Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Dynamic Games and Applications 4/2019

01.01.2019

Growth and Insecure Private Property of Capital

verfasst von: Bertrand Crettez, Naila Hayek, Lisa Morhaim

Erschienen in: Dynamic Games and Applications | Ausgabe 4/2019

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This paper revisits Strulik’s model of growth with insecure property rights. In this model, different social groups devote some effort to control a share of the capital stock. We show that a slight variation in the modeling of strategic interactions results in the coexistence of savings and efforts to control a share of the capital stock. We also study the effects of a change in the number of social groups on growth. We also show that an increase in social fractionalization may lead to less effort devoted to control capital and to a higher growth rate.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 390 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe




 

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
In the literature on the depletion of common resources, it is possible to accumulate some privately and safely held capital, but there is no costly competition to access the resources.
 
2
They also write that: “ethnicity is possibly a marker for organizing similar individuals along opposing lines.”
 
3
We do not focus on perpetual growth. We could obtain endogenous growth by assuming a Romer [13] like technology.
 
4
Strulik shows that conflict and growth can coexist in an economy populated by two groups of unequal sizes. Here, we do not need to assume a difference in size to obtain the coexistence result.
 
5
Physical feasibility implies that \(\sum _{i=1}^{n} \phi (\tau ^i_{t}, \varvec{\tau }^{-i}_{t}) = 1\).
 
6
We thank a referee for noticing that Strulik’s production function, namely \(f(k,l) = kl\), is not a special case of our production function when \(\alpha = 1\). To obtain Strulik’s specification from a Cobb–Douglas function, we could set: \(y_t = (A_t k_t)^{\alpha }(B_t l_t)^{1-\alpha }\) where, following Frankel [5] and Romer [13], \(A_t = l_t\), and \(B_t = k_t\). Generally, it is assumed that the decision maker is unaware of the specifications of \(A_{t}\) and \(B_{t}\), except if he is a social planner. That a social group behaves as a social planner is not strictly impossible, but this is probably a strong assumption.
 
7
In “Appendix A,” we show that under our specific assumptions the values of the agents’ objectives involved in the feedback Nash are always well defined.
 
8
That the objective is well defined is established in Appendix.
 
10
The data are available in Feenstra et al. [4] available for download at www.​ggdc.​net/​pwt The capital stock is evaluated at constant 2011 national prices (in mil. 2011 US$).
 
11
Recall that Strulik uses a continuous time setting. We translate his modeling assumptions in a discrete time setting.
 
12
The crucial hypothesis in this theorem is an invertibility condition which is satisfied in our case since \((1-\delta )+\sum _{j=1}^{n} f_1^j \frac{g(\tau ^j_{t})}{\sum _{h=1}^{n} g(\tau ^h_{t})} \ne 0\). Moreover, it is clear that the multiplier \(\lambda _0 \) in the cited Theorem 2.2 is different from zero in our case, so we have set it equal to one.
 
13
In the following expression, \(f^j_{1}\) stands for \(f'_{1}\left( \frac{ g(\tau ^j_{t}) }{ \left( \sum _{h=1}^{n} g(\tau ^h_{t}) \right) } k_{t}, 1-\tau ^j_{t} \right) \).
 
14
The fractionalization index gives the probability that two people drawn at random from the society will belong to different groups [3]. That is, if \(n_{i}\) is the population share of group i, the fractionalization index is \( \sum _{i=1}^{m} n_i (1-n_i)\). Another measure of social fragmentation is the polarization index P introduced by Esteban and Ray [7], where \(P = \sum _{i=1}^m \sum _{j=1}^m n_i^2 n_j d_{ij}\), with \(d_{ij}\) being the intergroup perceived distance. The R index is a special case of the P index where \(d_{ij} = 1\) when \(i \not = j\) [9]. Theses indexes are briefly discussed in Ray and Esteban [12], Sect. 5.1. In our symmetric society, the fractionalization and the R indexes have the same value.
 
15
Moreover, recall that our setting slightly differs from Strulik’s: we use a Cobb–Douglas function, whereas Strulik uses the production function \(A k_{i} (1-\tau ^{i})\), and we consider a general g(.) function, whereas Strulik concentrates on the case \(g(\tau ) = \alpha +\tau \) (Strulik, ibid, page footnote 3, however, indicates that most of his results can be obtained with more general contest success functions).
 
16
Our analysis has been cast in a neo-classical setting preventing perpetual growth. But we can recover our results (regarding predation time and savings) in a perpetual growth setting by assuming that \(y_t = (k_t)^{\alpha }(B_t l_t)^{1-\alpha }\) and that each social group takes \(B_t = k_{t}\) as given. Everything would be as if \(y_t = C_t k_t^{\alpha }l_t^{1-\alpha }\) (with \(C_t \equiv k_t^{1- \alpha }\)). In particular, the predation game would remain unchanged. Only the savings game would be different (although we could use the same methods to find the equilibrium savings). People would still save a part of individual production, but in equilibrium, production would be a linear function of capital.
 
