Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Empirical Economics 5/2020

Open Access 10.09.2019

Crime, deterrence and punishment revisited

verfasst von: Maurice J. G. Bun, Richard Kelaher, Vasilis Sarafidis, Don Weatherburn

Erschienen in: Empirical Economics | Ausgabe 5/2020

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Despite an abundance of empirical evidence on crime spanning over 40 years, there exists no consensus on the impact of the criminal justice system on crime activity. We construct a new panel data set that contains all relevant variables prescribed by economic theory. Our identification strategy allows for a feedback relationship between crime and deterrence variables, and it controls for omitted variables and measurement error. We deviate from the majority of the literature in that we specify a dynamic model, which captures the essential feature of habit formation and persistence in aggregate behaviour. Our results show that the criminal justice system exerts a large influence on crime activity. Increasing the risk of apprehension and conviction is more influential in reducing crime than raising the expected severity of punishment.
Hinweise
This article greatly benefited from comments made by the editor and two anonymous referees. We are grateful to Eddie Anderson and Frank Windmeijer for useful comments and suggestions. We would also like to thank seminar participants at the Statistical Society of Australia (NSW branch) and the NSW Bureau of Crime statistics and Research. The usual disclaimer applies.
Maurice J. G. Bun: The research of the author has been funded by the Dutch Research Council (NWO) Vernieuwingsimpuls research grant ‘Causal Inference with Panel Data’.
Vasilis Sarafidis: The research of the author has been by the Australian Research Council (ARC) under research grant number DP-170103135.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

1 Introduction

Crime, originating from the root of Latin cern\({\bar{o}}\) (‘I decide, I give judgment’), is the behaviour judged by the State to be in violation of the prevailing norms that underpin the moral code of society. Where informal social controls are not sufficient to deter such behaviour, the State may intervene to punish or reform those responsible through the criminal justice system. The precise sanctions imposed depend on the type of crime and the prevailing cultural norms of the society. For offences deemed to be serious, criminal justice systems have historically imprisoned those responsible, in the hope that a combination of deterrence and incapacitation may lower the crime rate. According to an estimate, about 10 million people in the world are institutionalized for punishment, almost half of which are held in America, China and the UK (Walmsley 2009). Over the past 30 years, the American prison population has more than quadrupled. Raphael and Stoll (2009) have shown that the increase in the US prison population between 1984 and 2002 may be explained almost entirely by an increase in punitiveness, rather than an increase in crime. This has led some to label the extraordinary growth in the US prison population as one of the largest scale policy experiments of the century (Spelman 2000). Others have recently argued that significant reductions in the size of prison populations are possible nowadays without endangering public safety (Sundt et al. 2016).
The USA is not the only country to have experienced upward trends in its imprisonment rate over the last 30 years of course; nor is it the only country where the increase in imprisonment rates was driven by more punitive law and order policies rather than by an increase in crime. The Australian imprisonment rate, for example, has risen by 88% over the last 30 years. In the period covered by this article, it rose by more than 30%. Since 2000, this rise in imprisonment rates in Australia has occurred against a backdrop of falling crime (Weatherburn 2016).
How effective is the criminal justice system in deterring crime? To what extent do changes in the expected punishment influence the motivation of individuals to engage in illegal pursuits? How much wrongdoing does each additional prisoner avert? In order to address these questions in a constructive way, it is important to recognize that changes in the aggregate crime rate stem from individual behaviour. Policies such as increased sentence lengths may lower the crime rate through two possible channels: deterrence and incapacitation. It is well accepted in the literature that for a particular policy to be effective it cannot operate on incapacitation effects alone (Durlauf and Nagin 2011). In turn, for a policy to deter criminal behaviour it must be designed with an understanding of what causes individuals to engage in criminal activity.
During the early part of the twentieth century, most theories of crime tended to attribute criminal behaviour to defects in the individual or in society (Vold et al. 2002). The seminal papers by Becker (1968) and Ehrlich (1975) denied the existence of any qualitative difference between offenders and non-offenders and asserted that individuals engage in criminal activity whenever the expected benefit of doing so exceeds the expected cost. Therefore, criminals do not differ from the rest of society in their basic motivation but in their appraisal of benefits and costs. On this view, a rational criminal behaves in a calculated manner, considering the benefit of the illegal act together with the risk of apprehension and conviction as well as the likelihood and severity of potential punishment, which are a function of three separate stages of processing through the criminal justice system pertaining to the roles of police, courts and prison system, respectively. The idea of a rational criminal forges an important link with the deterrence hypothesis that underpins the criminal justice system—the notion that the crime rate can be reduced by raising the expected cost of criminal activity.
Since the seminal work of Becker (1968) and Ehrlich (1975), a large empirical literature has developed, seeking to inform public policy by collecting data on various populations and building econometric models that describe criminal behaviour of individuals. The public concern about crime is well justified given the pernicious effects that it has on economic activity, as well as on the quality of one’s life in terms of a reduced sense of personal and proprietary security. However, despite the rich history of econometric modelling spanning over 40 years, there is arguably no consensus on whether there is a strong deterrent effect of law enforcement policies on crime activity. Empirical studies provide mixed evidence that are insufficient to draw clear conclusions.1
The present paper revisits the economics of crime and punishment and provides a case study for New South Wales (NSW), Australia. We focus on four individual crime categories—namely theft, robbery, assault and homicide incidents. These offences broadly span the classification of criminal activity often employed in the literature. In addition, we consider two broader crime categories, property and violent crime. In order to alleviate heterogeneity bias, which can potentially arise due to differences across individual crime types in terms of occurrence and level of seriousness (see e.g. Cherry and List 2002), we consider weighted sums of the aforementioned four individual crime categories.
Our empirical strategy relies on GMM estimation of dynamic panel data models, and it takes into account various important methodological issues arising in the empirical analysis of criminal behaviour. In particular, our identification strategy allows for endogeneity or weak exogeneity between crime and the deterrence variables. Due to the panel structure of our modelling framework, instruments naturally arise with respect to sufficiently lagged values of the regressors. The validity of the instruments is examined empirically using tests for weak identification and overidentifying restrictions. In addition, the dynamic specification of our model captures the essential feature of habit formation and costs of adjustment in aggregate behaviour. This is important because it permits distinguishing between the effect of law enforcement policies in the short and the long run, and deriving equilibrium conditions as well as other meaningful dynamic quantities such as mean lag length of the effects.2
The results of our analysis show that criminal activity is highly responsive to the prospect of arrest and conviction, but much less responsive to the prospect or severity of imprisonment, if at all. This provides support to the idea that the consequences of being arrested and found guilty of a criminal offence include indirect sanctions imposed by society and not just the punishment meted out by the criminal justice system. In particular, a convicted individual may no longer enjoy the same opportunities in the labour market and so the cost of social stigmatization can already be substantial in the event of conviction.
The sensitivity of our results is analysed extensively. First, we examine different moment conditions, depending on whether the probability of arrest is treated as endogenous or (weakly) exogenous, and we test for the validity of each specification. Second, we apply the methodology of Griliches and Hausman (1986) in order to test for measurement error in the data. Third, we estimate the crime model using a range of estimators other than GMM. Finally, we examine the effect of omitted variables in our model. The conclusions of our analysis appear to be fairly robust.
The remainder of this paper is as follows. Section 2 reviews various methodological issues arising in the empirical analysis of criminal behaviour. Section 3 presents the econometric specification and the identification strategy employed. Section 4 discusses the data and reports the results. A final section concludes.

2 Methodological issues

Unfortunately, empirical analysis of the effect of law enforcement policies on criminal activity is inherently problematic due to the nature of crime data available. In particular, data collected from individuals are self-reported and are doubtlessly affected by significant measurement error (Freeman 1999). Moreover, the time and cost involved in surveying a representative population can be prohibitively large. As a result, empirical studies of crime typically use some form of aggregate data, which describe crime in locales (e.g. local areas, states or countries) and are based on official records rather than self-reported information.
However, aggregate data are also not without problems. This has led some to suggest that the use of individual and aggregate data may be regarded as two complementary approaches (Trumbull 1989).
To begin with, since the economic model of crime purports to describe illegal behaviour of individual agents rather than an empirical aggregate, summing up over crime offences over individuals might inherently introduce some form of so-called aggregation bias.
Furthermore, the use of aggregate data introduces a problem of lack of exogeneity for some regressors, making the causal effect of law enforcement policies on crime more difficult to identify. For example, an exogenous upward shift in crime rate may eventually overwhelm police resources, given that police resources are fixed in the short term, causing the probability of arrest to decrease. This property is known in the econometrics jargon as reverse causality or simultaneity.
Even if some feedback relationship is not present in the data, the empirical probability of arrest (when defined as number of arrests divided by the number of crime offences) suffers from the fact that the numerator of the dependent variable (number of crime offences) is the denominator in the probability of arrest. This artificially induces a negative correlation between the two variables (Nagin 1978)—a phenomenon that is known as ratio bias (see e.g. Dills et al. 2008).
An additional issue arising with aggregate data might be measurement error. Measurement error can manifest itself in at least two ways. Firstly, crime data typically record reported crime offences, rather than actual ones. For instance, it has sometimes been argued that it does not always serve the victim’s best interest to report an offence (Myers 1980). This type of measurement error may particularly affect the crime rate and probability of arrest variables (Levitt 1998), as they are both constructed based on the number of crime offences. Secondly, because of timing issues, judiciary variables (courts and prisons) might follow a different timing than other variables affecting the (individual) propensity to commit a crime. As a result, (say) the empirical probability of imprisonment, which is the ratio of the number of imprisonments over convictions, could reflect crime offences that occurred at previous points in time.3 To put this differently, if offenders have high discount rates (as it has been argued in, for example, Wilson and Hernstein 1985), the speed with which offenders are apprehended and punished is important. This issue can be particularly pronounced with relatively high-frequency data (e.g. monthly observations), but less so for yearly data.4
Finally, there is the potential for omitted variable bias in the estimated parameters. Omitted variables imply a bias if they are correlated with included regressors. In particular, it is hardly ever the case that a complete model is specified that includes all deterrence variables prescribed by economic theory. This is likely to be due to lack of data or the fact that certain experimental designs intended to combat endogeneity preclude the possibility of examining all deterrence variables of interest. Whatever the appropriate explanation is, the evidence on crime deterrence has come to conform broadly to several distinct sub-researches, in which the effect of the probability of arrest, the probability of conviction, the probability of imprisonment and the length of average sentence is rarely examined together.
The aforementioned issues—namely aggregation bias, reverse causality, ratio bias, measurement error and omitted variable bias, all render the deterrence explanatory variables endogenous, that is, correlated with the error term of the model. It is well known that in the presence of endogeneity, least-squares-based estimates of the economic model of crime are biased and inconsistent. Despite that, a majority of crime studies do not control for endogeneity, which casts doubt on their results (Blumstein et al. 1978). Dills et al. (2008) use aggregate data to demonstrate that raw correlations between crime rates and deterrence variables are frequently weak or even perverse due to the problem of reverse causality and note that any identification strategy would need to be powerful enough to partial out the effect of deterrence on the crime rate and provide a result consistent with economic theory.
Table 1
Empirical estimates of the elasticity of the crime rate with respect to policing and justice
Authors
Year
Population
Unit of observation
Data (sample size)
Method
Crime type
Arrest
Conviction
Imprisonment
Sentence length
Panel A: Complete economic models of crime
   Entorf and Spengler
Germany
West German states
Panel (10, 25)
FGLS
Violent
\(-\) 0.225
\(-\) 0.251
\(-\) 0.006
0.019
Property
\(-\) 0.155
\(-\) 0.228
\(-\) 0.055
0.029
   Cornwell and Trumbull
North Carolina
County
Panel (90, 7)
OLS, 2SLS
Total
\(-\) 0.455
\(-\) 0.336
\(-\) 0.196
\(-\) 0.03
   Trumbull
North Carolina
County
Cross section (98)
OLS
Total
\(-\) 0.217
\(-\) 0.451
\(-\) 0.325
\(-\) 0.149
   Pyle
England and Wales
Police authorities
Cross section (41)
OLS
Robbery
\(-\) 0.5
0.73
\(-\) 0.48
\(-\) 0.57
Property
\(-\) 0.32
0.4
\(-\) 0.55
\(-\) 0.85
   Wolpin
USA, England and Wales
Country
Panel (3, 17)
OLS
Robbery
\(-\) 0.537
\(-\) 0.460
\(-\) 1.13
\(-\) 1.27
Panel B: Arrest
   Klick and Tabarrok
Washington D.C.
Police district
Panel (7,506)
OLS
Violent
\(-\) 0.3
   
