Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 3/2017

20.10.2016 | Original Research

Equity prices and fundamentals: a DDM–APT mixed approach

verfasst von: Fredj Jawadi, Georges Prat

Erschienen in: Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting | Ausgabe 3/2017

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This paper focuses on the linkage between equity prices and fundamentals for 27 individual shares belonging to the French stock price index (CAC40). To assess fundamental value, the traditional dividend discount model (DDM) is coupled with the arbitrage pricing theory (APT), which assumes that investors hold efficient portfolios. This yields a simple equity valuation relationship for which the APT determines the long-term risk premium included in the DDM. Accordingly, equity risk premia are determined by common factors reflecting the non diversifiable risk. These factors are not a priori identified by the theory, and therefore must be exhibited through an empirical analysis. Four domestic and three international common factors are found, all being among those identified by empirical analyses of the APT in the literature. While studies related to stock price indices showed that DDM fundamental values are very smooth compared to stock indices, our DDM–APT model reproduces both trends and major fluctuations of share prices. Further, as for studies based on stock indices, a mean-reverting process of equity prices towards fundamentals is highlighted, but the linear error correction model that was considered contains shortcomings suggesting a more complex adjustment process.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
For an overview of the literature on stock price indices and fundamentals’ relationships, see Jawadi and Prat (2012).
 
2
We leave aside portfolio choice theories based on the international CAPM or international APT where national stock market returns are considered from the perspective of building an efficient world portfolio. Studies generally focus on modeling the time-varying degree of integration of national stock markets and gains from international diversification. The empirical results show that international variables play a part in determining domestic market risk premium (in particular the return on the world stock index).
 
3
However, by introducing a time-varying risk premium in the Gordon dividends growth formula, Prat (1992, 2013) showed that it is possible to generate a fundamental value of the S&P index, which is more volatile than that obtained under REH. However, the author did not analyze the stock price adjustment towards the fundamental value.
 
4
Lansing (2016) explained changes in price variance through the effects of news about dividends.
 
5
Kocherlakota (1996) and more recently Prat (2007) provided comprehensive on the equity premium puzzle debate.
 
6
Adam et al. (2016) confirm for the US stock market that the consumption-based asset pricing model might solve the “volatility puzzle” if one allows for deviations from rational expectations. However, it is worth noting that, as for Cechetti et al. (2000), this study does not examine the correlation over time between theoretical and observed returns.
 
7
See Appendix of the present paper.
 
8
In particular, the VAR system used by Campbell and Shiller (1988b) (that includes the log dividend-price ratio, stock returns, growth in dividends and other variables representing the risk-free rate and the risk premium) puts into evidence that these variables enable to improve the forecast of the US stock market, which suggests that expectations are in fact not rational. This result was confirmed by Campbell (1991) and Campbell and Shiller (2001) who showed for twelve countries that, contrary to the efficient market hypothesis, price-earnings and dividend-price ratios are relevant variables to predict future stock price changes. Among others, Zhi et al. (2014) confirmed recently this result for G7 countries.
 
9
For each of the 5 years covering the period 1961–1965, the authors showed that between 50 and 75 % of variance in the observed price/earnings ratios of 175 American firms can be explained by the DDM wherein beta coefficients (deduced from the CAPM) are considered as a risk indicator. For a given firm, this means that the risk premium is given by the product of beta by its regression coefficient. It can then be seen that this approach is a mixture of the DDM and a simple version of the CAPM.
 
10
In particular, see Chapter 5 by Barucci (2003) that gives an overview of the empirical results arising from the two asset-pricing models.
 
11
Recall that the APT risk premia for n equities are generally estimated in two steps. The first one consists of regressing (time series) each of the n observed one-period returns on a set of the zero-mean unexpected components of k common variables and possibly changes in their expected values (typically, an ARIMA model is used to estimate the one-period ahead expected value). Accordingly, the slopes of these regressions give the estimated values of the sensitivities of returns to common factors while the intercepts represent the expected returns (a preliminary factor analysis is sometimes used in this first stage to choose the k relevant common factors, which of course does not avoid the arbitrary choice in the initial set of common variables). The second step consists of regressing (cross-section) the n expected returns on the estimated values of sensitivities, the k factorial premia being given by the values of the slopes while the riskless rate is captured by the intercept of this regression. Accordingly, the significant common factors are those for which the slopes are significant, the risk premium of any equity being measured by cumulating the effects of the k-independent factors.
 