17
In this vein, Vahabi [18, 19] considers that this quality is linked to the characteristics of the goods.
 
Literatur
1.
Zurück zum Zitat Benhabib J, Rustichini A (1996) Social conflict and growth. J Econ Growth 1:125–142CrossRef Benhabib J, Rustichini A (1996) Social conflict and growth. J Econ Growth 1:125–142CrossRef
2.
Zurück zum Zitat Blot J, Hayek N (2014) Infinite-horizon optimal control in the discrete-time framework. Springer, New YorkCrossRef Blot J, Hayek N (2014) Infinite-horizon optimal control in the discrete-time framework. Springer, New YorkCrossRef
3.
Zurück zum Zitat Bruk SI, Apenchenko VS (eds) (1964) Atlas narodov mira. Academy of Science, Moscow Bruk SI, Apenchenko VS (eds) (1964) Atlas narodov mira. Academy of Science, Moscow
4.
Zurück zum Zitat Feenstra RC, Inklaar R, Timmer MP (2015) The next generation of the Penn world Table. Am Econ Rev 105(10):3150–3182CrossRef Feenstra RC, Inklaar R, Timmer MP (2015) The next generation of the Penn world Table. Am Econ Rev 105(10):3150–3182CrossRef
5.
Zurück zum Zitat Frankel M (1962) The production function in allocation and growth: a synthesis. Am Econ Rev 55(3):296–319 Frankel M (1962) The production function in allocation and growth: a synthesis. Am Econ Rev 55(3):296–319
6.
Zurück zum Zitat Gonzales FM (2012) The use of coercion in society: insecure property rights, conflicts and economic backwardess. In: Garfinkel MR, Skaperdas S (eds) Oxford handbook of the economics of peace and conflict Gonzales FM (2012) The use of coercion in society: insecure property rights, conflicts and economic backwardess. In: Garfinkel MR, Skaperdas S (eds) Oxford handbook of the economics of peace and conflict
7.
Zurück zum Zitat Joan E, Debraj R (1994) On the measurement of polarization. Econometrica 62:819–52CrossRef Joan E, Debraj R (1994) On the measurement of polarization. Econometrica 62:819–52CrossRef
8.
Zurück zum Zitat Lindner I, Strulik H (2008) Social fractionalization, endogenous predation norms, and economic development. Economica 75(298):244–58CrossRef Lindner I, Strulik H (2008) Social fractionalization, endogenous predation norms, and economic development. Economica 75(298):244–58CrossRef
9.
Zurück zum Zitat Montalvo JG, Reynal-Querol M (2005) Ethnic polarization, potential conflict and civil war. Am Econ Rev 95:796–816CrossRef Montalvo JG, Reynal-Querol M (2005) Ethnic polarization, potential conflict and civil war. Am Econ Rev 95:796–816CrossRef
10.
Zurück zum Zitat Ogilvie S, Carus AW (2014) Institutions and economic growth in historical perspective. In: Aghion P, Durlauf S (eds) Handbook of economic growth, vol 2A, Chapter 8. Elsevie, Amsterdam, pp 403–513 Ogilvie S, Carus AW (2014) Institutions and economic growth in historical perspective. In: Aghion P, Durlauf S (eds) Handbook of economic growth, vol 2A, Chapter 8. Elsevie, Amsterdam, pp 403–513
11.
Zurück zum Zitat Polachnek S, Sevastionava D (2012) Does conflict disrupt growth? Evidence of the relationship between political instability and national economic performance. J Int Trade Econ Dev Int Comp Rev 21(3):361–388CrossRef Polachnek S, Sevastionava D (2012) Does conflict disrupt growth? Evidence of the relationship between political instability and national economic performance. J Int Trade Econ Dev Int Comp Rev 21(3):361–388CrossRef
12.
Zurück zum Zitat Ray D, Esteban J (2017) Conflict and development. Ann Rev Econ 9:263–93CrossRef Ray D, Esteban J (2017) Conflict and development. Ann Rev Econ 9:263–93CrossRef
13.
Zurück zum Zitat Romer P (1986) Increasing returns and long-run growth. J Political Econ 94(5):1002–1037CrossRef Romer P (1986) Increasing returns and long-run growth. J Political Econ 94(5):1002–1037CrossRef
14.
Zurück zum Zitat Rouillon S (2017) Cooperative and noncooperative extraction in a common pool with habit formation. Dyn Games Appl 7(3):468-49MathSciNetCrossRef Rouillon S (2017) Cooperative and noncooperative extraction in a common pool with habit formation. Dyn Games Appl 7(3):468-49MathSciNetCrossRef
15.
Zurück zum Zitat Stokey NL, Lucas RE, Prescott EC (1989) Recursive methods in economic dynamics. Harvard University Press, CambridgeCrossRef Stokey NL, Lucas RE, Prescott EC (1989) Recursive methods in economic dynamics. Harvard University Press, CambridgeCrossRef
16.
Zurück zum Zitat Strulik H (2008) Social composition, social conflict and economic development. Econ J 118:1145–1170CrossRef Strulik H (2008) Social composition, social conflict and economic development. Econ J 118:1145–1170CrossRef
17.
Zurück zum Zitat Tornell A, Lane PR (1999) The voracity effect. Am Econ Rev 89:22–46CrossRef Tornell A, Lane PR (1999) The voracity effect. Am Econ Rev 89:22–46CrossRef
18.
Zurück zum Zitat Vahabi M (2015) The political economy of predation: manhunting and the economics of escape. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge Vahabi M (2015) The political economy of predation: manhunting and the economics of escape. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
19.
Zurück zum Zitat Vahabi M (2016) A positive theory of the predatory state. Publ Choice 168(3–4):153–175CrossRef Vahabi M (2016) A positive theory of the predatory state. Publ Choice 168(3–4):153–175CrossRef
20.
Zurück zum Zitat Van Long N (2010) A survey of dynamic games in economics. World Scientific, SingaporeCrossRef Van Long N (2010) A survey of dynamic games in economics. World Scientific, SingaporeCrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Growth and Insecure Private Property of Capital
verfasst von
Bertrand Crettez
Naila Hayek
Lisa Morhaim
Publikationsdatum
01.01.2019
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Dynamic Games and Applications / Ausgabe 4/2019
Print ISSN: 2153-0785
Elektronische ISSN: 2153-0793
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s13235-018-00294-9

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 4/2019

Dynamic Games and Applications 4/2019 Zur Ausgabe