Burglary
\(-\) 0.3
   
   Fajnzylber et al.
United Nations
Country
Panel (45, 5)
GMM
Robbery
0.08
  
.035
Homicide
\(-\) 0.09
  
\(-\) 0.346
   Corman and Mocan
New York
City
Time series (108)
OLS
Murder
\(-\) 0.336
   
Burglary
\(-\) 0.355
   
   Bodman and Maultby
Australia
State
Cross section (60)
2SLS
Robbery
\(-\) 0.258
  
\(-\) 0.621
Burglary
\(-\) 0.367
   
   Levitt
USA
City
Panel (59, 23)
2SLS
Violent
\(-\) 0.9\(^{*}\)
   
Property
\(-\) 0.24\(^{*}\)
   
   Marvell and Moody
USA
City
Panel (56, 22)
Granger
Total
\(-\) 0.133
   
Homicide
\(-\) 0.241
   
Burglary
\(-\) 0.151
   
   Sampson and Cohen
USA
City
Cross section (171)
2SLS
Robbery
\(-\) 0.28
   
Burglary
\(-\) 0.12
   
   Car-Hill and Stern
England and Wales
Police districts
Cross section (64)
FIML
Total
\(-\) 0.59
  
\(-\) 0.17
Panel C: Imprisonment
   Johnson and Raphael
USA
State
Panel (51, 27)
2SLS
Violent
  
\(-\) 0.11
 
Property
  
\(-\) 0.21
 
   Lofstrom and Raphael
USA
County
Panel (19, 36)
2SLS
Violent
  
0.01
 
Property
  
\(-\) 0.09
 
   Liedka et al.
USA
State
Panel (51, 29)
Granger
Total
  
\(-\) 0.245
 
Murder
  
\(-\) 0.13
 
Burglary
  
\(-\) 0.136
 
   Levitt
USA
City
Panel (100, 21)
2SLS
Violent
\(-\) 0.435
 
\(-\) 0.171
 
Property
\(-\) 0.501
 
\(-\) 0.305
 
   Witt and Witte
USA
Country
Time series (38)
VAR
Total
  
\(-\) 0.55
 
   Levitt
USA
State
Panel (51, 23)
2SLS
Violent
  
\(-\) 0.261
 
Property
  
\(-\) 0.379
 
   Marvell and Moody
USA
State
Panel (49, 19)
Granger
Total
  
\(-\) 0.159
 
Homicide
  
\(-\) 0.065
 
Burglary
  
\(-\) 0.253
 
   Ehrlich
USA
State
Cross section (47)
2SLS
Total
  
\(-\) 0.991
\(-\) 1.123
Panel D: Conviction and other studies
   Haas
1980
New Jersey
Municipality
Cross section (181)
2SLS
Total
 
\(-\) 0.02
  
   Withers
Australia
State
Cross section (104)
OLS
Violent
 
0.29
0.09
 
Total
 
\(-\) 0.62
\(-\) 0.6
 
Property
 
\(-\) 0.59
\(-\) 0.56
 
   Sjoquist
USA
Municipality
Cross section (53)
OLS
Theft
\(-\) 0.342
\(-\) 0.678
 
\(-\) 0.212
\(^*\) Author provided multiple estimates, in which case the median is reported
Table 1 summarizes the empirical results for some widely cited contributions to the crime deterrence literature using aggregate data.5 For each of the studies noted, the table reports the sampling population, the unit of observation, the structure of the data followed by the sample size6, the method used to estimate the model, the type of crime analysed and finally the actual results. Clearly, there is a paucity of studies that estimate a fully specified economic model of crime, with notable exceptions being the papers by Wolpin (1978, 1980), Pyle (1984), Trumbull (1989), Cornwell and Trumbull (1994) and Entorf and Spengler (2008, 2015). In most of these studies, least-squares-based methods are used to obtain estimates of the parameters; hence, all deterrence variables are treated as exogenous. Trumbull (1989) justifies this choice claiming that endogeneity is not a salient feature of the existing data set, based on the results of a Wu–Hausman specification test. A few studies also apply IV regression and treat the probability of arrest as endogenous, but all remaining variables as exogenous (Cornwell and Trumbull 1994; Entorf and Spengler 2008, 2015). The authors fail to find a statistically significant relationship between the deterrence variables and crime using a 2SLS procedure.7
The remaining studies restrict their attention to a particular variable of interest. Failing to include all deterrence variables fosters a disconnect between economic theory and empirical analysis. In order for a criminal to be punished, the person must be arrested and found guilty first; omitting the probability of arrest and conviction clearly ignores a fundamental aspect of the criminal decision. For example, Mustard (2003) shows that arrest rates are likely to be negatively correlated with the probability of conviction and sentence length since arrest rates are often substitutes for conviction rates and sentences. As a result, Mustard (2003) concludes that previous estimates of the marginal effect of the probability of arrest may understate the true effect of the arrest rate by as much as 50%. Furthermore, omitted variables may invalidate estimation based on instrumental variables. Candidate instrumental variables may not be orthogonal to the deterrence variables omitted from the regression; hence, actually they do not constitute instruments.

3 Econometric specification

3.1 Model

The dependent variable is the rate of crime, which is defined as the ratio of the number of crime offences committed in a given local government area (LGA) i at time t (labelled \(crm_{it}\)) over population (\(pop_{it}\)). The rate of crime is not the same as the binary ‘crime–no crime’ decision an individual faces, but it is arguably the closest substitute one can observe at the aggregate level.
The economic model of crime postulates that criminals are rational individuals who assess the risk of apprehension and conviction as well as the likelihood of punishment prior to committing an offence, and ultimately evaluate the expected benefit and cost associated with an illegal activity. Therefore, the crime rate is modelled as a function of the empirical probability of arrest, the empirical probability of conviction given arrest and the empirical probability of imprisonment given conviction.
This leads to the following specification:
$$\begin{aligned} \ln \left( \frac{crm_{it}}{pop_{it}}\right)= & {} \alpha \ln \left( \frac{ crm_{it-1}}{pop_{it-1}}\right) +\beta _{1}\ln \left( \frac{arr_{it}}{crm_{it} }\right) +\beta _{2}\ln \left( \frac{conv_{it}}{arr_{it}}\right) \nonumber \\&+\beta _{3}\ln \left( \frac{impr_{it}}{conv_{it}}\right) +\beta _{4}\ln avsen_{it}+\beta _{5}\ln income_{it} \nonumber \\&+\beta _{6}\ln unemp_{it}+\eta _{i}+\lambda _{t}+\varepsilon _{it}\text {,} \end{aligned}$$
(1)
for \(t=1,\ldots ,T\) time periods and \(i=1,\ldots ,N\) regions, where \((crm_{it},arr_{it},conv_{it},impr_{it})\) denote the number of crime offences, arrests, convictions and imprisonments, respectively. The inclusion of sentence length (\(avsen_{it}\)), income (\(income_{it}\)) and unemployment (\( unemp_{it}\)) in the above equation captures the expected cost/gains from the illegal and legal sectors. Precise definitions of all variables used in our regression analysis are provided in Table 2.
Table 2
Definition of variables in the crime model
Variable
Definition
crmr
Number of criminal incidents divided by total population
prbarr
Number of arrests divided by criminal incidents
prbconv
Number of convictions divided by arrests
prbimpr
Number of imprisonments divided by convictions
avsen
Average non-parole period (months) imposed for prison sentences
income
Average wage and salary earner income
unemp
Unemployment rate (%)
Using short-hand notation, the model can be rewritten as:
$$\begin{aligned} \ln crmr_{it}= & {} \alpha \ln crmr_{it-1}+\beta _{1}\ln prbarr_{it}+\beta _{2}\ln prbconv_{it} \nonumber \\&+\beta _{3}\ln prbimpr_{it}+\beta _{4}\ln avsen_{it}+\beta _{5}\ln income_{it} \nonumber \\&+\beta _{6}\ln unemp_{it}+\eta _{i}+\lambda _{t}+\varepsilon _{it}. \end{aligned}$$
(2)
The error term in (2) allows for regional-specific effects (\(\eta _{i}\)), which may be correlated with the regressors, as well as time effects (\(\lambda _{t}\)) that capture common variations in crime across regions. The coefficient of the lagged value of the dependent variable, \(\alpha \), measures the combined effect of short-run dynamics and time-varying omitted regressors hidden in lagged crime rates.
We also considered the possibility that criminals may form expectations about conviction rates in an adaptive manner, implying that lags of these variables should also be included on the right-hand side. We tested specifications including such lagged effects but they were largely insignificant.
Finally, it is worth mentioning that many of the models used in the literature (see e.g. Table 1) are restricted versions of (2). For example, many studies do include the probability of arrest, but exclude the probabilities of conviction and imprisonment and sentence lengths.

