Skip to main content
Erschienen in:
Buchtitelbild

2022 | OriginalPaper | Buchkapitel

1. Introduction

verfasst von : Alfonso Novales, Esther Fernández, Jesús Ruiz

Erschienen in: Economic Growth

Verlag: Springer Berlin Heidelberg

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Through the different chapters of the book, we will be presenting exogenous and endogenous, non-monetary and monetary growth models, discussing their main properties and learning how to obtain numerical solutions to them. Solutions take the form of a set of time series for the main variables in the model. Numerical solutions allow us to estimate the effects of alternative policies. After a review of some time series issues, we review in this chapter standard stochastic, dynamic structural models, as an introduction to model simulation. We then explain why economic growth models are very relevant to the analysis of policy questions. The chapter closes with an introduction to numerical solution methods.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 390 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe




 

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
That amounts to constructing the forecast by application of the conditional expectation operator to the analytical representation of the future value being predicted, where the conditional expectation is formed with respect to the sigma algebra of events known at time t.
 
2
This is the limit of a random variable, and an appropriate limit concept must be used. It suffices to say that the power of ρ going to zero justifies the zero limit for the product random variable.
 
3
That is, if the innovation ε t has zero variance.
 
4
When working with several variables, responses can be obtained for impulses in more than one variable. To make the size of the responses comparable, each innovation is supposed to take a value equal to its standard deviation, which may be quite different for different innovations.
 
5
Or significantly increasing the innovation variance. What are the differences between both cases in terms of the values taken by the process?
 
6
The two polynomials can be written as 1 − a 1 B − a 2 B 2 = (1 − B)(1 − λB), the second root being 1∕λ. The reader just needs to find the value of λ in each case.
 
7
We could have done otherwise, like starting the first order autoregressions at their mathematical expectation, and the second order autoregressions outside their expected values. The reader can experiment with these changes.
 
8
As it would be obtained by a profit maximizing competitive firm with a Cobb–Douglas technology, \(Y=a_{0}K^{a_{1}}L^{a_{2}},a_{1}+a_{2}\leq 1,\) represented in logs by the first relationship, with \(d_{0}=\ln (a_{0}a_{1}).\)
 
9
A system with as many equations as endogenous variables.
 
10
We assume here, for simplicity, that all random shocks are white noise. Extending the model to incorporate possible autoregressive structures for the shocks is straightforward.
 
11
If we denote by p i the i-th row of the s × q matrix P, then \( {\textit {Var}}(z_{i})=p_{i}^{\prime }\varSigma _{\varepsilon }p_{i},\) \({\textit {Var}}(z_{j})=p_{j}^{ \prime }\varSigma _{\varepsilon }p_{j},\) \({\textit {Cov}}(z_{i},z_{j})=p_{i}^{\prime }\varSigma _{\varepsilon }p_{j},\) and \({\textit {Corr}}(z_{i},z_{j})=\frac {p_{i}^{\prime }\varSigma _{\varepsilon }p_{j}}{\sqrt {p_{i}^{\prime }\varSigma _{\varepsilon }p_{i}}\sqrt {p_{j}^{\prime }\varSigma _{\varepsilon }p_{j}}},\) with Σ ε being the q × q variance–covariance matrix of vector ε.
 
12
If, for instance, C t, C t−1, and C t−2 appear in the model, both, C t and C t−1, will form part of vector z t, while C t−1 and C t−2 will be included in vector z t−1. The representation could also be extended easily to accommodate lagged innovation values.
 
13
Such equation is λ 2 − (a 2 + β 2)λ + β 2 = 0.
 
14
Which is known as Cholesky identification strategy, from the way how a factor decomposition of the variance–covariance matrix of the original innovations is used to produce the linear transformation of the system of equations.
 
15
Alternatively, we could have considered a process with some inertia for Government expenditures or even change the model to make the value of Government expenditures to be related to the past level of output, for instance.
 