12
In the Appendix of this paper, we compare this traditional formula with its so-called dynamic version proposed by Campbell and Shiller (1988b) and explain why we used the first one rather than the second one.
 
13
Unlike aggregate dividends associated with stock price indices, the monthly time series of dividends follows stepped patterns for any given firm.
 
14
With respect to the usual regressive expectation process, the observed rate of growth \( g_{it} \) was here replaced by the long term rate \( \bar{g}_{it} \).
 
15
This value can be viewed as characterizing the dynamic equilibrium condition regarding dividends growth.
 
16
This condition means that the purchase of securities is offset by short sales. Interestingly, the absence of the arbitrage hypothesis is in accordance with Welch (2000) who showed that investors have a strong view in favor of this condition.
 
17
If the only common factor is the domestic stock market, the risk premia of equities given by Eq. (3) correspond to the CAPM; this case is characterized by \( {}_{1}\varphi_{t} = \tilde{R}_{mt} - r_{ot} \), where \( \tilde{R}_{mt} \) stands for the expected market return and \( {}_{j}\varphi_{t} = 0\,\;\forall j,t \) for \( j \ne 1 \).
 
18
Of course, one should expect different sensitivities to common factors for small firms than for large firms.
 
19
Unlike to empirical tests of the APT in the literature [see footnote (14) above].
 
20
Regarding the seven significant common factors \( {}_{j}X_{t}^{{}} \) considered hereafter, for \( {}_{1}X_{t}^{{}} \) (domestic stock market) and \( {}_{5}X_{t}^{{}} \) (world stock market), we have \( {}_{j}a = 1 \) (and \( {}_{j}b = 0 \))  since these factors are directly viewed as market and world risk premia respectively; for \( {}_{2}X_{t}^{{}} \) (economic sentiment), we have \( {}_{j}a < 0 \) for \( {}_{3}X_{t}^{{}} \) and \( {}_{4}X_{t}^{{}} \) (interest rate spreads) and for \( {}_{6}X_{t}^{{}} \) (oil price) we have \( {}_{j}a > 0 \); for \( {}_{7}X_{t}^{{}} \) (Euro/USD exchange rate), the sign of \( {}_{j}a \) is a priori undetermined since this variable both increases the cost of imports (negative effect) and improves competitiveness (positive effect), so that the overall effect might vary according to the companies.
 
21
However, some important companies were excluded either because (1) data on dividends was not available over the period, (2) these companies were subject to a merger or acquisition (i.e. EADS, EDF/GDF), or (3) the companies were listed on the stock market after 1989.
 
22
It can be seen that the French market factor in Fig. 2 confirms this point.
 
23
The magnitude of the deviation for each of the four groups is measured as the average of the standard errors of individual deviations (as estimated from the DDM-APT model) relative to the equities belonging to the group.
 
24
The world inflation rate was also considered, but this variable appeared significant for only 4 of the 27 equities considered, so it was excluded from the set of potential factors.
 
25
We alternatively expressed this variable in real terms (i.e. deflated by the world commodity price index) but the results remained quite similar.
 
26
Stock price indices, exchange rate and oil price are dated at the end of the month (as are equity prices), while interest rates and the Economic Sentiment Index are monthly averages.
 
27
We do not report the results to save space.
 
28
Of course, under the unrealistic conditions that the DDM is “the true” valuation formula, that the common factors of risk premia are perfectly known, and that share prices adjust instantaneously to their fundamentals, the correlations between the contemporaneous residuals \( \varepsilon_{it} = \eta_{{i{\kern 1pt} t}} + \zeta_{{i{\kern 1pt} t}} \) of the 27 firms would be null and then the OLS relevant, since the error terms \( \zeta_{{i{\kern 1pt} t}} \) would be white noises while the terms \( \eta_{{i{\kern 1pt} t}} \) that represent specific components of risk are a priori uncorrelated across firms.
 
