Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Mathematics and Financial Economics 4/2020

29.05.2020

Asset pricing in a pure exchange economy with heterogeneous investors

verfasst von: Xinfeng Ruan, Jin E. Zhang

Erschienen in: Mathematics and Financial Economics | Ausgabe 4/2020

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

In this paper, we provide a complete solution to the problem of equilibrium asset pricing in a pure exchange economy with two types of heterogeneous investors having higher/lower risk aversion. Using a perturbation method, we obtain analytical approximate formulas for the optimal consumption-sharing rule, which is numerically justified to be accurate for a large risk aversion and heterogeneity. We present analytical formulas for the equilibrium pricing function, Sharpe ratio, risk-free rate, stock price and optimal trading strategies. We then analyse the properties of the equilibrium and derive some testable hypotheses, which enhance our understanding on the economics of financial markets.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
In the literature aggregation results for CRRA utility with different initial wealth levels but identical risk aversion and beliefs are well understood, see the recent analysis in [16]. They fully characterize the class of utility functions of heterogeneous households and study the existence of a representative consumer.
 
2
This paper considers a more general set of risk-aversion parameters, compared with [25]. In a different perspective, we propose a simple and intuitive closed-form solution which indeed enhances the understanding on the economics of financial markets. For example, the implications for the price-dividend ratio are very interesting. Compared to [25], our model newly implies that the price-divided ratio should be larger for firms with large size and low-risk aversion shareholders (e.g., institutional investors). This is consistent with the empirical evidence in [12]. Our framework can be easily applied to analyse different markets, e.g., bonds, stocks, options and funds. Further discussing a property of a particular market with an equilibrium model is beyond the scope of the current article.
 
3
The “complete” solution in this paper is relative to the partial solutions in the literature, e.g., lacking the closed-form solution for asset prices in [9] and missing the solution for the price of the stock yielding multiple or continuous dividends in [4].
 
4
Other literature studies on heterogeneous investors with margin constraints. Gârleanu and Pedersen [10] study a model with heterogeneous-risk-aversion agents facing margin constraints and discuss how margin constraints affect capital market equilibrium. Rytchkov [23] develop constant margin constraints in [10] into time-varying case. Recently, a two-tree [18] heterogeneous-belief model is studied by Han et al. [11].
 
5
In a constrained economy, finding the equilibrium reduces to solving a system of partial differential equations (PDEs) in [7] or ordinary differential equations (ODEs) in [8].
 
6
Perturbation method is a method of finding an approximate solution to a problem, by starting from the exact solution of a related, simpler problem. A critical feature of the technique is a middle step that breaks the problem into “solvable” and “perturbation” parts. Historically this method was invented in the area of engineering science in solving some nonlinear problems in which it is difficult to obtain exact solutions. The validity of the approximate solutions obtained is often justified numerically with a reasonable range of parameters. A proof of convergence of this method is an open question. In finance, this method has been used by Kogan and Uppal [15] to analyse a heterogenous-agent economy in the presence of portfolio constraints.
 
7
We thank a reviewer for suggesting us to pay attention to the advantage of analytical simplicity and transparency.
 
8
With the standard logarithmic preferences (\(\gamma _H=\gamma _L=1\)), Yang and Zhang [27] propose a dynamic asset pricing model with heterogeneous sentiments and [19] develop a model with two institutional investors.
 
9
Kaniel and Kondor [14] propose a heterogeneous-agents Lucas tree model and distinguish investors (including fund managers, clients, direct traders and newborn investors) that trade on their own account from investors that trade through managed portfolios as opposed to low and high risk-aversion investors as in this paper. Kaniel and Kondor [14] therefore obtain an inverse U-shaped Sharpe ratio rather than our monotonic Sharpe ratio.
 
10
Unlike the incomplete information model [2] in which \(\lambda \) is stochastic as investors face the different state price densities, in our complete information model, \(\lambda \) should be constant (e.g., [3, 25]).
 
11
If we substitute Bhamra and Uppal’s [4] solutions of our model in “Appendix A” into the definition of the marginal utility of the representative investor in (11) and then solve the marginal utility, we will find that it is very difficult to explicitly solve the equilibrium price of long-lived stock (13). This is because the marginal utility is with respect to the \(\gamma _H\)th (or \(\gamma _L\)th) power of a hypergeometric function. Without a loss of generality, we only compare our solution with Bhamra and Uppal’s [4] as the closed solutions of [7, 8] have the same accuracy.
 