3.2 Identification strategy

We estimate model (2) by the generalized method of moments (GMM) developed originally by Hansen (1982) and adapted for estimation of dynamic panel data models by Arellano and Bond (1991), Arellano and Bover (1995) and Blundell and Bond (1998). The GMM approach has the advantage that, compared to maximum likelihood, it requires much weaker assumptions about the initial conditions of the data generating process and avoids full specification of the serial correlation and heteroskedasticity properties of the error, or indeed any other distributional assumptions. Moreover, GMM is a natural choice when multiple explanatory variables are endogenous. For the reasons discussed in Sect. 2, we treat the probability of arrest as an endogenous regressor. The lagged crime rate, which models the short-run dynamics, is an additional endogenous regressor.
To remove the region-specific effects, first differences are taken from the original model in levels (2) resulting in:
$$\begin{aligned} \Delta \ln crmr_{it}= & {} \alpha \Delta \ln crmr_{it-1}+\beta _{1}\Delta \ln prbarr_{it}+\beta _{2}\Delta \ln prbcon\text {v}_{it} \nonumber \\&+\beta _{3}\Delta \ln prbimpr_{it}+\beta _{4}\Delta \ln a\text {v} sen_{it}+\beta _{5}\Delta \ln income_{it} \nonumber \\&+\beta _{6}\Delta \ln unemp_{it}+\Delta \lambda _{t}+\Delta \varepsilon _{it}. \end{aligned}$$
(3)
GMM estimation of the first-differenced model (3) has been developed by Arellano and Bond (1991). Since dynamic panels are often largely overidentified, an important practical issue is how many moment conditions to use. It is well documented that numerous instruments can overfit endogenous variables in finite samples, resulting in a trade-off between bias and efficiency. There is substantial theoretical work on the overfitting bias of GMM coefficient estimators in panel data models (Ziliak 1997; Alvarez and Arellano 2003; Bun and Kiviet 2006). Furthermore, with many moment conditions the power of (mis)specification tests deteriorates rapidly (Bowsher 2002). Roodman (2009) compares two popular approaches for limiting the number of instruments: (i) the use of (up to) certain lags instead of all available lags and (ii) combining instruments into smaller sets. Using asymptotic expansion techniques, Bun and Kiviet (2006) show that the order of magnitude of bias is reduced when going from all moment conditions to using only nearest lags as instruments. Furthermore, their simulation results show that when the number of time periods is a double digit, like \(T=13\) in the current study, the GMM estimator using nearest lags as instruments has much less finite-sample bias than the GMM estimator using all moment conditions. Therefore, we follow the recommendation of using a limited number of moment conditions and only employ the three nearest lagged instruments. Furthermore, we collapse them resulting in the following six moment conditions for the model in first differences:
$$\begin{aligned} E\left[ \sum _{t=3+j}^{T}\ln crmr_{it-2-j}\Delta \varepsilon _{it}\right] =0;\qquad E\left[ \sum _{t=3+j}^{T}\ln prbarr_{it-2-j}\Delta \varepsilon _{it} \right] =0\text {,} \end{aligned}$$
(4)
for \(j=0,1,2\). We note that another advantage of collapsed instruments is that the underlying time-specific moment conditions do not need to hold exactly for each time period, but only in sum. Regarding the probability of arrest, we will also estimate a specification under weak exogeneity, in which case we make use of
$$\begin{aligned} E\left[ \sum _{t=3}^{T}\ln prbarr_{it-1}\Delta \varepsilon _{it}\right] =0 \text {.} \end{aligned}$$
(5)
Conviction and imprisonment rates, as well as the severity of punishment, are determined by the judiciary system. In practice, it is hard to believe that the judiciary system is strictly exogenous to crime rates. Similarly, it is natural to think that recent changes in economic conditions may exert some impact on current crime rates. As a result, we allow in estimation for a feedback relationship between past values of crime and current values of the remaining deterrence regressors (prbconv, prbimpr, avsen), as well as of economic conditions (income, unemp).
As it is briefly mentioned in Sect. 2, since the number of crime offences enters into both the numerator of \(\ln crmr\) and the denominator of \(\ln prbarr\) in Eq. (3), the model is subject to ratio bias. However, so long as the idiosyncratic error term of the model, \(\varepsilon _{it}\), is serially uncorrelated, then values of \(\ln prbarr_{it-1}\) lagged two or more periods may serve as valid instruments to identify \(\beta _{2}\).8
It is well known that identification can be weak when the panel data are persistent or, more generally, when the correlation between endogenous regressors and instruments is close to zero. We therefore check the identification strength of the exploited moment conditions in various ways. First, we estimate pure autoregressive models for the endogenous regressors and check whether autoregressive dynamics are reasonably far away from the unit root. Second, we use the Kleibergen and Paap (2006) rank statistic to test for underidentification in the first-differenced and levels IV models.
To check the validity of the estimated specification, we report the p value of Hansen’s (1982) J test of overidentifying restrictions and the p value of Arellano and Bond’s (1991) test of serial correlation of the disturbances up to second order. The former is used to determine empirically the validity of the overidentifying restrictions in the GMM model. The latter is useful because the use of lagged values of the endogenous variables as instruments (in levels) requires that serial correlation in the idiosyncratic error term is only up to a certain order.9
Long-run estimates are computed by dividing the short-run slope coefficients by 1 minus the estimated autoregressive parameter. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses, which are valid under arbitrary forms of heteroskedasticity and serial correlation. Furthermore, we perform the correction proposed by Windmeijer (2005) for the finite-sample bias of the standard errors of the two-step GMM estimator.10 The standard errors of the long-run estimated parameters are subsequently obtained using the Delta method.

4 Data and results

4.1 Data

We construct a new data set containing information on criminal activity and deterrence for all \(N=153\) local government areas in New South Wales, each one observed over a period of \(T=13\) years from 1995/1996 to 2007/2008. The Australian Standard Geographic Classification (ASGC) defines the LGA as the lowest level of aggregation following the census Collection District (CD) and Statistical Local Area (SLA).11 Thus, the LGA represents a low level of aggregation compared to standard practice in the literature, where regressions using city-, state- and country-level data are common. LGAs in NSW range in size from over 350,000 people (3261.9 persons per \(\hbox {km}^{2}\) to a little over 2,000 people (i.e. less than one person per \(\hbox {km}^{2}\) ). The average LGA has a population of 58,438 persons (sd. = 77,585 persons) (Australian Bureau of Statistics 2017). Although LGAs include both urban and rural areas, most of the population of NSW can be found in urban rather than rural areas. The three cities of Sydney, Newcastle and Wollongong account for three quarters of the NSW population (NSW Department of Industry 2017).
Our data on crime are drawn from COPS—the NSW Police Operational Policing System, to which the NSW Bureau of Crime Statistics and Research has online access. This system records each crime incident reported to or discovered by police. A crime incident is defined as an activity detected by or reported to police which:
  • Involved the same offender(s);
  • Involved the same victims(s);
  • Occurred at one location;
  • Occurred during one uninterrupted period of time;
  • Falls into one offence category;
  • Falls into one incident type (e.g. ‘actual’, ‘attempted’, ‘conspiracy’).
The data are categorized according to the date of reporting to or detection by police, not by the date of occurrence of the offence. The deterrence variables (probabilities of arrest, conviction and imprisonment, as well as average non-parole period length) are drawn from a separate database on court appearances and outcomes maintained by the NSW Bureau of Crime Statistics and Research. This database contains information, inter alia, on the charge(s) laid against each offender, which charge(s) resulted in a conviction, whether a prison sentence was imposed, the length of the aggregate (total) sentence and the length of the non-parole period. The aggregate sentence is the maximum time the offender can be held in custody for the offence(s) he/she has committed. The non-parole period defines the minimum period the offender must spend in custody before being released on parole. Where the aggregate sentence is less than 6 months, no non-parole period can be specified. In this instance, the aggregate sentence defines the minimum period the offender must spend in custody. For the purposes of this analysis, we define the sentence length as the length of the non-parole period where one is specified and the length of the aggregate sentence where the aggregate sentence is less than 6 months.12
It is worth noting that in NSW there are three levels to the NSW court system, namely the Supreme, District and Local Courts. However, more than 90% of criminal cases are finalized in a Local Court, where guilt or innocence is determined by a magistrate rather than by a judge or jury. In 2016, more than 90% of Local Court cases resulted in a conviction on at least one charge, in most cases because the defendant pleaded guilty.13 The average time taken to finalize a Local Court matter in 2016 was 64 days. The only offences examined here that are exclusively dealt with by a higher court (i.e. the District or Supreme Court) are those involving robbery, homicide and some serious sexual offences. The majority of these cases also involve a guilty plea. The average time to finalize a guilty plea in the higher courts is around 14 months but the distribution is highly skewed, with the majority of guilty pleas being finalized in less than 12 months. In the vast majority of cases, then, only a short period elapses between arrest and sentence and most of those arrested will end up convicted.
Income and population data have been obtained from the Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) website, while the unemployment data have been purchased from the Small Area Labour Markets division of the Department of Education, Employment and Workplace Relations (DEEWR). The raw data for income and population are not readily comparable with the crime data because they are based on different ASGC standards, i.e. LGA boundaries are defined slightly differently by the NSW Bureau and the ABS. To this end, we mapped the data to a common ASGC standard (2006) using a series of concordance tables, in order to achieve consistency. Similarly, the unemployment data were first mapped to the same ASGC standard (2006) to account for name and boundary changes that occurred in the LGAs over the sample period. The resulting SLA data were then aggregated to the LGA level to be directly comparable to the other data.
We distinguish between two broad crime categories, i.e. property and violent crime. Property crime is defined as any incident of robbery without a weapon, robbery with a firearm, robbery with a weapon not a firearm, stealing property in a dwelling house, motor vehicle theft, stealing from motor vehicle, stealing from retail store, stealing from dwelling, stealing from person, stock theft, other theft and fraud. Violent crime is defined as any incident of homicide, non-domestic violence-related assault, domestic violence-related assault, robbery without a weapon, robbery with a firearm, robbery with a weapon not a firearm, sexual assault, indecent assault or act of indecency, or other sexual offence.14
Since both property and violent crime comprise individual crime categories that have quite different occurrence and level of seriousness, adding them all up together using simple (unweighted) summation can potentially invalidate inferences.15 For instance, a homicide incident occurs less often and can be far more severe compared to a robbery incident. Therefore, in what follows we analyse weighted sums of property and violent crime. The weights are computed using two different ways. Firstly, we compute variance weights based on the sample within standard deviation of the individual crime types. This set of weights reflects the fact that more severe types of crime occur less often. Secondly, we compute weights based on the ‘average seriousness score per incident’ reported in Heller and McEwen (1973) and Blumstein (1974).16 The seriousness scores for each of the aforementioned crime categories are as follows: theft, 2.29; robbery, 6.43; assault, 9.74; homicide, 33.29. These scores have been adjusted such that in each of the two broad crime categories, they add up to unity.17
In order to deal effectively with heterogeneity across different individual crime types, we also analyse in length each of the aforementioned four crime types separately, namely theft, robbery, assault and homicide. These four categories broadly span the classification of crime offences often used in the literature, see e.g. Table 1 in the present paper, as well as Table 1 in Cherry and List (2002).
The various deterrence variables (probabilities of arrest, conviction and imprisonment, as well as average prison length) are computed specifically for each type of crime analysed. This accommodates the expectation that, apart from having different values across crime types, these variables may potentially have a different deterrence effect across crime types.
Table 3
Descriptive statistics
Variable
Crime type
Mean
Stdev
10th Perc
90th Perc
Crime rate
 