29
The average of the \( R^{2} \) between the 351 pairs of the 27 SUR-residuals is 0.25, with a minimum of zero and a maximum of 0.64 (about 80 % of \( R^{2} \) were found to be significant). To compare, we estimated Eq. (6) for the 27 firms using OLS and found a drop up to 20 % of the number of significant common factors for all firms with respect to the SUR method, hence confirming the interest of using the latter. However, the SUR method brings no correction to the variance of estimates when errors terms are auto-correlated. To appreciate the consequence of this issue, we compared the OLS results to those obtained using the Newey-West method—according to which the variances of estimates converge towards their true values when residuals are serially correlated—and found that the two methods lead practically to the same set of significant common factors, hence suggesting that, with our data, the autocorrelation of residuals does not alter the selection of factors. In addition to being robust to correlation of residuals across firms, the SUR method has the advantage to avoid the arbitrary choice of instrumental variables, as it would be the case especially with the GMM. Finally, note that, although a panel approach was feasible with our cylindered data, it is not appropriate since all slopes related to the 27 firms are a priori firm-dependent.
 
30
Surprisingly, oil price appeared insignificant for Total. This suggests that, on average, the negative effect on risk premium arising from an expected increase in the supply side of the oil market is compensated for by the positive effect resulting from an expected decrease in oil demand. Otherwise, the fact that the WTI market relates to crude oil price while Total is concerned with production and refining for both oil and gas, adds uncertainty with regard to the sign of the global effect.
 
31
The tenuous results concerning the ADF tests are mainly due to the existence of a few extreme values in the residuals of Eq. (6). We did not eliminate these points by using dummies since the extreme deviations between equity prices and fundamental values may intervene in the adjustment process of share prices towards fundamentals analyzed hereafter.
 
32
In fact, while for some equities the volatility is greater for \( f_{it}^{*} \) than for \( p_{it}^{{}} \), the opposite prevails for others. Similar remarks can be made when sub-periods are distinguished for a given equity. Regarding the mean of the 27 \( f_{it}^{*} \) and the mean of the 27 \( p_{it}^{{}} \), these two averages appeared to be rather comparable (standard errors are 19.1 and 17.9, respectively); if observations corresponding to the bursting of the “dot.com bubble” are excluded, these two averaged values are not significantly different.
 
33
This visual feeling is confirmed when the common component of deviations is approximated by the average of the 27 deviations \( z_{{i{\kern 1pt} t}} \), that is \( \bar{z}_{{{\kern 1pt} t}} = \frac{1}{27}\sum\limits_{i = 1}^{27} {z_{i\,t} } \). Indeed, the mean value of the 27 coefficients \( R^{2} (z_{it} ,\bar{z}_{\,t} ) \) was 0.34, indicating that, on average, about 1/3 of the variance of an equity’s deviation is due to the common component, while 2/3 is due to a specific component (we checked that the average \( R^{2} \) between the specific components \( z_{{i{\kern 1pt} \,t}} - \,\;\bar{z}_{t} \) and the common component \( \bar{z}_{t} \), which equals 0.04, can be neglected in a first instance). Although \( \bar{z}_{t} \) was found to be significantly serially correlated, we checked that this common component is not linked with any linear combination of our seven common factors, hence confirming that these factors was captured satisfactorily in the fundamental values of equities.
 
34
The fundamental value of a given equity is supposed common knowledge for stockholders but each of them has their own appreciation of uncertainty about this value.
 
35
See Jawadi and Prat (2012) for more details.
 
36
Recall that the basic specification of the ECM can be written as \( p_{{i{\kern 1pt} t}} - p_{{i{\kern 1pt} t - 1}} = \rho_{i} (f_{{i{\kern 1pt} t - 1}}^{*} - p_{{i{\kern 1pt} t - 1}} ) + \,b_{i} (f_{{i{\kern 1pt} t}}^{*} - f_{{i{\kern 1pt} t - 1}}^{*} ) + \zeta_{it} \), \( \rho_{i} > 0 \), \( b_{i} > 0 \). Under the long-term equilibrium condition \( b_{i} = 1 \) (meaning that price and fundamental value increase at the same rate) and re-arranging the terms, we get \( z_{{i{\kern 1pt} t}} - z_{{i{\kern 1pt} t - 1}} = - \rho_{i} \,z_{{i{\kern 1pt} t - 1}} + \zeta_{it} \). By increasing this basic ECM by including past values of changes in \( p_{it} \) and \( f_{{i{\kern 1pt} t}}^{*} \), we get Eq. (9) provided that \( k_{i} = 0 \). We leave the possibility that the intercept \( k_{i} \) is different from zero since there is a priori no reason for the means of deviations \( z_{it} \) to be null over the period under consideration. In fact, we found \( k_{i} \ne 0 \) for only 3 of the 27 equities.
 