12
The perturbation method can be applied in solving the equilibrium in a more general settings, such as the case of heterogeneity in time discount factors and heterogeneity in assessment of the dividend mean growth rates. The details involving a lot of algebra will be presented in a subsequent research.
 
13
Following Wang [25], we focus on the consumption rate rather than the consumption over dividend (income) ratio. Based on the solutions in Eqs. (16)–(17), it does not make any difference using either one.
 
14
The proportion of institutional investors in the U.S. public equity market in 2010 is 67 %.
 
15
The optimal consumption for investor H in [25] is
$$\begin{aligned}{\widehat{c}}_{H,t}=\frac{1}{2 b^2}\left( \sqrt{1+4b^2D_t}-1\right) , \end{aligned}$$
and Bhamra and Uppal’s [4] solution is given in “Appendix A”.
 
16
The only difference between the first-order and second-order perturbation solutions is that the risk-free rate and the price-dividend ratio are no longer constant. More details see “Appendix C”.
 
17
Corresponding to Wang [25], the trading strategies are expressed by the unique state variable \(D_t\) rather than \(W_{i,t}\) or \(S_t\). However, our solution are more explicit than [25] as \(S_t\) is solved in (19).
 
18
Given \(\beta , \gamma \) and \(\varepsilon \), we can solve a from a quadratic equation in (28) so that b can be determined by \(\beta , \gamma \) and \(\varepsilon \).
 
19
The risk-free interest rate in the second-order approximation is stochastic. More details see “Appendix C”.
 
20
The volatility in the second-order approximation is not constant. More details see “Appendix C”.
 
21
The second equality is proved by using the restricted equation of the weight ratio b in (28). By using Eq. (21) and the fact that the volatility of the stock is \(\sigma _D\), the equity premium in our model is \(\left( 1-\varepsilon \frac{a-1}{a+1} \right) \gamma \sigma _D^2+{\mathcal {O}}(\varepsilon ^2)= \gamma _A \sigma _D^2+{\mathcal {O}}(\varepsilon ^2)\) which is equivalent to the results solved in the classical equilibrium model with one representative investor (e.g., [20, 26]). It shows that our model can not fully explain the equity premium puzzle. However, the main target of the paper is to explore how the size of type L investors and risk-averse heterogeneity influence the prices of the assets and investments.
 
22
Here we set \(E[D_t]=D_0 e^{\mu t} =1.43\) as the value of \(D_t\).
 
23
The proof is available upon request.
 
24
Similarly to [3], the non-zero volatility of the risk-free interest rate or the stochastic risk-free interest rate is due to the more volatile consumptions in (16)-(17) in the second-order. In addition, it leads to that the volatility of the stock price is no longer \(\sigma _D\).
 
25
Similar to Wang [25], the wealth process can be expressed by the stock price and the divided. As there is only one state variable \(D_t\), the wealth process \(W_{H,t}\) is one of our solutions.
 
26
By using the restricted equation of the weight ratio b in (38), we can get the second equality in (39). As \(\gamma _H=\gamma (1+\varepsilon )\) and \(\gamma _H-\gamma (1-\varepsilon )\), only constant and the first order terms of \({\widehat{\phi }}_{H,0}\) contribute to the finally results.
 
27
Even though we set \(\beta <0.5\) (e.g., \(\beta =0.2\) or \(b=0.35\)) which means the initial size type L investors is quite small , the evolutions of Fig. 9 are not changed. It tells us that with the economy developing better and better, the type L investors become wealthier and wealthier. This is consistent to the fact that the size of type L investors jumps sharply from 7-8% in 1950 to 67% in 2010. Our model does explain the phenomenon that type L investors as risk takers become larger and larger in the financial market.
 