Property
0.047
0.028
0.023
0.074
Violent
0.009
0.010
0.003
0.013
Theft
0.049
0.029
0.024
0.092
Robbery
0.001
0.002
0.000
0.002
Assault
0.012
0.013
0.004
0.018
Homicide
0.000
0.000
0.000
0.000
Probability of arrest
 
Property
0.087
0.049
0.040
0.149
Violent
0.611
0.177
0.386
0.182
Theft
0.087
0.049
0.040
0.149
Robbery
0.396
0.247
0.000
0.975
Assault
0.617
0.174
0.403
0.840
Homicide
0.665
0.453
0.000
0.983
Probability of conviction
 
Property
0.366
0.309
0.138
0.594
Violent
0.391
0.140
0.251
0.540
Theft
0.360
0.278
0.135
0.588
Robbery
0.604
0.659
0.250
0.967
Assault
0.378
0.132
0.244
0.361
Homicide
0.646
0.670
0.000
0.966
Probability of imprisonment
 
Property
0.107
0.119
0.000
0.219
Violent
0.098
0.083
0.000
0.239
Theft
0.101
0.112
0.000
0.212
Robbery
0.373
0.275
0.000
0.700
Assault
0.083
0.083
0.000
0.177
Homicide
0.522
0.222
0.000
1.000
Average sentence (days)
 
Property
3.742
3.089
0.000
6.950
Violent
22.62
28.41
1.358
58.58
Theft
5.065
2.437
2.500
7.496
Robbery
11.62
7.497
4.500
19.00
Assault
6.902
5.621
3.000
11.50
Homicide
2043
12612
12.000
180.0
Income ($ ’000)
 
34.0
9.4
25.2
44.0
Unemployment (%)
 
7.1
5.1
3.0
12.4
Descriptive statistics computed for the variables used in regression analysis. \(N=153\) and \(T=13\), yielding a total of 1989 observations
Table 4
Sample correlation coefficients
 
crmr
prbarr
prbconv
prbimpr
avsen
income
unemp
Property crime
   crmr
1
      
   prbarr
\(-\) 0.003
1
     
   prbconv
\(-\) 0.121
\(-\) 0.390
1
    
   prbimpr
0.096
0.100
0.014
1
   
   avsen
0.182
\(-\) 0.065
0.099
0.376
1
  
   income
0.073
\(-\) 0.406
0.052
\(-\) 0.030
0.195
1
 
   unemp
0.165
0.277
\(-\) 0.067
0.082
0.089
\(-\) 0.317
1
Violent crime
   crmr
1
      
   prbarr
0.161
1
     
   prbconv
\(-\) 0.254
\(-\) 0.194
1
    
   prbimpr
0.206
0.112
0.005
1
   
   avsen
\(-\) 0.005
\(-\) 0.048
0.008
0.025
1
  
   income
\(-\) 0.147
\(-\) 0.466
\(-\) 0.085
\(-\) 0.174
0.001
1
 
   unemp
0.131
0.170
\(-\) 0.004
0.169
\(-\) 0.002
\(-\) 0.317
1
Descriptive statistics computed for the variables used in regression analysis. \(N=153\) and \(T=13\), yielding a total of 1989 observations
Tables 3 and 4 report descriptive statistics for the various categories of crime considered in our analysis.18 As expected, the mean value of the rate of violent crime, as well as that of its individual crime components, is smaller than that of property crime and it exhibits a much smaller dispersion as well. This indicates that violent crime occurs less frequently and is more localized. The empirical probability of arrest is higher on average for violent crime than property crime, which reflects the fact that in many cases violent crime involves face-to-face contact increasing the probability of apprehension. In regard to the category of homicides, the mean value of average sentence length is much larger than the value in the 90th percentile, which indicates that there are a relatively small number of very big sentences in the sample.
Figures 1 and 2 show the development over time of property and violent crime as well as their corresponding arrest rates. Cross-sectional averages have been plotted; hence, the line graphs depict average development across LGAs. Figure 1 shows that property crime increases gradually in the 1990s, peaks around 2000 and then falls sharply afterwards. The property crime arrest rate gradually decreases until 2003 and then stabilizes. By contrast as shown in Fig. 2, average violent crime increases steadily until 2002, and then, it exhibits a small downward trend. At the same time, the arrest rate declines until 2002 and it follows an upward trend after that date. Figure 3 shows that economic conditions, i.e. per capita income and unemployment, improved steadily over the whole sample period.
To get an idea of the time-series persistence in our data, we estimate pure autoregressive models for the crime rate and the probability of arrest, i.e. the endogenous regressors in our empirical analysis. System GMM estimates of autoregressive coefficients are in the range 0.2–0.6, which shows moderate persistence only. Not surprisingly panel unit root tests (Harris and Tzavalis 1999; Im et al. 2003) reject the null hypothesis of a unit root for both crime rates and probability of arrest and for both property and violent crime.

4.2 Baseline results

We analyse the weighted sums of property crime and violent crime, based on the econometric model presented in the previous section. First-differenced GMM estimates allowing for endogeneity of lagged crime and the probability of arrest are reported in Tables 5 and 6. We treat all remaining explanatory variables as weakly exogenous. In Table 5, aggregate crime series have been constructed using the within standard deviation of individual crime types, whereas in Table 6 aggregate crime series have been constructed using weights computed based on the average seriousness score per incident.
Table 5
GMM estimates of the (weighted) crime model
 
Property
Violent
Short run
Long run
Short run
Long run
Lagged crime rate
0.225
 
0.425
 
(0.125)
 
(0.143)
 
Probability of arrest
\(-\) 0.283
\(-\) 0.365
\(-\) 0.398
\(-\) 0.692
(0.113)
(0.181)
(0.169)
(0.173)
Probability of conviction
\(-\) 0.148
\(-\) 0.191
\(-\) 0.325
\(-\) 0.564
(0.043)
(0.069)
(0.050)
(0.150)
Probability of imprisonment
\(-\) 0.019
\(-\) 0.025
\(-\) 0.016
\(-\) 0.027
(0.013)
(0.018)
(0.013)
(0.023)
Average sentence
0.019
0.025
0.010
0.017
(0.017)
(0.024)
(0.007)
(0.012)
Income
\(-\) 0.452
\(-\) 0.583
0.174
0.302
(0.306)
(0.402)
(0.309)
(0.527)
Unemployment
\(-\) 0.043
\(-\) 0.055
\(-\) 0.322
\(-\) 0.500
(0.095)
(0.122)
(0.145)
(0.333)
p value oir
0.465
 
0.152
 
p value rank test
0.000
 
0.000
 
p value serial correlation
    
   lag 1
0.000
 
0.000
 
   lag 2
0.047
 
0.960
 
Weights are computed based on the within standard deviation of individual crime types. Each regression includes LGA- and time-specific effects
Table 6
GMM estimates of the (weighted) crime model
 
Property
Violent
Short run
Long run
Short run
Long run
Lagged crime rate
0.218
 
0.405
 
(0.119)
 
(0.145)
 
Probability of arrest
\(-\) 0.297
\(-\) 0.380
\(-\) 0.400
\(-\) 0.672
(0.105)
(0.172)
(0.170)
(0.184)
Probability of conviction
\(-\) 0.215
\(-\) 0.275
\(-\) 0.318
\(-\) 0.535
(0.053)
(0.089)
(0.055)
(0.148)
Probability of imprisonment
\(-\) 0.035
\(-\) 0.044
\(-\) 0.031
\(-\) 0.052
(0.016)
(0.024)
(0.014)
(0.027)
Average sentence
0.009
0.012
0.005
0.009
(0.011)
(0.015)
(0.004)
(0.006)
Income
\(-\) 0.578
\(-\) 0.739
0.176
0.296
(0.278)
(0.366)
(0.310)
(0.511)
Unemployment
\(-\) 0.058
\(-\) 0.075
0.322
0.542
(0.093)
(0.118)
(0.145)
(0.329)
p value oir
0.456
 
0.471
 
p value rank test
0.000
 
0.000
 
p value serial correlation
    
   lag 1
0.000
 
0.000
 
   lag 2
0.052
 
0.789
 
Weights are computed based on the average seriousness score per incident. Each regression includes LGA- and time-specific effects
The results reported in Tables 5 and 6 are remarkably similar even if the corresponding weights take rather different values. Therefore, we only discuss the results in Table 5 based on variance weights. To begin with, the p values from the reported overidentifying restrictions test show no evidence of lack of validity of the estimated specification. Furthermore, the Kleibergen and Paap (2006) rank test indicates no underidentification in either equation as the null hypothesis is soundly rejected at the 5% level of significance.
The GMM estimates of the deterrence effects are of the expected sign with the exception of the coefficient of average sentence, which is largely insignificant. For property crime, a 1% increase in the probability of arrest appears to decrease the expected value of the crime rate by 0.283% in the short run and 0.365% in the long run, ceteris paribus. Likewise, the elasticity of the probability of conviction is about \(-\,0.148\) and \(-\,0.191\) in the short and long run, respectively. The fact that the estimated elasticities are larger in the long run is well anticipated, since typically one needs time to adjust fully to changes in law enforcement policies, due to habitual behaviour, imperfect knowledge and uncertainty. In particular, the value of the autoregressive parameter indicates that it takes about 2 years for 90% of the total impact of either one of the explanatory variables on crime to be realized, all else being constant.
The estimated coefficients of the probability of imprisonment are much smaller compared to the coefficients of the probability of arrest and the probability of conviction, whereas the effect of average sentence is insignificant as mentioned above. This indicates that imprisoning more criminals, or imprisoning them for longer, is not as effective as increasing the risk of apprehension or conviction once arrested. In other words, criminal activity seems to be highly responsive to the prospect of arrest and conviction, but less responsive to the prospect or severity of imprisonment. This provides support to the idea that the consequences of being arrested and found guilty of a criminal offence include the indirect sanctions imposed by society and not just the punishment meted out by the criminal justice system. A convicted individual may no longer enjoy the same opportunities in the labour market or the same treatment by their peers, and so the opportunity cost of lost income and the cost to the individual of social stigmatization are implied in the event of conviction. Zimring and Hawkins (1973, p 174) argue:
Official actions can set off societal reactions that may provide potential offenders with more reason to avoid conviction than the officially imposed unpleasantness of punishment.
The results suggest that the lost social standing resulting from a conviction may well outweigh the effects of prison sentence, let alone a fine or community service order.
Table 7 presents results for the four disaggregated crime categories. The conclusions are qualitatively similar to those of the weighted aggregates. In particular, the estimated deterrence effects are of the expected sign, with the exception of average sentence, the effect of which is largely statistically insignificant. Moreover, the coefficients of the risk of apprehension and conviction remain much larger than those of the probability of imprisonment and average sentence. Hence, increasing the risk of apprehension or conviction once arrested appears to be much more effective compared to the practice of imprisoning more criminals, or imprisoning them for longer.
There are two notable differences in the results obtained between the disaggregated and aggregated crime offences. Firstly, the standard error of the estimated coefficients obtained from the disaggregated models is relatively larger in general. This reflects the fact that the sample size for individual crime categories is smaller because there are quite more zero-crime occurrences in this case.19 Secondly, arguably for the same reason, the p value of the rank test statistics indicates a potential weak instruments problem for the robbery and homicide equations, and less so for theft. This shows that analysing weighted aggregates of individual crime categories is quite appealing in this respect.
Table 7
GMM estimates for disaggregated crime types
 
