuation study. However, original research can be time-consuming and expensive. What can you do if your time and/or funding prevents you from conducting an original study? For example, suppose the West Virginia Department of Environmental Protection (WVDEP) is deliberating on whether to grant a permit for a coal mine. Suppose a decision must be made within 60 days. The agency wants to balance the benefits derived from extracting the coal with the environmental damages caused by mining. One impact is the loss of recreational fishing downstream from the mining site. WVDEP wants to know the value of fishing on this stream. How could you provide this information? Even if WVDEP had the necessary funds to conduct a primary study, obviously there is not enough time. In this chapter, we describe how existing data or summary statistics from previous research can be used in different decision contexts. We use the term benefit transfer to describe the use of information from previous research to inform decisions.
Randall S. Rosenberger, John B. Loomis
Chapter 13. Nonmarket Valuation in Action
Abstract
If a tree falls in the forest and no one is around to hear it, does it make a sound? Likewise, if a nonmarket valuation study is done and it is not used to affect or inform policy or management, does it serve a purpose? Previous chapters in this book have gone into detail about how to implement specific nonmarket valuation techniques. After reading all those chapters, one might reasonably ask: Who cares? Do these methods make a difference in the real world of policy and management decisions related to resource allocation? answer is ... well, sometimes.
Daniel W. McCollum
Chapter 14. Where to from Here?
Abstract
While our editors were too polite to call it that, I was assigned to write the Old Professor’s chapter. It’s up to me to wrap up this volume by taking stock and looking into the future. Actually, being 30 years past the Ph.D., I rather like this role. Taking the long view suits me fine.
Richard C. Bishop
Backmatter
Metadaten
Titel
A Primer on Nonmarket Valuation
herausgegeben von
Patricia A. Champ
Kevin J. Boyle
Thomas C. Brown
Copyright-Jahr
2003
Verlag
Springer Netherlands
Electronic ISBN
978-94-007-0826-6
Print ISBN
978-1-4020-1445-1
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-007-0826-6