16
The choice of the steady-state level as initial condition is arbitrary. However, in this stochastic version of the model that choice is as good as any other, since the economy is already going to experience fluctuations due to the stochastic component of government expenditures.
 
17
Notice the difference between computing relative volatility by the ratios of standard deviations and through the ratios of the coefficients of variation, the latter option being preferable.
 
18
The autocorrelation function is the sequence of values Corr(Y t, Y ts), for all s.
 
19
This suggests no evidence of residual autocorrelation, a potential source of misspecification in the consumption equation.
 
20
This is arbitrary. We should take an impulse of size equal to one standard deviation of the innovations estimated from actual time series data, since that is the likely single period fluctuation in each variable.
 
21
This is, in fact, very important, since the structure and implications of a model may significantly change by just a change in assumptions on the timing of decisions, the arrival of information, or the opening and closing of markets.
 
22
This modelling approach is now commonplace in macroeconomics. Dynamic models with microeconomic foundations for aggregate economies are often used in Public Finance, Monetary Theory, Labour Economics, or International Economics, as they are used in Growth Theory. The main difference for the latter is their focus on characterizing the main determinants of short- and long-run growth.
 
23
A standard result in intermediate microeconomics courses.
 
24
Of course, different utility functions could give raise to different functional forms for the way how current consumption relates to future consumption and interest rates.
 
25
With δ being the percent per-period depreciation rate of capital.
 
26
In consistency with the utility maximization problem above, we can either assume that there is a single consumer or household in the economy or interpret labor and capital stock in this equation in per-capita terms.
 
27
And also on conditional expectations of nonlinear functions of future state and decision variables, in the case of stochastic growth models, as we will see in the next paragraph.
 
28
Under endogenous prices, optimization problems solved by economic agents do not have a linear-quadratic structure, implying that their decision rules are nonlinear. Since these decisions are part of the system summarizing the model, that system ends up being nonlinear as well.
Sargent’s Macroeconomic Theory [34] contains a variety of partial equilibrium models in which, with exogenous prices, optimization problems have a linear-quadratic structure. In that simple setup, decision rules are linear functions.
 
29
Expectations of future variables or functions of variables appearing in a model need to be treated as new variables, so that a model that includes an explicit role for expectations is not complete without incorporating some kind of assumption on the way agents form their expectations. The assumptions on the expectations formation mechanism play the role of additional equations. They are a crucial part of a stochastic model, as important as the assumptions on the functional form of the utility function or the aggregate production function, and affect the model implications regarding the time behavior for the endogenous variables.
 
30
These expectation mechanisms are said to be backward-looking, since they are substituted by a function of past variables, agents’ views about the future not playing any role.
 
31
Alternative specifications for limited rationality, in which agents are assumed to form expectations that are partially rational, have been shown to be useful to explain some regularities in actual time series data.
 
32
Significant progress has already been done in dealing with agents’ heterogeneity [11, 31], although the representative agent framework is still predominant.
 
33
This summary is intended to provide an overview to readers unfamiliar with Growth Theory. We do not have any pretension of being fully comprehensive.
 
34
As mentioned, the model also had implications regarding the convergence of economies in terms of per-capita income, which developed a huge empirical literature aiming to test such implications that are still very much alive, now in reference to more sophisticated growth models that have been developed since then. Along this line of reasoning, Growth Theory would not be very different from other areas of economic theory that imply more or less tight restrictions among the joint behavior of variables, which can be reduced to parameter testing in relatively simple econometric models.
 
35
Kydland and Prescott [24] point out: “In other words, modern business cycle models are stochastic versions of neoclassical Growth Theory. And the fact that business cycle models do produce normal-looking fluctuations adds dramatically to our confidence in the neoclassical Growth Theory model—including the answers it provides to growth accounting and public finance questions.”
 
36
In any event, like in any other growth model, the relationships among per- capita variables emerging from the model will generally be nonlinear, and a linear econometric model might be too poor an approximation to them.
 