Theft
Robbery
Assault
Homicide
Lagged crime rate
0.366
0.132
0.526
0.024
(0.201)
(0.107)
(0.151)
(0.091)
Probability of arrest
\(-\) 0.365
\(-\) 0.628
\(-\) 0.348
\(-\) 0.706
(0.262)
(0.259)
(0.203)
(0.374)
Probability of conviction
\(-\) 0.238
\(-\) 0.582
\(-\) 0.301
\(-\) 0.480
(0.118)
(0.120)
(0.063)
(0.157)
Probability of imprisonment
\(-\) 0.026
\(-\) 0.083
\(-\) 0.047
\(-\) 0.168
(0.022)
(0.048)
(0.019)
(0.161)
Average sentence
0.018
0.063
0.022
0.005
(0.020)
(0.043)
(0.013)
(0.042)
Income
\(-\) 2.155
\(-\) 0.447
\(-\) 0.121
\(-\) 1.871
(1.824)
(2.076)
(0.907)
(2.499)
Unemployment
\(-\) 0.047
0.154
\(-\) 0.318
0.114
(0.062)
(0.315)
(0.187)
(2.006)
p value oir
0.437
0.318
0.093
0.118
p value rank test
0.149
0.924
0.000
0.816
p value serial correlation
    
   lag 1
0.005
0.000
0.000
0.000
   lag 2
0.002
0.383
0.856
0.413
See Table 5

4.3 Sensitivity analysis

As discussed previously, the arrest probability is often seen as an endogenous regressor in the empirical crime literature. Hence, we have estimated our baseline crime model allowing for endogeneity of the probability of arrest. However, efficiency gains in the coefficient estimates may arise by imposing weak exogeneity on this main deterrence regressor. As such, we have re-estimated the model allowing for weak exogeneity in the probability of arrest. In this case, we add (5) into the set of moment conditions employed by the GMM estimator. The results are reported in Table 8.
Table 8
GMM estimates under weak exogeneity
 
Property
Violent
Theft
Robbery
Assault
Homicide
Lagged crime rate
0.285
0.379
0.440
0.158
0.487
0.042
(0.110)
(0.127)
(0.159)
(0.094)
(0.172)
(0.100)
Probability of arrest
\(-\) 0.097
\(-\) 0.233
\(-\) 0.218
\(-\) 0.528
\(-\) 0.356
\(-\) 0.688
(0.037)
(0.069)
(0.087)
(0.111)
(0.088)
(0.181)
Probability of conviction
\(-\) 0.085
\(-\) 0.279
\(-\) 0.189
\(-\) 0.529
\(-\) 0.286
\(-\) 0.468
(0.027)
(0.043)
(0.056)
(0.095)
(0.052)
(0.109)
Probability of imprisonment
\(-\) 0.006
\(-\) 0.016
\(-\) 0.027
\(-\) 0.080
\(-\) 0.044
\(-\) 0.290
(0.009)
(0.013)
(0.019)
(0.047)
(0.019)
(0.224)
Average sentence
0.001
0.008
0.009
0.061
0.016
0.032
(0.010)
(0.008)
(0.016)
(0.043)
(0.013)
(0.038)
Income
\(-\) 0.708
0.329
\(-\) 1.340
0.625
0.375
4.894
(0.358)
(0.334)
(1.888)
(2.563)
(0.982)
(26.54)
Unemployment
\(-\) 0.038
\(-\) 0.311
\(-\) 0.010
0.028
\(-\) 0.452
0.588
(0.096)
(0.158)
(0.065)
(0.279)
(0.224)
(1.504)
p value oir
0.155
0.124
0.244
0.137
0.033
0.034
p value rank test
0.000
0.000
0.002
0.032
0.000
0.463
p value serial correlation
      
   lag 1
0.000
0.000
0.002
0.000
0.000
0.088
   lag 2
0.072
0.785
0.005
0.351
0.711
0.848
See Table 5
There are two main differences between Table 5 and Table 8. Firstly, in the latter case the standard error of the estimated coefficients is much smaller, often by a magnitude of less than a half. That is, imposing weak exogeneity substantially improves the efficiency of the estimated coefficients. Secondly, the p value of the overidentification test statistic is now smaller in general, although it remains larger than 0.05 in most cases. Furthermore, compared to Table 7 the p value of the rank test falls dramatically, such that this time a weak instruments problem is potentially an issue only for the homicide equation.
To further test the exogeneity of the probability of arrest and conviction, we apply the empirical test of Griliches and Hausman (1986) to detect the presence of measurement error. The idea is that long differences20, as opposed to first differences, are less vulnerable to measurement error. Therefore, in the absence of measurement error the OLS estimator of the arrest/conviction rate elasticity in the differenced crime model should not show any systematic pattern across the different lengths. Levitt (1998) applied this test to investigate the extent of measurement error and ratio bias in the crime arrest rate relationship and found no significant measurement error. Table 9 reports findings for the Australian crime data. To save space, we only report results with respect to the two broad crime categories, as well as, for each one of them, their most dominant sub-category, namely theft and assault.
Table 9
Different OLS estimators of the arrest and conviction rate elasticities
 
Arrest
Conviction
Property
Violent
Theft
Assault
Property
Violent
Theft
Assault
First difference
\(-\) 0.060
\(-\) 0.186
\(-\) 0.101
\(-\) 0.207
\(-\) 0.079
\(-\) 0.228
\(-\) 0.125
\(-\) 0.208
(0.012)
(0.032)
(0.025)
(0.036)
(0.015)
(0.025)
(0.017)
(0.027)
Second long difference
\(-\) 0.072
\(-\) 0.169
\(-\) 0.094
\(-\) 0.205
\(-\) 0.100
\(-\) 0.196
\(-\) 0.135
\(-\) 0.185
(0.028)
(0.039)
(0.027)
(0.043)
(0.019)
(0.026)
(0.020)
(0.029)
Third long difference
\(-\) 0.092
\(-\) 0.173
\(-\) 0.105
\(-\) 0.216
\(-\) 0.123
\(-\) 0.194
\(-\) 0.143
\(-\) 0.193
(0.033)
(0.045)
(0.031)
(0.048)
(0.021)
(0.030)
(0.022)
(0.033)
Fourth long difference
\(-\) 0.120
\(-\) 0.167
\(-\) 0.111
\(-\) 0.222
\(-\) 0.160
\(-\) 0.188
\(-\) 0.153
\(-\) 0.183
(0.036)
(0.050)
(0.035)
(0.053)
(0.021)
(0.036)
(0.022)
(0.040)
Cluster robust standard errors reported in parentheses. Control variables and time-specific effects included. The jth long difference of prbarr\(_{it}\)is defined as prbarr\(_{it}-\) prbarr\(_{i,t-j}\)
The results corroborate the findings of Levitt (1998) in that there is little evidence of measurement error and ratio bias in the probability of arrest and the probability of conviction. We took second, third and fourth long differences, and the arrest/conviction rate elasticity changes little across specifications.
Next, we analyse the sensitivity of our results to omitted deterrence variables. Mustard (2003) shows how excluding conviction rates and sentence length from the model leads to omitted variables bias. In particular, due to the negative correlation between these regressors and the probability of arrest, the true effect of arrest rates on crime may be underestimated. Table 10 reports results from specifications including only the probability of arrest as a deterrence variable, which is treated as endogenous.
Table 10
Excluding conviction and sentencing data
 
Property
Violent
Theft
Robbery
Assault
Homicide
Lagged crime rate
0.364
0.390
0.324
0.053
0.409
\(-\) 0.154
(0.108)
(0.085)
(0.107)
(0.084)
(0.089)
0.089
Probability of arrest
\(-\) 0.054
\(-\) 0.154
\(-\) 0.036
\(-\) 0.291
\(-\) 0.048
\(-\) 0.252
(0.065)
(0.101)
(0.066)
(0.092)
(0.114)
(0.125)
Income
\(-\) 0.427
\(-\) 0.319
\(-\) 1.077
\(-\) 2.186
\(-\) 0.491
3.381
(0.234)
(0.199)
(0.403)
(1.249)
(0.362)
(3.921)
Unemployment
\(-\) 0.152
0.010
\(-\) 0.161
0.269
0.001
0.163
(0.079)
(0.050)
(0.820)
(0.221)
(0.057)
(0.361)
p value oir
0.009
0.016
0.007
0.122
0.025
0.683
p value rank test
0.035
0.000
0.007
0.109
0.001
0.752
p value serial correlation
      
   lag 1
0.000
0.000
0.000
0.000
0.000
0.000
   lag 2
0.453
0.753
0.765
0.600
0.987
0.826
Probability of conviction, imprisonment and average sentence length omitted
Probability of arrest is treated as endogenous
Table 11
POLS estimates of the crime model
 
Property
Violent
Theft
Robbery
Assault
Homicide
Lagged crime rate
0.922
0.883
0.917
0.557
0.892
0.338
(0.010)
(0.008)
(0.010)
(0.016)
(0.008)
(0.038)
Probability of arrest
\(-\) 0.042
\(-\) 0.058
\(-\) 0.078
\(-\) 0.413
\(-\) 0.059
\(-\) 0.476
(0.012)
(0.019)
(0.014)
(0.023)
(0.019)
(0.056)
Probability of conviction
\(-\) 0.072
\(-\) 0.201
\(-\) 0.100
\(-\) 0.385
\(-\) 0.183
\(-\) 0.518
(0.008)
(0.017)
(0.010)
(0.016)
(0.017)
(0.039)
Probability of imprisonment
\(-\) 0.010
\(-\) 0.007
\(-\) 0.015
0.044
\(-\) 0.005
\(-\) 0.091
(0.005)
(0.006)
(0.006)
(0.024)
(0.007)
(0.067)
Average sentence
0.012
0.004
\(-\) 0.003
0.020
\(-\) 0.007
0.014
(0.005)
(0.005)
(0.007)
(0.021)
(0.013)
(0.013)
Income
\(-\) 0.090
\(-\) 0.164
\(-\) 0.153
\(-\) 0.772
\(-\) 0.217
\(-\) 1.398
(0.023)
(0.027)
(0.025)
(0.076)
(0.029)
(0.224)
Unemployment
0.038
0.046
0.026
0.081
0.021
\(-\) 0.077
(0.009)
(0.009)
(0.009)
(0.026)
(0.009)
(0.067)
See Table 5
Table 12
LSDV estimates of the crime model
 