37
It should be noted that if \( z_{it} \) was viewed as an observable variable, Eq. (9) would corresponds to a classical unit root test, so that the condition found \( 0 < \rho_{i} < 1 \) in Table 3 would allow to conclude that \( z_{it} \) is stationary, meaning that \( p_{{i{\kern 1pt} t}} \) and \( f_{{i{\kern 1pt} t}}^{*} \) are cointegrated, which goes rather in the sense that \( f_{{i{\kern 1pt} t}}^{*} \) is a valid measure of the fundamental value.
 
38
As a result, the two largest firms (Total and Sanofi) are those for which prices adjust the slower to fundamentals. This suggests that, in our sample, the tendency of the market to reach efficiency is not improved with the increase of firm size.
 
39
To save space, we do not report the results of these tests. They are however available upon request.
 
40
Moreover, the short term adjustment process could also involve variables other than those considered in the right hand side of Eq. (9).
 
41
The subsequent studies based on the dynamic Gordon growth model also used a VAR system [among others, see Bekaert and Engstrom (2010)].
 
42
C&S found rather large residuals for the log dividend-price ratio Eq. (A.2). In fact, the authors reported that the Taylor approximation may in some cases produce non negligible errors with respect to the Gordon structural relation. In this regard, one can see that Eqs. (10) and (11) link the log of a percentage to percentages, while Eq. (1) leads to link a percentage to percentages, which seems a priori more natural.
 