Literatur
1.
Zurück zum Zitat Allen, F.: Do financial institutions matter? J. Finance 56(4), 1165–1175 (2001) Allen, F.: Do financial institutions matter? J. Finance 56(4), 1165–1175 (2001)
2.
Zurück zum Zitat Basak, S.: Asset pricing with heterogeneous beliefs. J. Bank. Finance 29(11), 2849–2881 (2005) Basak, S.: Asset pricing with heterogeneous beliefs. J. Bank. Finance 29(11), 2849–2881 (2005)
3.
Zurück zum Zitat Bhamra, H.S., Uppal, R.: The effect of introducing a non-redundant derivative on the volatility of stock-market returns when agents differ in risk aversion. Rev. Financ. Stud. 22(6), 2303–2330 (2009) Bhamra, H.S., Uppal, R.: The effect of introducing a non-redundant derivative on the volatility of stock-market returns when agents differ in risk aversion. Rev. Financ. Stud. 22(6), 2303–2330 (2009)
4.
Zurück zum Zitat Bhamra, H.S., Uppal, R.: Asset prices with heterogeneity in preferences and beliefs. Rev. Financ. Stud. 27(2), 519–580 (2014) Bhamra, H.S., Uppal, R.: Asset prices with heterogeneity in preferences and beliefs. Rev. Financ. Stud. 27(2), 519–580 (2014)
5.
Zurück zum Zitat Blume, M.E., Keim, D.B.: Institutional investors and stock market liquidity: trends and relationships. Available at SSRN 2147757 (2012) Blume, M.E., Keim, D.B.: Institutional investors and stock market liquidity: trends and relationships. Available at SSRN 2147757 (2012)
6.
Zurück zum Zitat Bommier, A., Rochet, J.C.: Risk aversion and planning horizons. J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. 4(4), 708–734 (2006) Bommier, A., Rochet, J.C.: Risk aversion and planning horizons. J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. 4(4), 708–734 (2006)
7.
Zurück zum Zitat Chabakauri, G.: Dynamic equilibrium with two stocks, heterogeneous investors, and portfolio constraints. Rev. Financ. Stud. 26(12), 3104–3141 (2013) Chabakauri, G.: Dynamic equilibrium with two stocks, heterogeneous investors, and portfolio constraints. Rev. Financ. Stud. 26(12), 3104–3141 (2013)
8.
Zurück zum Zitat Chabakauri, G.: Asset pricing with heterogeneous preferences, beliefs, and portfolio constraints. J. Monet. Econ. 75, 21–34 (2015) Chabakauri, G.: Asset pricing with heterogeneous preferences, beliefs, and portfolio constraints. J. Monet. Econ. 75, 21–34 (2015)
9.
Zurück zum Zitat Cvitanić, J., Jouini, E., Malamud, S., Napp, C.: Financial markets equilibrium with heterogeneous agents. Rev. Finance 16(1), 285–321 (2012)MATH Cvitanić, J., Jouini, E., Malamud, S., Napp, C.: Financial markets equilibrium with heterogeneous agents. Rev. Finance 16(1), 285–321 (2012)MATH
10.
Zurück zum Zitat Gârleanu, N., Pedersen, L.H.: Margin-based asset pricing and deviations from the law of one price. Rev. Financ. Stud. 24(6), 1980–2022 (2011) Gârleanu, N., Pedersen, L.H.: Margin-based asset pricing and deviations from the law of one price. Rev. Financ. Stud. 24(6), 1980–2022 (2011)
11.
Zurück zum Zitat Han, B., Lu, L., Zhou, Y.: Two trees with heterogeneous beliefs: spillover effect of disagreement. J. Financ. Quant. Anal. 54(4), 1791–1819 (2019) Han, B., Lu, L., Zhou, Y.: Two trees with heterogeneous beliefs: spillover effect of disagreement. J. Financ. Quant. Anal. 54(4), 1791–1819 (2019)
12.
Zurück zum Zitat Jain, R.: Institutional and individual investor preferences for dividends and share repurchases. J. Econ. Bus. 59(5), 406–429 (2007) Jain, R.: Institutional and individual investor preferences for dividends and share repurchases. J. Econ. Bus. 59(5), 406–429 (2007)
13.
Zurück zum Zitat Ju, N., Miao, J.: Ambiguity, learning, and asset returns. Econometrica 80(2), 559–591 (2012)MathSciNetMATH Ju, N., Miao, J.: Ambiguity, learning, and asset returns. Econometrica 80(2), 559–591 (2012)MathSciNetMATH