Property
Violent
Theft
Robbery
Assault
Homicide
Lagged crime rate
0.686
0.402
0.580
0.152
0.417
0.028
(0.019)
(0.019)
(0.020)
(0.021)
(0.020)
(0.044)
Probability of arrest
\(-\) 0.043
\(-\) 0.266
\(-\) 0.141
\(-\) 0.451
\(-\) 0.248
\(-\) 0.659
(0.014)
(0.024)
(0.017)
(0.024)
(0.025)
(0.058)
Probability of conviction
\(-\) 0.088
\(-\) 0.289
\(-\) 0.168
\(-\) 0.449
\(-\) 0.271
\(-\) 0.551
(0.010)
(0.017)
(0.013)
(0.018)
(0.017)
(0.041)
Probability of imprisonment
\(-\) 0.004
\(-\) 0.012
\(-\) 0.021
\(-\) 0.079
\(-\) 0.029
\(-\) 0.286
(0.005)
(0.006)
(0.007)
(0.020)
(0.007)
(0.066)
Average sentence
\(-\) 0.004
0.012
\(-\) 0.018
0.007
\(-\) 0.001
0.009
(0.006)
(0.004)
(0.007)
(0.017)
(0.007)
(0.012)
Income
\(-\) 0.319
0.060
\(-\) 0.699
\(-\) 1.079
0.065
\(-\) 1.564
(0.033)
(0.036)
(0.039)
(0.087)
(0.043)
(0.321)
Unemployment
0.103
0.006
0.022
0.062
\(-\) 0.001
0.020
(0.013)
(0.013)
(0.013)
(0.030)
(0.014)
(0.099)
See Table 5
Table 13
SUR estimates of the crime model
 
Property
Violent
Theft
Robbery
Assault
Homicide
Lagged crime rate
0.209
0.197
0.525
0.314
0.503
\(-\) 0.046
(0.019)
(0.029)
(0.042)
(0.043)
(0.047)
(0.042)
Probability of arrest
\(-\) 0.284
\(-\) 0.378
\(-\) 0.186
\(-\) 0.299
\(-\) 0.212
\(-\) 0.543
(0.016)
(0.029)
(0.035)
(0.036)
(0.045)
(0.055)
Probability of conviction
\(-\) 0.296
\(-\) 0.394
\(-\) 0.208
\(-\) 0.365
\(-\) 0.276
\(-\) 0.477
(0.012)
(0.023)
(0.032)
(0.028)
(0.043)
(0.039)
Probability of imprisonment
\(-\) 0.014
\(-\) 0.023
\(-\) 0.004
\(-\) 0.020
0.015
\(-\) 0.214
(0.007)
(0.016)
(0.012)
(0.031)
(0.014)
(0.062)
Average sentence
\(-\) 0.000
0.011
\(-\) 0.007
0\(-\) .002
0.012
0.023
(0.008)
(0.012)
(0.015)
(0.033)
(0.013)
(0.012)
Income
\(-\) 0.846
\(-\) 0.719
\(-\) 0.466
\(-\) 0.621
\(-\) 0.041
0.601
(0.129)
(0.508)
(0.215)
(0.487)
(0.262)
(1.16)
Unemployment
0.016
0.027
\(-\) 0.027
\(-\) 0.073
0.060
0.040
(0.013)
(0.024)
(0.017)
(0.039)
(0.021)
(0.092)
See Table 5
Table 14
MG estimates of the crime model
 
Property
Violent
Theft
Robbery
Assault
Homicide
Lagged crime rate
0.619
0.269
0.511
0.249
0.198
0.007
(0.052)
(0.042)
(0.050)
(0.047)
(0.043)
(0.043)
Probability of arrest
\(-\) 0.108
\(-\) 0.195
\(-\) 0.149
\(-\) 0.379
\(-\) 0.266
\(-\) 0.403
(0.044)
(0.059)
(0.053)
(0.069)
(0.063)
(0.221)
Probability of conviction
\(-\) 0.245
\(-\) 0.294
\(-\) 0.212
\(-\) 0.441
\(-\) 0.279
\(-\) 0.463
(0.039)
(0.033)
(0.038)
(0.060)
(0.032)
(0.112)
Probability of imprisonment
\(-\) 0.011
\(-\) 0.022
\(-\) 0.015
\(-\) 0.006
\(-\) 0.019
\(-\) 0.175
(0.014)
(0.016)
(0.018)
(0.039)
(0.015)
(0.278)
Average sentence
0.006
0.012
\(-\) 0.036
\(-\) 0.020
\(-\) 0.015
0.171
(0.029)
(0.015)
(0.020)
(0.044)
(0.016)
(0.079)
Income
\(-\) 0.159
0.258
\(-\) 0.588
\(-\) 0.797
0.344
\(-\) 1.972
(0.074)
(0.108)
(0.103)
(0.199)
(0.107)
(1.838)
Unemployment
0.045
0.070
\(-\) 0.003
0.044
0.103
0.369
(0.048)
(0.049)
(0.050)
(0.092)
(0.042)
(1.394)
See Table 5
The pattern of the estimates corroborates the findings of Mustard (2003), i.e. omitting other relevant deterrence variables lowers the arrest rate elasticity considerably in all cases. As expected, the overidentification test statistic suggests that the moment conditions used in GMM estimation are invalidated.21 The omitted deterrence variables are serially correlated and also correlated with the regressors (see Table 4).
Imposing (weak) exogeneity of the arrest probability implies that one can also use alternative inference methods. In particular, the standard least squares dummy variables (LSDV) estimator becomes a meaningful choice when T is large enough, and so does the mean group (MG) estimator proposed by Pesaran and Smith (1995), which allows for slope parameter heterogeneity across different LGAs. Here, \(T=13\) is double digit; hence, we might apply such methods with some confidence. In addition to the aforementioned estimators, imposing weak exogeneity of the arrest probability implies that a seemingly unrelated regressions (SUR) estimator could also be a viable alternative, especially in situations where T is thought to be large enough. In the present case, SUR presents an alternative approach for estimating aggregated crime models since it effectively weighs observations according to their (co-)variance (see e.g. Cherry and List 2002).
Tables 111213 and 14 report results for the pooled OLS (POLS), LSDV, SUR and MG estimators, respectively. It is obvious that not accounting for region-specific effects (Table 11) leads to severe underestimation of the effect of the judicial system on crime, whereas the autoregressive coefficient is biased upwards, as expected. The estimated coefficients obtained from LSDV and MG (Tables 12 and 14) are quite similar to each other and are, overall, plausible in sign and magnitude. Since the pattern of the MG-based estimates is mostly in line with the LSDV estimates, this suggests that the assumption of common parameters across regions is not so restrictive in our sample. The estimated coefficients obtained from SUR for the aggregated crime categories are statistically similar to those obtained from GMM (see Tables 5 and 6), with the main exception perhaps being the coefficient of the lagged dependent variable for violent crime, which appears to be somewhat smaller. The standard errors for all three estimators suggest much higher precision relative to GMM.

5 Concluding remarks

We estimate an econometric model for crime using a new panel data set containing information on illegal activity and deterrence variables for local government areas in New South Wales, Australia. We take into account various endogeneity concerns expressed previously in the literature. Our findings suggest that the criminal justice system can potentially exert a large impact on crime.
Our results show that increasing the risk of apprehension and conviction exhibits a much larger effect in reducing crime compared to raising the expected severity of punishment. This may have significant policy implications. For example, if it were estimated that the cost of keeping a prisoner incarcerated for a year was roughly equivalent to the cost of making a single additional arrest, then one could justify a redirection of resources from prisons to policing. This implies that imprisoning more criminals, or imprisoning them for longer, is not optimal from a policy perspective, assuming that the cost involved behind these activities is of similar magnitude.
In our analysis, we address the impact of feedback between crime and deterrence, and it controls for measurement error and omitted variables. The resulting dynamic panel data model of crime is estimated by GMM. We show that the detrimental effects of measurement error and ratio bias are largely absent in our data. In general, we do not find overwhelming evidence for endogeneity of arrest rates. Furthermore, we show the necessity of including all relevant deterrence variables from the judiciary system to avoid underestimation of the effect of law enforcement policies.
Our conclusion that the deterrent effect of prison is rather limited will be regarded by some as controversial but it is entirely consistent with recent research on prison downsizing strategies that have been implemented over the last few years in the USA. For example, in the first year following the passage of California’s Public Safety Realignment Act in 2011 (an Act designed to reduce the California prison population), the State’s prison population fell by approximately 27,400, a roughly 17% decline on the population in 2010. With the exception of a slight and transient increase in auto-theft, studies have found little evidence that the reduction in prisoner numbers produced an increase in crime (Sundt et al. 2016; Lofstrom and Raphael 2016). The extensive literature on the specific deterrent effect of prison on re-offending also reveals largely negative findings (Nagin et al. 2009).
There are, nonetheless, several issues that remain to be explored. As Nagin (2013) points out, the conclusion that risk of apprehension exerts a more significant effect than punishment severity is largely derived from research examining the risk of apprehension by police. Little has been done to see whether the risk of conviction, given arrest, also has a deterrent effect or on punishment celerity—that is, the effect which sanction speed has on risk of re-offending (Chalfin and McCrary 2017). We know comparatively little about the kinds of police activities (and other forms of intervention) that exert the strongest influence on the perceived risk of apprehension. Finally, much work remains to be done in assessing the costs and benefits of various criminal justice options for reducing crime.
Open AccessThis article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Fußnoten
1
See Table 1 for a highly selective overview of crime studies.
 
2
For a recent overview on the dynamic panel data literature, see Bun (2015).
 
3
We are grateful to an anonymous referee for pointing this out.
 
4
This last observation is confirmed in our empirical analysis of Sect. 4, where we examine the case of measurement error in the arrest/conviction probability. We find little evidence for it.
 
5
The empirical crime literature is vast and extends over to several fields in social sciences, including economics, psychology, criminology, to mention a few. As such, it is impossible to pay justice to it. However, Table 1 does provide a good picture of the main methodological issues typically arising in crime analyses.
 