37
Constant returns to scale in the single cumulative input as a reason for positive long-term growth is the characteristic of the AK economy, introduced by Rebelo [30]. An explicit role for public capital as a productive input was proposed by Barro [2]. The model with a variety of intermediate goods is due to Spence [40], Dixit and Stiglitz [15], Ethier [17] and Romer [32, 33]. Uzawa [43], Lucas [26], and Caball é and Santos [6] assigned an explicit role to the stock of human capital in the production of the final good.
 
40
For a discussion of analytical solution methods for linear rational expectations models, see Whiteman [45].
 
41
We do not pretend these methods to be superior in any sense to those not covered in the chapter. They have been chosen because of their relative simplicity. An introduction to more complex, but possibly more exact methods, is also provided in that chapter.
 
42
Unless we work under the assumption of rational expectations, the model’s implications regarding the way agents’ expectations relate to state variables are generally hard to derive.
 
43
What is called a bubble equilibrium.
 
44
Welfare should be understood as the discounted time aggregate value of current and future utility. We are thinking here about a set of identical consumers, who live together forever, a usual assumption in growth models.
 
45
However, the appropriate approach to use frequency distributions from the alternative models to evaluate in probability terms (or in likelihood terms) their ability to fit the data is still very much open to discussion. And so it is the selection of statistics whose value in actual data should be replicated by the theoretical models considered.
 
46
Exogenous shocks could be modelled as shocks in productivity, as it is done often throughout the book.
 
47
Alternatively, we could consider the possibility of maintaining tax rates unchanged and finance the fluctuations in expenditures by debt management or money injections. Appropriate conditions guaranteeing long-run solvency would then have to be imposed, as it is discussed at different points in this textbook.
 
48
Of course, the type of results reached by Poole [28] in a static setup that “in the presence of supply shocks it is better to implement a monetary policy aimed to maintaining a given growth rate of money, while leaving interest rates to be determined in the market, the opposite being true if randomness enters mainly through the demand side” is another result typical from the type of analysis described in these sections.
 
49
And hence, in which per-capita variables display zero growth.
 
50
Macroeconometrics textbooks include some of these methods. As examples, see Canova [9] or De Jong and Dave [14].
 
51
Impulse responses and variance decompositions are statistics computed from vector autoregressive models. We will show how to compute them in actual and in simulated data, providing MATLAB programs to do so.
 