43
In fact, this is a generally accepted assumption since one cannot probably do otherwise. For example, when expected returns are for one year ahead, it is implicitly supposed something like uniformity of expectations during this time horizon.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Abou A, Prat G (2000) Modelling stock price expectations: lessons from microdata. In: Gardes F, Prat G (eds) Price expectations in goods and financial markets. Edward Elgar, Northampton, pp 313–346 Abou A, Prat G (2000) Modelling stock price expectations: lessons from microdata. In: Gardes F, Prat G (eds) Price expectations in goods and financial markets. Edward Elgar, Northampton, pp 313–346
Zurück zum Zitat Abou A, Prat G (2010) The dynamics of U.S. equity premia: lessons from professionals’ view. Bank Mark Invest 104:4–20 Abou A, Prat G (2010) The dynamics of U.S. equity premia: lessons from professionals’ view. Bank Mark Invest 104:4–20
Zurück zum Zitat Adam K, Beutel J, Nicolini JP (2016) Stock market volatility and learning. J Finance 71(1):33–82CrossRef Adam K, Beutel J, Nicolini JP (2016) Stock market volatility and learning. J Finance 71(1):33–82CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Allen DE, Yang W (2001) Do UK stock prices deviate from fundamentals? Joondalup Campus Working Paper No. 6027, Edith Cowan University, Australia Allen DE, Yang W (2001) Do UK stock prices deviate from fundamentals? Joondalup Campus Working Paper No. 6027, Edith Cowan University, Australia
Zurück zum Zitat Anderson HM (1997) Transaction costs and nonlinear adjustment towards equilibrium in the US treasury bill markets. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 59:465–484CrossRef Anderson HM (1997) Transaction costs and nonlinear adjustment towards equilibrium in the US treasury bill markets. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 59:465–484CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Barberis N, Thaler RH (2003) A survey of behavioral finance. In: Constantinides GM, Harris M, Stultz R (eds) Handbook of the economics of finance. Elsevier Science, North Holland, Amsterdam, pp 1053–1123 Barberis N, Thaler RH (2003) A survey of behavioral finance. In: Constantinides GM, Harris M, Stultz R (eds) Handbook of the economics of finance. Elsevier Science, North Holland, Amsterdam, pp 1053–1123
Zurück zum Zitat Barberis N, Shleifer A, Vishny RW (1998) A model of investor sentiment. J Financ Econ 49:307–343CrossRef Barberis N, Shleifer A, Vishny RW (1998) A model of investor sentiment. J Financ Econ 49:307–343CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Barsky RB, De Long JB (1993) Why does the stock market fluctuate? Q J Econ 108(2):291–311CrossRef Barsky RB, De Long JB (1993) Why does the stock market fluctuate? Q J Econ 108(2):291–311CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bates GE (1962) Comprehensive stock value tables. Harv Bus Rev 40(1):53–67 Bates GE (1962) Comprehensive stock value tables. Harv Bus Rev 40(1):53–67
Zurück zum Zitat Bekaert G, Engstrom E (2010) Inflation and the stock market: understanding the ‘Fed Model’. J Monet Econ 57(3):278–294CrossRef Bekaert G, Engstrom E (2010) Inflation and the stock market: understanding the ‘Fed Model’. J Monet Econ 57(3):278–294CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Beltratti A, Shiller R (1990) Stock prices and bond yields: can their co-movements be explained in terms of present value models? NBER Working Paper No. 3464, October Beltratti A, Shiller R (1990) Stock prices and bond yields: can their co-movements be explained in terms of present value models? NBER Working Paper No. 3464, October
Zurück zum Zitat Booth L (1998) A new model for estimating risk premiums (along with some evidence of their decline). J Appl Corp Finance 11(1):109–121CrossRef Booth L (1998) A new model for estimating risk premiums (along with some evidence of their decline). J Appl Corp Finance 11(1):109–121CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Boswijk HP, Hommes CH, Manzan S (2007) Behavioral heterogeneity in stock prices. J Econ Dyn Control 31(6):1938–1970CrossRef Boswijk HP, Hommes CH, Manzan S (2007) Behavioral heterogeneity in stock prices. J Econ Dyn Control 31(6):1938–1970CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bruneau C, Duval-Kieffer C, Nicolai J-P (1999) Changements structurels de la prime de risque et évaluation des marchés d’actions. Economie et Prévision 140–41:63–76CrossRef Bruneau C, Duval-Kieffer C, Nicolai J-P (1999) Changements structurels de la prime de risque et évaluation des marchés d’actions. Economie et Prévision 140–41:63–76CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Campbell J (1991) A variance decomposition for stock returns. Econ J 101(405):157–179CrossRef Campbell J (1991) A variance decomposition for stock returns. Econ J 101(405):157–179CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Campbell J, Shiller R (1988a) Stock prices, earnings and expected dividends. J Finance 43:662–676CrossRef Campbell J, Shiller R (1988a) Stock prices, earnings and expected dividends. J Finance 43:662–676CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Campbell JY, Shiller RJ (1988b) The dividend price ratio and expectations of future dividends and discount factors. Rev Financ Stud 1:195–228CrossRef Campbell JY, Shiller RJ (1988b) The dividend price ratio and expectations of future dividends and discount factors. Rev Financ Stud 1:195–228CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Campbell JY, Shiller R (2001) Valuation ratios and the long-run stock market outlook: an update. NBER Working Paper No. 8282 Campbell JY, Shiller R (2001) Valuation ratios and the long-run stock market outlook: an update. NBER Working Paper No. 8282