6
For panel data models, the cross-sectional dimension, N, is given first, followed by the time dimension, T.
 
7
Bun and Sarafidis (2015) shows that this is due to weak instruments for the Cornwell and Trumbull (1994) study.
 
8
That is, \(\ln prbarr_{it-2}\) (and further lags) satisfies in this case the two conditions required for validity of an instrument, namely, it remains correlated with \(\Delta \ln prbarr_{it}\) in (3) but it is uncorrelated with \(\Delta \varepsilon _{it}\).
 
9
We note that instruments are more likely to be valid in panel data settings compared to time series or cross-sectional regressions because the multi-dimensionality of panel data allows one to capture richer sources of unobserved heterogeneity relative to time series and cross-sectional data alone.
 
10
All GMM results have been obtained using David Roodman’s xtabond2 algorithm in Stata 15.
 
11
Each CD contains on average about 225 households (2001 Census). There are about 37,000 CDs throughout Australia. The boundaries of an SLA are designed to be typically coterminous with Local Government Areas unless the LGA does not fit entirely into a Statistical Subdivision, or is not of a comparative nature to other LGAs. There are 193 SLAs in NSW.
 
12
Courts in NSW enjoy considerable discretion as to the type of penalty and—where prison is concerned—the length of the prison term. Indeed, in most cases the only constraint is the statutory maximum penalty, which is usually well above the average sentence (see Weatherburn 1994). This implies some considerable variation in sentence length being exogenously driven, depending on individual characteristics of the judge.
 
13
The only offences examined here that are exclusively dealt with by a judge and jury are murder, sexual assault and robbery.
 
14
It is apparent that robbery is both a property and violent crime because it involves violence (or the threat of it) to unlawfully obtain property.
 
15
We are grateful to two anonymous referees for alerting us about this issue at first place.
 
16
On the computation of these scores, the interested reader may refer to Tables 6 and 2 of the aforementioned papers, respectively, as well as the associated discussion.
 
17
In terms of property crime, weights based on the within standard deviation of individual crime types are theft = 0.950;  robbery = 0.050, whereas weights based on the seriousness score are theft = 0.528;  robbery = 0.472.
In terms of violent crime, weights based on the within standard deviation of individual crime types are robbery = 0.272; assault = 0.718; homicide = 0.010, whereas weights based on the seriousness score are robbery = 0.099 ; assault = 0.387; homicide = 0.514.
 
18
We note that the results of the GMM estimated aggregate crime models are very similar irrespective of the method used to compute weights; see Tables 5 and 6. Therefore, unless otherwise stated, in what follows aggregate crime results correspond to variance weights computed based on the within standard deviation of individual crime types.
 