Literatur
1.
Zurück zum Zitat Aghion, P., & Howitt, P. (1992). A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica, 80(2), 323–351.CrossRef Aghion, P., & Howitt, P. (1992). A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica, 80(2), 323–351.CrossRef
2.
Zurück zum Zitat Barro, R. J. (1990). Government spending in a simple model of endogenous growth. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), S103–S126.CrossRef Barro, R. J. (1990). Government spending in a simple model of endogenous growth. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), S103–S126.CrossRef
3.
Zurück zum Zitat Barro, R. J., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (1997). Technological diffusion, convergence, and growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 2(1), 1–26.CrossRef Barro, R. J., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (1997). Technological diffusion, convergence, and growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 2(1), 1–26.CrossRef
4.
Zurück zum Zitat Bayoumi, T., Laxton, D., & Pesenti, P. (2004). Benefits and spillovers of greater competition in Europe: A macroeconomic assessment. ECB Working Paper, No. 341, European Central Bank. Bayoumi, T., Laxton, D., & Pesenti, P. (2004). Benefits and spillovers of greater competition in Europe: A macroeconomic assessment. ECB Working Paper, No. 341, European Central Bank.
5.
Zurück zum Zitat Blanchard, O., & Kahn, C. M. (1980). The solution of linear difference models under rational expectations. Econometrica, 48(5), 1305–1311.CrossRef Blanchard, O., & Kahn, C. M. (1980). The solution of linear difference models under rational expectations. Econometrica, 48(5), 1305–1311.CrossRef
6.
Zurück zum Zitat Caballe, J., & Santos, M. (1993). On endogenous growth with physical and human capital. Journal of Political Economy, 101, 1042–1067.CrossRef Caballe, J., & Santos, M. (1993). On endogenous growth with physical and human capital. Journal of Political Economy, 101, 1042–1067.CrossRef
7.
Zurück zum Zitat Cagan, P. (1956). The monetary dynamics of hyperinflation. In M. Friedman (Ed.) Studies in the quantity theory of money (pp. 25–117). Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Cagan, P. (1956). The monetary dynamics of hyperinflation. In M. Friedman (Ed.) Studies in the quantity theory of money (pp. 25–117). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
8.
Zurück zum Zitat Calvo, G. (1983). Staggered prices in a utility maximizing framework. Journal of Monetary Economics, 12, 383–398.CrossRef Calvo, G. (1983). Staggered prices in a utility maximizing framework. Journal of Monetary Economics, 12, 383–398.CrossRef
9.
Zurück zum Zitat Canova, F. (2007). Methods for applied macroeconomic research. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRef Canova, F. (2007). Methods for applied macroeconomic research. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRef
10.
Zurück zum Zitat Cass, D. (1965). Optimum growth in an aggregative model of capital accumulation. Review of Economic Studies, 32, 233–240.CrossRef Cass, D. (1965). Optimum growth in an aggregative model of capital accumulation. Review of Economic Studies, 32, 233–240.CrossRef
11.
Zurück zum Zitat Castañeda, A., Diaz-Gimenez, & J., Rios-Rull, J. V. (1998). Exploring the income distribution business cycle dynamics. Journal of Monetary Economics, 42, 93–130. Castañeda, A., Diaz-Gimenez, & J., Rios-Rull, J. V. (1998). Exploring the income distribution business cycle dynamics. Journal of Monetary Economics, 42, 93–130.
12.
Zurück zum Zitat Coenen, G., & Wieland, V. (2000). A small estimated euro area model with rational expectations and nominal rigidities. European Economic Review, 49, 1081–1104.CrossRef Coenen, G., & Wieland, V. (2000). A small estimated euro area model with rational expectations and nominal rigidities. European Economic Review, 49, 1081–1104.CrossRef
13.
Zurück zum Zitat Coenen, G., McAdam, P., & Straub, R. (2008). Tax reform and labor-market performance in the Euro area: A simulation-based analysis using the new area-wide model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 32(8), 2543–2583.CrossRef Coenen, G., McAdam, P., & Straub, R. (2008). Tax reform and labor-market performance in the Euro area: A simulation-based analysis using the new area-wide model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 32(8), 2543–2583.CrossRef
14.
Zurück zum Zitat De Jong, D. N., & Dave, C. (2007). Structural macroeconometrics. Princeton: Princeton University Press. De Jong, D. N., & Dave, C. (2007). Structural macroeconometrics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
15.
Zurück zum Zitat Dixit, A. K., & Stiglitz, J. (1977). Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity. American Economic Review, 67, 297–308. Dixit, A. K., & Stiglitz, J. (1977). Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity. American Economic Review, 67, 297–308.
16.
Zurück zum Zitat Erceg, C. J., Guerrieri, L., & Gust, C. (2005). SIGMA: A new open economy model for policy analysis. International Finance Discussion Papers No. 835. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, July. Erceg, C. J., Guerrieri, L., & Gust, C. (2005). SIGMA: A new open economy model for policy analysis. International Finance Discussion Papers No. 835. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, July.
17.
Zurück zum Zitat Ethier, W. J. (1982). National and international returns to scale in the modern theory of international trade. American Economic Review, 72, 389–405. Ethier, W. J. (1982). National and international returns to scale in the modern theory of international trade. American Economic Review, 72, 389–405.
18.
Zurück zum Zitat Gali, J., & Gertler, M. (1999). Inflation dynamics: A structural econometric analysis. Journal of Monetary Economics, 44(2), 195–222.CrossRef Gali, J., & Gertler, M. (1999). Inflation dynamics: A structural econometric analysis. Journal of Monetary Economics, 44(2), 195–222.CrossRef
19.
Zurück zum Zitat Hansen, L. P. (1982). Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators. Econometrica, 50(4), 1029–1054.CrossRef Hansen, L. P. (1982). Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators. Econometrica, 50(4), 1029–1054.CrossRef
20.
Zurück zum Zitat Howitt, P., & Aghion, P. (1998). Capital accumulation and innovation as complementary factors in long-run growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 3, 111–130.CrossRef Howitt, P., & Aghion, P. (1998). Capital accumulation and innovation as complementary factors in long-run growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 3, 111–130.CrossRef
21.
Zurück zum Zitat Jones, L. E., & Manuelli, R., (1990). A convex model of economic growth. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), 1008–1038.CrossRef Jones, L. E., & Manuelli, R., (1990). A convex model of economic growth. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), 1008–1038.CrossRef
22.
Zurück zum Zitat King, R. G., Plosser, C. I., & Rebelo, S. (1988). Production, growth, and business cycles: II. New directions. Journal of Monetary Economics, 21, 309–341.CrossRef King, R. G., Plosser, C. I., & Rebelo, S. (1988). Production, growth, and business cycles: II. New directions. Journal of Monetary Economics, 21, 309–341.CrossRef
23.
Zurück zum Zitat Koopmans, T. C. (1965). On the concept of optimal economic growth. In The economic approach to development planning. North-Holland: Amsterdam. Koopmans, T. C. (1965). On the concept of optimal economic growth. In The economic approach to development planning. North-Holland: Amsterdam.
24.
Zurück zum Zitat Kydland, F. E., & Prescott, E. C. (1996). The computational experiment: An econometric tool. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10(1), 69–85.CrossRef Kydland, F. E., & Prescott, E. C. (1996). The computational experiment: An econometric tool. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10(1), 69–85.CrossRef
25.
Zurück zum Zitat Lucas, R. E. (1976). Econometric policy evaluation: A critique. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy. Lucas, R. E. (1976). Econometric policy evaluation: A critique. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy.
26.
Zurück zum Zitat Lucas, R. E. (1988). On the mechanism of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 122, 3–42.CrossRef Lucas, R. E. (1988). On the mechanism of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 122, 3–42.CrossRef
27.
Zurück zum Zitat Marcet, A., & den Haan, W. J. (1990). Solving nonlinear stochastic models by parameterizing expectations. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 8, 31–34. Marcet, A., & den Haan, W. J. (1990). Solving nonlinear stochastic models by parameterizing expectations. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 8, 31–34.
28.
Zurück zum Zitat Poole, W. (1970). Optimal choice of monetary policy instruments in a simple stochastic macro model. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84(2), 197–216.CrossRef Poole, W. (1970). Optimal choice of monetary policy instruments in a simple stochastic macro model. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84(2), 197–216.CrossRef
29.
Zurück zum Zitat Ramsey, F. (1928). A mathematical theory of saving. Economic Journal, 38, 543–559.CrossRef Ramsey, F. (1928). A mathematical theory of saving. Economic Journal, 38, 543–559.CrossRef
30.
Zurück zum Zitat Rebelo, S. (1991). Long-run policy analysis and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy, 99(3), 500–521.CrossRef Rebelo, S. (1991). Long-run policy analysis and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy, 99(3), 500–521.CrossRef
31.
Zurück zum Zitat Rios-Rull, J. V. (1996). Life-cycle economies and aggregate fluctuations. Review of Economic Studies, 63, 465–490.CrossRef Rios-Rull, J. V. (1996). Life-cycle economies and aggregate fluctuations. Review of Economic Studies, 63, 465–490.CrossRef
32.
Zurück zum Zitat Romer, P. M. (1987). Growth based on increasing returns due to specialization. American Economic Review, 77(2), 56–62. Romer, P. M. (1987). Growth based on increasing returns due to specialization. American Economic Review, 77(2), 56–62.
33.
Zurück zum Zitat Romer, P. M. (1990). Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy Part II, 98(5), S71–S102.CrossRef Romer, P. M. (1990). Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy Part II, 98(5), S71–S102.CrossRef
34.
Zurück zum Zitat Sargent, T. J. (1979). Macroeconomic Theory. New York: Academic Press. Sargent, T. J. (1979). Macroeconomic Theory. New York: Academic Press.
35.
Zurück zum Zitat Schumpeter, J. A. (1934). The theory of economic development. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Schumpeter, J. A. (1934). The theory of economic development. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
36.
Zurück zum Zitat Sidrauski, M. (1967). Rational choice and patterns of growth in a monetary economy. American Economic Revenue, 57(2), 534–544. Sidrauski, M. (1967). Rational choice and patterns of growth in a monetary economy. American Economic Revenue, 57(2), 534–544.
37.
Zurück zum Zitat Sims, C. A. (2001). Solving linear rational expectations models. Journal of Computational Economics, 20, 1–20.CrossRef Sims, C. A. (2001). Solving linear rational expectations models. Journal of Computational Economics, 20, 1–20.CrossRef
38.
Zurück zum Zitat Smets, F., Christoffel, K., Coenen, G., Motto, R., & Rostagno, M. (2010). Models and their uses. SERIEs, 1, 51–61.CrossRef Smets, F., Christoffel, K., Coenen, G., Motto, R., & Rostagno, M. (2010). Models and their uses. SERIEs, 1, 51–61.CrossRef
39.
Zurück zum Zitat Solow, R. M. (1956). A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70(1), 65–94.CrossRef Solow, R. M. (1956). A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70(1), 65–94.CrossRef
40.
Zurück zum Zitat Spence, M. (1976). Product selection, fixed costs, and monopolistic competition. Review of Economic Studies, 43(2): 217–235.CrossRef Spence, M. (1976). Product selection, fixed costs, and monopolistic competition. Review of Economic Studies, 43(2): 217–235.CrossRef
41.
Zurück zum Zitat Swan, T. W. (1956). Economic growth and capital accumulation. Economic Record, 32, 334–361.CrossRef Swan, T. W. (1956). Economic growth and capital accumulation. Economic Record, 32, 334–361.CrossRef
42.
Zurück zum Zitat Uhlig, H. (1999). A toolkit for analyzing nonlinear dynamic stochastic models easily. In R. Marimon & A. Scott (Eds.) Computational methods for the study of dynamic economics (pp. 30–61). Oxford: Oxford University Press. Uhlig, H. (1999). A toolkit for analyzing nonlinear dynamic stochastic models easily. In R. Marimon & A. Scott (Eds.) Computational methods for the study of dynamic economics (pp. 30–61). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
43.
Zurück zum Zitat Uzawa, H. (1964). Optimal growth in a two sector model of capital accumulation. Review of Economic Studies, 31(1): 1–24.CrossRef Uzawa, H. (1964). Optimal growth in a two sector model of capital accumulation. Review of Economic Studies, 31(1): 1–24.CrossRef
44.
Zurück zum Zitat Vitek, F. (2018). The Global Macrofinancial Model. IMF Working Paper No. 18/81. Vitek, F. (2018). The Global Macrofinancial Model. IMF Working Paper No. 18/81.
45.
Zurück zum Zitat Whiteman, C. H. (1983). Linear rational expectations models: A user’s guide. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.CrossRef Whiteman, C. H. (1983). Linear rational expectations models: A user’s guide. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Introduction
verfasst von
Alfonso Novales
Esther Fernández
Jesús Ruiz
Copyright-Jahr
2022
Verlag
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-63982-5_1

Premium Partner