Zurück zum Zitat Cecchetti SG, Lam PS, Mark NC (1990) Mean reversion in equilibrium asset prices. Am Econ Rev 80:398–418 Cecchetti SG, Lam PS, Mark NC (1990) Mean reversion in equilibrium asset prices. Am Econ Rev 80:398–418
Zurück zum Zitat Cechetti SG, Lam PS, Mark NC (2000) Asset pricing with distorted beliefs: are equity returns too good to be true? Am Econ Rev 80:787–805CrossRef Cechetti SG, Lam PS, Mark NC (2000) Asset pricing with distorted beliefs: are equity returns too good to be true? Am Econ Rev 80:787–805CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chen NF, Roll R, Ross S (1986) Economic forces and the stock market: testing the APT and alternative asset pricing theories. J Bus 59:383–403CrossRef Chen NF, Roll R, Ross S (1986) Economic forces and the stock market: testing the APT and alternative asset pricing theories. J Bus 59:383–403CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Copeland TE, Weston JF, Shastri K (2005) Financial theory and corporate policy. Pearson Addison Wesley, Boston Copeland TE, Weston JF, Shastri K (2005) Financial theory and corporate policy. Pearson Addison Wesley, Boston
Zurück zum Zitat Damodaran A (2011) Damodaran on valuation: security analysis for investment and corporate finance. Wiley, New York Damodaran A (2011) Damodaran on valuation: security analysis for investment and corporate finance. Wiley, New York
Zurück zum Zitat Daniel K, Hirshleifer D, Subrahmanyam A (1998) Investor psychology and security market under- and overreactions. J Finance 53:1839–1885CrossRef Daniel K, Hirshleifer D, Subrahmanyam A (1998) Investor psychology and security market under- and overreactions. J Finance 53:1839–1885CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Efthimios GD, Norman CS, Martin W (2004) What valuation models do analysts use? Account Horiz 18(4):221–240CrossRef Efthimios GD, Norman CS, Martin W (2004) What valuation models do analysts use? Account Horiz 18(4):221–240CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Elton EJ, Gruber MJ, Mei J (1994) Cost of capital using arbitrage pricing theory: a case study of nine New York utilities. Financ Mark Inst Instrum 3:46–73 Elton EJ, Gruber MJ, Mei J (1994) Cost of capital using arbitrage pricing theory: a case study of nine New York utilities. Financ Mark Inst Instrum 3:46–73
Zurück zum Zitat Engle RF, Granger CWJ (1991) Long-run economic relationships, readings in cointegration. Advanced texts in econometrics, Paperback, London Engle RF, Granger CWJ (1991) Long-run economic relationships, readings in cointegration. Advanced texts in econometrics, Paperback, London
Zurück zum Zitat Fama EF (1965) The behaviour of stock market prices. J Bus 38(1):31–105CrossRef Fama EF (1965) The behaviour of stock market prices. J Bus 38(1):31–105CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fama EF, French KR (1988) Dividends yields and expected stock returns. J Financ Econ 1:3–25CrossRef Fama EF, French KR (1988) Dividends yields and expected stock returns. J Financ Econ 1:3–25CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fama EF, French KR (2002) The equity premium. J Finance 57(2):637–659CrossRef Fama EF, French KR (2002) The equity premium. J Finance 57(2):637–659CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Foerster SR, Sapp SG (2005) The dividend discount model in the long-run: a clinical study. J Appl Finance 15(2):55–75 Foerster SR, Sapp SG (2005) The dividend discount model in the long-run: a clinical study. J Appl Finance 15(2):55–75
Zurück zum Zitat Fontaine P (1987) Arbitrage et évaluation internationale des actifs financiers. Economica, Paris Fontaine P (1987) Arbitrage et évaluation internationale des actifs financiers. Economica, Paris
Zurück zum Zitat Gordon MJ (1959) Dividends, earnings and stock prices. Rev Econ Stat 41(2):99–105CrossRef Gordon MJ (1959) Dividends, earnings and stock prices. Rev Econ Stat 41(2):99–105CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gordon MJ (1962) The investment, financing and valuation of the corporation. Irwin, Homewood Gordon MJ (1962) The investment, financing and valuation of the corporation. Irwin, Homewood
Zurück zum Zitat Gordon MJ, Shapiro E (1956) Capital equipment analysis: the required rate of profit. Manag Sci 3(1):102–110CrossRef Gordon MJ, Shapiro E (1956) Capital equipment analysis: the required rate of profit. Manag Sci 3(1):102–110CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Heaton J, Lucas D (2000) Stock prices and fundamentals. NBER Chapters. In: NBER Macroeconomics Annual, vol 14. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, pp 213–264 Heaton J, Lucas D (2000) Stock prices and fundamentals. NBER Chapters. In: NBER Macroeconomics Annual, vol 14. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, pp 213–264
Zurück zum Zitat Jawadi F (2006) Stock price adjustment toward fundamentals. PhD Thesis, University of Paris West, Paris Jawadi F (2006) Stock price adjustment toward fundamentals. PhD Thesis, University of Paris West, Paris
Zurück zum Zitat Jawadi F, Prat G (2012) Arbitrage costs and nonlinear stock price adjustment in the G7 Countries. Appl Econ 44(12):1561–1582CrossRef Jawadi F, Prat G (2012) Arbitrage costs and nonlinear stock price adjustment in the G7 Countries. Appl Econ 44(12):1561–1582CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Jawadi F, Louhichi W, Idi Cheffou A (2015) Testing and modeling jump contagion across international stock markets: a nonparametric intraday approach. J Financ Mark 26:64–84CrossRef Jawadi F, Louhichi W, Idi Cheffou A (2015) Testing and modeling jump contagion across international stock markets: a nonparametric intraday approach. J Financ Mark 26:64–84CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kocherlakota NR (1996) The equity premium: it’s still a puzzle. J Econ Lit 34:42–71 Kocherlakota NR (1996) The equity premium: it’s still a puzzle. J Econ Lit 34:42–71
Zurück zum Zitat Kryzanowski L, Lalancette S, To MC (1997) Performance attribution using an APT with pre-specified macrofactors and time-varying risk premia and betas. J Financ Quant Anal 32(2):205–224CrossRef Kryzanowski L, Lalancette S, To MC (1997) Performance attribution using an APT with pre-specified macrofactors and time-varying risk premia and betas. J Financ Quant Anal 32(2):205–224CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lansing K (2016) On variance bounds for asset price changes. J Financ Mark 28:132–148CrossRef Lansing K (2016) On variance bounds for asset price changes. J Financ Mark 28:132–148CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lorie JH, Hamilton MT (1973) The stock market: theory and evidence. Irwin, Homewood Lorie JH, Hamilton MT (1973) The stock market: theory and evidence. Irwin, Homewood
Zurück zum Zitat Lucas RE (1978) Asset prices in an exchange economy. Econometrica 46:1429–1445CrossRef Lucas RE (1978) Asset prices in an exchange economy. Econometrica 46:1429–1445CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Malkiel BG, Cragg JG (1970) Expectations and structure of share prices. Am Econ Rev 60:601–617. This text was updated in (same title), a National Bureau of Economic Research Monograph, 1982 Malkiel BG, Cragg JG (1970) Expectations and structure of share prices. Am Econ Rev 60:601–617. This text was updated in (same title), a National Bureau of Economic Research Monograph, 1982
Zurück zum Zitat Manzan S (2003) Essays on nonlinear economic dynamics. PhD Thesis, University of Amsterdam Manzan S (2003) Essays on nonlinear economic dynamics. PhD Thesis, University of Amsterdam
Zurück zum Zitat Mehra R, Prescott E (1985) The equity premium: a puzzle. J Monet Econ 15:145–161CrossRef Mehra R, Prescott E (1985) The equity premium: a puzzle. J Monet Econ 15:145–161CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Park C (2006) Rational beliefs or distorted beliefs: equity premium puzzle and micro survey data. South Econ J 72:677–689CrossRef Park C (2006) Rational beliefs or distorted beliefs: equity premium puzzle and micro survey data. South Econ J 72:677–689CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Poterba JM, Summers LH (1988) Mean reversion in stock prices: evidence and implications. J Financ Econ 22:27–59CrossRef Poterba JM, Summers LH (1988) Mean reversion in stock prices: evidence and implications. J Financ Econ 22:27–59CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Prat G (1992) Anticipations et évaluation des actions. In: Kempf H, Marois W (eds) Monnaie, taux d’intérêt et anticipations. Economica, Paris Prat G (1992) Anticipations et évaluation des actions. In: Kempf H, Marois W (eds) Monnaie, taux d’intérêt et anticipations. Economica, Paris
Zurück zum Zitat Prat G (2007) Les comportements boursiers sont-ils eulériens? Revue Economique 58(2):427–453CrossRef Prat G (2007) Les comportements boursiers sont-ils eulériens? Revue Economique 58(2):427–453CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Prat G (2013) Equity risk premium and time horizon: what do the U.S. secular data say? Econ Model 34:76–88CrossRef Prat G (2013) Equity risk premium and time horizon: what do the U.S. secular data say? Econ Model 34:76–88CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rahman MA, Hassan MK (2013) Firm fundamentals and stock prices in emerging Asian stock markets: some panel data evidence. Rev Quant Financ Account 41(3):463–487CrossRef Rahman MA, Hassan MK (2013) Firm fundamentals and stock prices in emerging Asian stock markets: some panel data evidence. Rev Quant Financ Account 41(3):463–487CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Roll R, Ross RA (1980) An empirical investigation of the arbitrage pricing theory. J Finance 35:1073–1103CrossRef Roll R, Ross RA (1980) An empirical investigation of the arbitrage pricing theory. J Finance 35:1073–1103CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ross S (1976) The arbitrage pricing theory of capital asset pricing. J Econ Theory 13:341–360CrossRef Ross S (1976) The arbitrage pricing theory of capital asset pricing. J Econ Theory 13:341–360CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Samuelson P (1965) Proof that properly anticipated prices fluctuate randomly. Ind Manag Rev 6:41–49 Samuelson P (1965) Proof that properly anticipated prices fluctuate randomly. Ind Manag Rev 6:41–49
Zurück zum Zitat Sharpe WF (1964) Capital asset prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. J Finance 19(3):425–442 Sharpe WF (1964) Capital asset prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. J Finance 19(3):425–442
Zurück zum Zitat Shiller RJ (1981) Do stock prices move too much to be justified by subsequent changes in dividends? Am Econ Rev 7:421–436 Shiller RJ (1981) Do stock prices move too much to be justified by subsequent changes in dividends? Am Econ Rev 7:421–436
Zurück zum Zitat Shiller RJ (2000) Irrational exuberance. Princeton University, Princeton Shiller RJ (2000) Irrational exuberance. Princeton University, Princeton
Zurück zum Zitat Shleifer A, Summers LH (1990) The noise trader approach to finance. J Econ Perspect 4:19–33CrossRef Shleifer A, Summers LH (1990) The noise trader approach to finance. J Econ Perspect 4:19–33CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Summers LH (1986) Does the stock market rationally reflect fundamental values? J Finance XLI:591–601CrossRef Summers LH (1986) Does the stock market rationally reflect fundamental values? J Finance XLI:591–601CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Teräsvirta T (1994) Specification, estimation and evaluation of smooth transition autoregressive models. J Am Stat Assoc 89:208–218 Teräsvirta T (1994) Specification, estimation and evaluation of smooth transition autoregressive models. J Am Stat Assoc 89:208–218
Zurück zum Zitat Teräsvirta T, Yang Y (2014) Specification, estimation and evaluation of vector smooth transition autoregressive models with applications. CREATES Research Papers, Institute for Økonomi, Aarhus University, 28 March Teräsvirta T, Yang Y (2014) Specification, estimation and evaluation of vector smooth transition autoregressive models with applications. CREATES Research Papers, Institute for Økonomi, Aarhus University, 28 March
Zurück zum Zitat Van Dijk D, Teräsvirta T, Franses PH (2002) Smooth transition autoregressive models—a survey of recent developments. Econ Rev 21:1–47CrossRef Van Dijk D, Teräsvirta T, Franses PH (2002) Smooth transition autoregressive models—a survey of recent developments. Econ Rev 21:1–47CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Watanapalachaikul S, Islam SMN (2007) Rational speculative bubbles in the Thai stock market: econometric tests and implications. Rev Pac Basin Financ Mark Policies 10(1):1–13CrossRef Watanapalachaikul S, Islam SMN (2007) Rational speculative bubbles in the Thai stock market: econometric tests and implications. Rev Pac Basin Financ Mark Policies 10(1):1–13CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Welch I (2000) Views of financial economists on the equity premium and on professional controversies. J Bus 73(4):501–537CrossRef Welch I (2000) Views of financial economists on the equity premium and on professional controversies. J Bus 73(4):501–537CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Whitbeck VS, Kisor M (1963) A new tool in investment decision-making. Financ Anal J 19(3):55–62CrossRef Whitbeck VS, Kisor M (1963) A new tool in investment decision-making. Financ Anal J 19(3):55–62CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Williams JB (1938) Theory of investment value. North Holland Publishing CO, Amsterdam. See Chapter V: Evaluation by the rule of present worth, pp 55–75 Williams JB (1938) Theory of investment value. North Holland Publishing CO, Amsterdam. See Chapter V: Evaluation by the rule of present worth, pp 55–75
Zurück zum Zitat Zellner A (1962) An efficient method of estimating seemingly unrelated regressions and tests for aggregation bias. J Am Stat Assoc 57:348–368CrossRef Zellner A (1962) An efficient method of estimating seemingly unrelated regressions and tests for aggregation bias. J Am Stat Assoc 57:348–368CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Zhi D, Ravi J, Jianfeng S (2014) Growth expectations, dividends yields, and future stock returns. NBER WP No. 20651, October Zhi D, Ravi J, Jianfeng S (2014) Growth expectations, dividends yields, and future stock returns. NBER WP No. 20651, October
Metadaten
Titel
Equity prices and fundamentals: a DDM–APT mixed approach
verfasst von
Fredj Jawadi
Georges Prat
Publikationsdatum
20.10.2016
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting / Ausgabe 3/2017
Print ISSN: 0924-865X
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7179
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-016-0604-y

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 3/2017

Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 3/2017 Zur Ausgabe