14.
Zurück zum Zitat Kaniel, R., Kondor, P.: The delegated lucas tree. Rev. Financ. Stud. 26(4), 929–984 (2012) Kaniel, R., Kondor, P.: The delegated lucas tree. Rev. Financ. Stud. 26(4), 929–984 (2012)
15.
Zurück zum Zitat Kogan, L., Uppal, R.: Risk aversion and optimal portfolio policies in partial and general equilibrium economies. Working paper, National Bureau of Economic Research (2001) Kogan, L., Uppal, R.: Risk aversion and optimal portfolio policies in partial and general equilibrium economies. Working paper, National Bureau of Economic Research (2001)
16.
Zurück zum Zitat Koulovatianos, C., Schröder, C., Schmidt, U.: Do demographics prevent consumption aggregates from reflecting micro-level preferences? Eur. Econ. Rev. 111, 166–190 (2019) Koulovatianos, C., Schröder, C., Schmidt, U.: Do demographics prevent consumption aggregates from reflecting micro-level preferences? Eur. Econ. Rev. 111, 166–190 (2019)
17.
Zurück zum Zitat Longstaff, F.A., Wang, J.: Asset pricing and the credit market. Rev. Financ. Stud. 25(11), 3169–3215 (2012) Longstaff, F.A., Wang, J.: Asset pricing and the credit market. Rev. Financ. Stud. 25(11), 3169–3215 (2012)
18.
19.
Zurück zum Zitat Ma, C., Wang, H., Cheng, F., Hu, D.: Asset pricing and institutional investors with disagreements. Econ. Model. 64, 231–248 (2017) Ma, C., Wang, H., Cheng, F., Hu, D.: Asset pricing and institutional investors with disagreements. Econ. Model. 64, 231–248 (2017)
20.
Zurück zum Zitat Mehra, R., Prescott, E.C.: The equity premium: a puzzle. J. Monet. Econ. 15(2), 145–161 (1985) Mehra, R., Prescott, E.C.: The equity premium: a puzzle. J. Monet. Econ. 15(2), 145–161 (1985)
21.
Zurück zum Zitat Munk, C.: Financial Asset Pricing Theory. OUP, Oxford (2013) Munk, C.: Financial Asset Pricing Theory. OUP, Oxford (2013)
22.
Zurück zum Zitat Nayfeh, A.H.: Perturbation Methods. Wiley, Hoboken (2008) Nayfeh, A.H.: Perturbation Methods. Wiley, Hoboken (2008)
23.
Zurück zum Zitat Rytchkov, O.: Asset pricing with dynamic margin constraints. J. Finance 69(1), 405–452 (2014) Rytchkov, O.: Asset pricing with dynamic margin constraints. J. Finance 69(1), 405–452 (2014)
24.
Zurück zum Zitat Veronesi, P.: Heterogeneous households under uncertainty. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research (2019) Veronesi, P.: Heterogeneous households under uncertainty. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research (2019)
25.
Zurück zum Zitat Wang, J.: The term structure of interest rates in a pure exchange economy with heterogeneous investors. J. Financ. Econ. 41(1), 75–110 (1996)MathSciNet Wang, J.: The term structure of interest rates in a pure exchange economy with heterogeneous investors. J. Financ. Econ. 41(1), 75–110 (1996)MathSciNet
26.
Zurück zum Zitat Yan, H.: Estimation uncertainty and the equity premium. Int. Rev. Finance 9(3), 243–268 (2009) Yan, H.: Estimation uncertainty and the equity premium. Int. Rev. Finance 9(3), 243–268 (2009)
27.
Zurück zum Zitat Yang, C., Zhang, R.: Dynamic asset pricing model with heterogeneous sentiments. Econ. Model. 33, 248–253 (2013) Yang, C., Zhang, R.: Dynamic asset pricing model with heterogeneous sentiments. Econ. Model. 33, 248–253 (2013)
Metadaten
Titel
Asset pricing in a pure exchange economy with heterogeneous investors
verfasst von
Xinfeng Ruan
Jin E. Zhang
Publikationsdatum
29.05.2020
Verlag
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Erschienen in
Mathematics and Financial Economics / Ausgabe 4/2020
Print ISSN: 1862-9679
Elektronische ISSN: 1862-9660
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11579-020-00266-x

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 4/2020

Mathematics and Financial Economics 4/2020 Zur Ausgabe