19
This is especially so for LGAs covering rural areas.
 
20
For a variable \(y_{it}\), the jth long difference is defined as \(y_{it}-y_{i,t-j}\).
 
21
Again, the only exceptions appear to be the robbery and homicide equations, which, however, are weakly identified as discussed previously.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Alvarez J, Arellano M (2003) The time series and cross-sectional asymptotics of dynamic panel data estimators. Econometrica 71:1121–1159 Alvarez J, Arellano M (2003) The time series and cross-sectional asymptotics of dynamic panel data estimators. Econometrica 71:1121–1159
Zurück zum Zitat Arellano M, Bond S (1991) Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Rev Econ Stud 58:277–298 Arellano M, Bond S (1991) Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Rev Econ Stud 58:277–298
Zurück zum Zitat Arellano M, Bover O (1995) Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components models. J Econom 68:29–51 Arellano M, Bover O (1995) Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components models. J Econom 68:29–51
Zurück zum Zitat Becker GS (1968) Crime and punishment: an economic approach. J Polit Econ 76(2):169–217 Becker GS (1968) Crime and punishment: an economic approach. J Polit Econ 76(2):169–217
Zurück zum Zitat Blumstein A (1974) Seriousness weights in an index of crime. Am Sociol Rev 39:854–864 Blumstein A (1974) Seriousness weights in an index of crime. Am Sociol Rev 39:854–864
Zurück zum Zitat Blumstein A, Cohen J, Nagin DS (eds) (1978) Deterrence and incapacitation-estimating the effect of criminal sanctions on crime rates. National Academies Press, Washington Blumstein A, Cohen J, Nagin DS (eds) (1978) Deterrence and incapacitation-estimating the effect of criminal sanctions on crime rates. National Academies Press, Washington
Zurück zum Zitat Blundell R, Bond S (1998) Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. J Econom 87(1):115–143 Blundell R, Bond S (1998) Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. J Econom 87(1):115–143
Zurück zum Zitat Bodman PM, Maultby C (1997) Crime, punishment and deterrence in Australia: a further empirical investigation. Int J Soc Econ 24:884–901 Bodman PM, Maultby C (1997) Crime, punishment and deterrence in Australia: a further empirical investigation. Int J Soc Econ 24:884–901
Zurück zum Zitat Bowsher CG (2002) On testing overidentifying restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Econ Lett 77:211–220 Bowsher CG (2002) On testing overidentifying restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Econ Lett 77:211–220
Zurück zum Zitat Bun MJG (2015) Identifying the impact of deterrence on crime: internal versus external instruments. Appl Econ Lett 22(3):204–208 Bun MJG (2015) Identifying the impact of deterrence on crime: internal versus external instruments. Appl Econ Lett 22(3):204–208
Zurück zum Zitat Bun MJG, Kiviet JF (2006) The effects of dynamic feedbacks on LS and MM estimator accuracy in panel data models. J Econom 132:409–444 Bun MJG, Kiviet JF (2006) The effects of dynamic feedbacks on LS and MM estimator accuracy in panel data models. J Econom 132:409–444
Zurück zum Zitat Bun MJG, Sarafidis V (2015) Chapter 3: The Oxford handbook of panel data. In: Baltagi B (ed) Dynamic panel data models. Oxford Bun MJG, Sarafidis V (2015) Chapter 3: The Oxford handbook of panel data. In: Baltagi B (ed) Dynamic panel data models. Oxford
Zurück zum Zitat Bun MJG, Sarafidis V (2015) Dynamic panel data models. In: Baltagi B (ed) The Oxford handbook of panel data. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 76–110 Bun MJG, Sarafidis V (2015) Dynamic panel data models. In: Baltagi B (ed) The Oxford handbook of panel data. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 76–110
Zurück zum Zitat Chalfin A, McCrary J (2017) Criminal deterrence: a review of the literature. J Econ Lit 55(1):5–48 Chalfin A, McCrary J (2017) Criminal deterrence: a review of the literature. J Econ Lit 55(1):5–48
Zurück zum Zitat Cherry TL, List JA (2002) Aggregation bias in the economic model of crime. Econ Lett 75:81–86 Cherry TL, List JA (2002) Aggregation bias in the economic model of crime. Econ Lett 75:81–86
Zurück zum Zitat Corman H, Mocan HN (2000) A time-series analysis of crime, deterrence, and drug abuse in New York city. Am Econ Rev 90(3):584–604 Corman H, Mocan HN (2000) A time-series analysis of crime, deterrence, and drug abuse in New York city. Am Econ Rev 90(3):584–604
Zurück zum Zitat Cornwell C, Trumbull WN (1994) Estimating the economic model of crime with panel data. Rev Econ Stat 76(2):360–366 Cornwell C, Trumbull WN (1994) Estimating the economic model of crime with panel data. Rev Econ Stat 76(2):360–366
Zurück zum Zitat Dills AK, Miron JA, Summers G (2008) What do economists know about crime? National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series, No. 13759 Dills AK, Miron JA, Summers G (2008) What do economists know about crime? National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series, No. 13759
Zurück zum Zitat Durlauf SN, Nagin DS (2011) The deterrent effect of imprisonment. In: Cook P, Ludwig J, McCrary J (eds) Controlling crime. University of Chicago Press, Chicago Durlauf SN, Nagin DS (2011) The deterrent effect of imprisonment. In: Cook P, Ludwig J, McCrary J (eds) Controlling crime. University of Chicago Press, Chicago
Zurück zum Zitat Ehrlich I (1973) Participation in illegitimate activities: a theoretical and empirical investigation. J Polit Econ 81(3):521–565 Ehrlich I (1973) Participation in illegitimate activities: a theoretical and empirical investigation. J Polit Econ 81(3):521–565
Zurück zum Zitat Ehrlich I (1975) The deterrent effect of capital punishment: a question of life and death. Am Econ Rev 65(3):397–417 Ehrlich I (1975) The deterrent effect of capital punishment: a question of life and death. Am Econ Rev 65(3):397–417
Zurück zum Zitat Entorf H, Spengler H (2008) Is being ’soft on crime’ the solution to rising crime rates? Evidence from Germany. IZA Discussion Paper No. 3710, Germany Entorf H, Spengler H (2008) Is being ’soft on crime’ the solution to rising crime rates? Evidence from Germany. IZA Discussion Paper No. 3710, Germany
Zurück zum Zitat Entorf H, Spengler H (2015) Crime, prosecutors, and the certainty of conviction. Eur J Law Econ 39:167–201 Entorf H, Spengler H (2015) Crime, prosecutors, and the certainty of conviction. Eur J Law Econ 39:167–201
Zurück zum Zitat Fajnzylber P, Lederman D, Loayza N (2002) Inequality and violent crime. J Law Econ 45(1):1–39 Fajnzylber P, Lederman D, Loayza N (2002) Inequality and violent crime. J Law Econ 45(1):1–39
Zurück zum Zitat Freeman RB (1999) The economics of crime. In: Ashenfelter OC, Card D (eds) Handbook of labor economics 3, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 3529–3571 Freeman RB (1999) The economics of crime. In: Ashenfelter OC, Card D (eds) Handbook of labor economics 3, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 3529–3571
Zurück zum Zitat Griliches Z, Hausman J (1986) Errors in variables in panel data. J Econom 31:93–118 Griliches Z, Hausman J (1986) Errors in variables in panel data. J Econom 31:93–118
Zurück zum Zitat Hansen LP (1982) Large sample properties of generalized methods of moments estimators. Econometrica 50(4):1029–1054 Hansen LP (1982) Large sample properties of generalized methods of moments estimators. Econometrica 50(4):1029–1054
Zurück zum Zitat Harris RDF, Tzavalis E (1999) Inference for unit roots in dynamic panels where the time dimension is fixed. J Econom 91:201–226 Harris RDF, Tzavalis E (1999) Inference for unit roots in dynamic panels where the time dimension is fixed. J Econom 91:201–226
Zurück zum Zitat Heller NB, McEwen JT (1973) Applications of crime seriousness information in police departments. J Crim Justice 1:241–253 Heller NB, McEwen JT (1973) Applications of crime seriousness information in police departments. J Crim Justice 1:241–253
Zurück zum Zitat Im KS, Pesaran MH, Shin Y (2003) Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels. J Econom 115:53–74 Im KS, Pesaran MH, Shin Y (2003) Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels. J Econom 115:53–74
Zurück zum Zitat Johnson R, Raphael S (2012) How much crime reduction does the marginal prisoner buy? J Law Econ 55(2):275–310 Johnson R, Raphael S (2012) How much crime reduction does the marginal prisoner buy? J Law Econ 55(2):275–310
Zurück zum Zitat Kleibergen F, Paap R (2006) Generalized reduced rank tests using the singular value decomposition. J Econom 133:97–126 Kleibergen F, Paap R (2006) Generalized reduced rank tests using the singular value decomposition. J Econom 133:97–126
Zurück zum Zitat Klick J, Tabarrok A (2005) Using terror alert levels to estimate the effect of police on crime. J Law Econ 48(1):267–279 Klick J, Tabarrok A (2005) Using terror alert levels to estimate the effect of police on crime. J Law Econ 48(1):267–279
Zurück zum Zitat Levitt SD (1996) The effect of prison population size on crime rates: evidence from prison overcrowding litigation. Q J Econ 111(2):319–351 Levitt SD (1996) The effect of prison population size on crime rates: evidence from prison overcrowding litigation. Q J Econ 111(2):319–351
Zurück zum Zitat Levitt SD (1997) Using electoral cycles in police hiring to estimate the effect of police on crime. Am Econ Rev 87(3):270–290 Levitt SD (1997) Using electoral cycles in police hiring to estimate the effect of police on crime. Am Econ Rev 87(3):270–290
Zurück zum Zitat Levitt SD (1998) Why do increased arrest rates appear to reduce crime: deterrence, incapacitation, or measurement error? Econ Inq 36:353–372 Levitt SD (1998) Why do increased arrest rates appear to reduce crime: deterrence, incapacitation, or measurement error? Econ Inq 36:353–372
Zurück zum Zitat Levitt SD (2002) Using electoral cycles in police hiring to estimate the effect of police on crime: reply. Am Econ Rev 92(4):1244–1250 Levitt SD (2002) Using electoral cycles in police hiring to estimate the effect of police on crime: reply. Am Econ Rev 92(4):1244–1250
Zurück zum Zitat Liedka RV, Piehl AM, Useem B (2006) The crime-control effect of incarceration: does scale matter? Criminol Public Policy 5(2):245–276 Liedka RV, Piehl AM, Useem B (2006) The crime-control effect of incarceration: does scale matter? Criminol Public Policy 5(2):245–276
Zurück zum Zitat Lofstrom M, Raphael S (2016) Prison downsizing and public safety: evidence from California. Criminol Public Policy 15(2):349–365 Lofstrom M, Raphael S (2016) Prison downsizing and public safety: evidence from California. Criminol Public Policy 15(2):349–365
Zurück zum Zitat Marvell T, Moody C (1994) Prison population growth and crime reduction. J Quant Criminol 10(2):109–140 Marvell T, Moody C (1994) Prison population growth and crime reduction. J Quant Criminol 10(2):109–140
Zurück zum Zitat Marvell TB, Moody CE (1996) Specification problems, police levels, and crime rates. Criminology 34(4):609–646 Marvell TB, Moody CE (1996) Specification problems, police levels, and crime rates. Criminology 34(4):609–646
Zurück zum Zitat Mustard DB (2003) Reexamining criminal behavior: the importance of omitted variable bias. Soc Sci Q 61(1):23–43 Mustard DB (2003) Reexamining criminal behavior: the importance of omitted variable bias. Soc Sci Q 61(1):23–43
Zurück zum Zitat Myers SL Jr (1980) Why are crimes underreported? What is the crime rate? Does it “really” matter? Rev Econ Stat 85(1):205–211 Myers SL Jr (1980) Why are crimes underreported? What is the crime rate? Does it “really” matter? Rev Econ Stat 85(1):205–211
Zurück zum Zitat Nagin DS (1978) General deterrence: a review of the empirical evidence. In: Blumstein A, Cohen J, Nagin DS (eds) On the feasibility of identifying the crime function in a simultaneous model of crime rates and sanction levels. National Academies Press, Washington Nagin DS (1978) General deterrence: a review of the empirical evidence. In: Blumstein A, Cohen J, Nagin DS (eds) On the feasibility of identifying the crime function in a simultaneous model of crime rates and sanction levels. National Academies Press, Washington
Zurück zum Zitat Nagin DS (2013) Deterrence in the twenty-first century. Crime Justice 42(1):199–263 Nagin DS (2013) Deterrence in the twenty-first century. Crime Justice 42(1):199–263
Zurück zum Zitat Nagin DS, Cullen FT, Jonson CL (2009) Imprisonment and reoffending. Crime Justice 38(1):115–200 Nagin DS, Cullen FT, Jonson CL (2009) Imprisonment and reoffending. Crime Justice 38(1):115–200
Zurück zum Zitat Pesaran MH, Smith RP (1995) Estimating long-run relationships from dynamic heterogeneous panels. J Econom 68:79–113 Pesaran MH, Smith RP (1995) Estimating long-run relationships from dynamic heterogeneous panels. J Econom 68:79–113
Zurück zum Zitat Pyle D (1984) Combating crime: do the police give value for money? Public Money 4(1):27–30 Pyle D (1984) Combating crime: do the police give value for money? Public Money 4(1):27–30
Zurück zum Zitat Raphael S, Stoll MA (2009) Why are so many Americans in prison? In: Raphael S, Stoll MA (eds) Do prisons make us safer? The benefits and costs of the prison boom. Russell Sage Foundation, New York Raphael S, Stoll MA (2009) Why are so many Americans in prison? In: Raphael S, Stoll MA (eds) Do prisons make us safer? The benefits and costs of the prison boom. Russell Sage Foundation, New York
Zurück zum Zitat Roodman D (2009) A note on the theme of too many instruments. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 71:135–158 Roodman D (2009) A note on the theme of too many instruments. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 71:135–158
Zurück zum Zitat Sampson RJ, Cohen J (1988) Deterrent effects of the police on crime: a replication and theoretical extension. Law Soc Rev 22(1):163–189 Sampson RJ, Cohen J (1988) Deterrent effects of the police on crime: a replication and theoretical extension. Law Soc Rev 22(1):163–189
Zurück zum Zitat Sjoquist DL (1973) Property crime and economic behavior: some empirical results. Am Econ Rev 63(3):439–446 Sjoquist DL (1973) Property crime and economic behavior: some empirical results. Am Econ Rev 63(3):439–446
Zurück zum Zitat Spelman W (2000) The limited importance of prison expansion. In: Blumstein A, Wallman J (eds) The crime drop in America. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 97–129 Spelman W (2000) The limited importance of prison expansion. In: Blumstein A, Wallman J (eds) The crime drop in America. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 97–129
Zurück zum Zitat Sundt J, Salisbury EJ, Harmon MG (2016) Is downsizing prisons dangerous? The effect of California’s realignment act on public safety. Criminol Public Policy 15(2):315–341 Sundt J, Salisbury EJ, Harmon MG (2016) Is downsizing prisons dangerous? The effect of California’s realignment act on public safety. Criminol Public Policy 15(2):315–341
Zurück zum Zitat Trumbull WN (1989) Estimations of the economic model of crime using aggregate and individual level data. South Econ J 56(2):423–439 Trumbull WN (1989) Estimations of the economic model of crime using aggregate and individual level data. South Econ J 56(2):423–439
Zurück zum Zitat Vold GB, Bernard TJ, Snipes JB (2002) Theoretical criminology, 5th edn. Oxford University Press, Oxford Vold GB, Bernard TJ, Snipes JB (2002) Theoretical criminology, 5th edn. Oxford University Press, Oxford
Zurück zum Zitat Walmsley R (2009) World prison population list. Technical report, King’s College London Walmsley R (2009) World prison population list. Technical report, King’s College London
Zurück zum Zitat Weatherburn D (2016) “Rack ‘em, pack ‘em and stack ‘em”: decarceration in an age of zero tolerance. Curr Issues Crim Justice 28(2):137–156 Weatherburn D (2016) “Rack ‘em, pack ‘em and stack ‘em”: decarceration in an age of zero tolerance. Curr Issues Crim Justice 28(2):137–156
Zurück zum Zitat Wilson J, Hernstein R (1985) Crime and human nature. Simon and Schuster, New York Wilson J, Hernstein R (1985) Crime and human nature. Simon and Schuster, New York
Zurück zum Zitat Windmeijer F (2005) A finite sample correction for the variance of linear efficient two step GMM estimators. J Econom 126:25–51 Windmeijer F (2005) A finite sample correction for the variance of linear efficient two step GMM estimators. J Econom 126:25–51
Zurück zum Zitat Withers G (1984) Crime, punishment and deterrence in Australia: an empirical investigation. Econ Rec 60(2):176–185 Withers G (1984) Crime, punishment and deterrence in Australia: an empirical investigation. Econ Rec 60(2):176–185
Zurück zum Zitat Witt R, Witte A (2000) Crime, prison, and female labor supply. J Quant Criminol 16(1):69–85 Witt R, Witte A (2000) Crime, prison, and female labor supply. J Quant Criminol 16(1):69–85
Zurück zum Zitat Wolpin KI (1978) An economic analysis of crime and punishment in England and Wales, 1894–1967. J Polit Econ 86(5):815–840 Wolpin KI (1978) An economic analysis of crime and punishment in England and Wales, 1894–1967. J Polit Econ 86(5):815–840
Zurück zum Zitat Wolpin KI (1980) A time series-cross section analysis of international variation in crime and punishment. Rev Econ Stat 62(3):417–423 Wolpin KI (1980) A time series-cross section analysis of international variation in crime and punishment. Rev Econ Stat 62(3):417–423
Zurück zum Zitat Ziliak JP (1997) Efficient estimation with panel data when instruments are predetermined: an empirical comparison of moment-condition estimators. J Bus Econ Stat 15:419–431 Ziliak JP (1997) Efficient estimation with panel data when instruments are predetermined: an empirical comparison of moment-condition estimators. J Bus Econ Stat 15:419–431
Zurück zum Zitat Zimring FE, Hawkins GJ (1973) Deterrence–the legal threat in crime control. University of Chicago Press, Chicago Zimring FE, Hawkins GJ (1973) Deterrence–the legal threat in crime control. University of Chicago Press, Chicago
Metadaten
Titel
Crime, deterrence and punishment revisited
verfasst von
Maurice J. G. Bun
Richard Kelaher
Vasilis Sarafidis
Don Weatherburn
Publikationsdatum
10.09.2019
Verlag
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Erschienen in
Empirical Economics / Ausgabe 5/2020
Print ISSN: 0377-7332
Elektronische ISSN: 1435-8921
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-019-01758-6

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 5/2020

Empirical Economics 5/2020 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner