Skip to main content

2018 | OriginalPaper | Buchkapitel

Innovation, Business Models, and Catastrophe: Reframing the Mental Model for Innovation Management

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Innovation is often considered to be the golden bullet of corporate success. However, seen on a global level, most of our present-day innovations and innovation strategies are fuelling a process which might well lead to global collapse. The reason for this is that innovation and innovation management are guided by a mental model of economy which seems beholden to the three mantras of “Outwit, Outperform, Outsmart”, “Be Better or Vanish”, and “Be Different or Die”. According to these mantras and the mental model behind them, corporate success can best be facilitated by the invention of product qualities, value propositions, and business models so exclusive that they secure absolute dominance over the market, the value chain, or the revenue stream. Guided by these principles, games of innovation that might in themselves be rational and, as such, often highly successful will fuel developments that are highly destructive on the global level, as they keep a constant downward spiral of acceleration, concentration, disruption, and resource depletion spinning.
To counter the inherent destructiveness of present-day wealth creation, the mental model and mantras guiding our innovation games need to change. This can be done by aligning innovation and innovation management with the evolutionary and ecological principles of natural value creation and the values of the Global Ethos concept. Together, they form the basis for a new understanding of lastingly viable value creation and innovation management: the concept of ethicological business models and value propositions. Instead of fuelling a process that underlies the continuous and globally destructive mechanisms of concentration, disruption, and resource depletion, they have the potential to stop this downward spiral by establishing innovative forms of resource growth and added value creation cycles.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 390 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe




 

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
The pursuit of dominance in the market to gain control over market access can be called the pursuit of inverse monopolies (Glauner 2016). The market strategies and negotiating power of leading retailers show the mechanisms behind such inverse monopolies. According to a report published by German anti-trust officials in April 2014, 85% of the German food retail industry is dominated by a mere four companies: Aldi, Edeka, Lidl/Kaufland, and REWE. They use their power to force suppliers in increasing dependence, while also engaging in a strategy of flooding the market with discount to premium store brands. Traditional brands are under pressure from three sides, which only reinforces the monopoly-lite power of the big four retailers: First, small to mediums-sized producers are forced to accept often ruinous discounts and bonus payments, and even subsidize the shelf space and marketing campaigns for their products. Second, since the retailers do not expect the same discounts or payments from their own store brands, the independent producers are placed at a natural disadvantage. This is made worse by a third aspect of the strategies used by the major retailers: The creation of store brands often goes hand in hand with more vertical integration, with retailers acquiring or establishing own production and processing facilities. This in turn gives the retailers even more leverage. A recent comparative advertising campaign by Lidl pitted well-known brands against the discount retailer’s own brands, representing a type of price war against products on offer by Lidl itself: A radio advert compared the sound of opening a bottle of Lipton’s ice tea with the sound of a Lidl ice tea, with a voice over asking: “What’s the difference? Lipton’s ice tea, €1.50. Lidl ice tea, €0.49”.
 
2
“In 1990, 1.9 billion were living in extreme poverty. By 2015 that number had been cut by more than half, to 830 million, while in parallel the global middle class had almost tripled. And most citizens of advanced economics today command goods and services that were beyond the reach of even kings and emperors only 200 years ago“(Stuchtey et al. 2016, S. 8). Even if these figures sound extremely positive in the abstract, they need to be taken with a pinch of salt: As the Pew Research Center authors Rakesh Kochhar and Russ Oats stress in their study “A global middle class is more promise than reality”, poverty is defined as an income of less than $2 a day, average and high middle-class income as $10.01 to $20 or $20.01 to $50 per day, and high income as $50 per day. People above the global poverty line and up to those defined as the global middle classes therefore have an income of between $730 and $7300 per year: “Even those newly minted as middle class enjoy a standard of living that is modest by Western norms. As defined in this study, people who are middle income live on $10–20 a day, which translates to an annual income of $14,600–29,200 for a family of four. That range merely straddles the official poverty line in the United States—$23,021 for a family of four in 2011” (Kochhar und Oats 2015, p. 6).
 
3
Referencing Ayres and Warr (2005, 2009), Stuchtey et al. (2016) have revealed that the exponential growth since the industrial revolution has for the most part been due to the exploitation of fossil fuels and other natural resources: “Taming wind and hydro energy, and inputting them into the economy, once allowed mechanization of grinding, pumping, sawing, irrigation and many other laborious tasks … Taming coal and vastly increasing the amount of energy put into the economy was crucial for the first industrial revolution. While our modern economy has of course moved on from horses and steam engines, it is still striking how many industries continue to depend heavily on natural resources: food, transport, construction and all primary material production, for instance” (Stuchtey et al. 2016, p. 59). The idea “that the success [of modern day wealth creation, FG] is largely built on transforming natural capital, the economist’s word for natural resources, into other forms of capital” (Stuchtey et al. 2016, p. 9) leads them to conclude that today’s untenable rate of resource depletion will lead to an inevitable collapse in the accepted model of constant economic growth: “Since the mid-1980s and with ever-increasing speed, environmental depletion has reached a global scale and scope where it actually starts to threaten the viability of our model of wealth creation itself. Our economy has grown so big, so fast, that it is quickly depleting the very same natural capital on which it thrives. In a way, it is falling victim to its own success” (Stuchtey et al. 2016, p. 11).
 
4
One is the human pursuit for differentiation, analyzed by Pierre Bourdieu (1982). It triggers our continuous search for new products, which we want to consume more often than not simple in order to show that we can do it. The other two are the economic spiral of prices and innovations and the need to yield interest on invested capital (Glauner 2016).
 
5
This can be shown not only with a view to the formation of bubbles, but even more so for one of the core inventions of economic transactions: the invention of money. Money, whether it be a thousand dollar bill or the Rai stone money of the Micronesian people of Palau and Yap weighing up to 5 tons, always carries its wealth only by force of the trust people put into it and into its owners. Such trust is a social, not a physical construct. As vast numbers of bursting bubbles show, it can vanish in seconds, leaving nothing else behind but waste paper and stones.
 
6
Following Pierre Duhem (1908) and Thomas Kuhn (1962) on the paradigmatic nature of scientific theory formation and Heinz von Foerster (1972, 1987) and Ernst von Glasersfeld (1995) on the cybernetic construction of reality, we have to admit that the objects of scientific enquiry are essentially constituted by the theories and observation / measurement processes we bring to the equation. But our perception of the world is not just dependent on the theories we espouse. It is also un- or underdetermined by its objective nature (Quine 1960). What we experience as existent has always been ‘ontologically relative’ (Quine 1969). The world is changing in the wake of new theories coming to the fore—our many scientific revolutions—in its basic form, function, and make-up. This now implies that the world can be described in many different ways and that no single way can lay claim to absolute truth. As Paul Feyerabend argues against the adherents of a positivist science and logical positivism and against the deceptively enlightened methods of rational science, such as Popper’s fallibilism (Popper 1935), all descriptions of the world are allowed. There is no one method with a rightful claim to universal validity: “anything goes” (Feyerabend 1975, 32).
 
7
As John Searle argues with good reason, the forms and laws of our social world, that is, the world of our man-made institutions and belief systems, are made by our declarations. Declarations are statements which bring about the fact when uttered, as the statement “You are fired!”, said by a boss to his or her employee, brings about the very fact it states. As Searle concludes with a view to our social practices and belief systems, “all of institutional reality, and therefore, in a sense, all of human civilization, is created by speech acts that have the same logical form as declarations “(Searle 2010, 12f; vgl. 1995, 59ff und 1969, 50ff und 175ff). These declarations are mirrors of the culturally informed hopes and aspirations that we carry into the world.
 
8
This explains why even Michael Jensen nowadays prefers to talk about integrity and morality, instead of how to control misconduct. As one of the founders of the principal-agent approach, which was built on the concept of mistrust, his recent thinking on integrity and morality as “powerful access to increased performance for individuals egoism, groups, organizations, and societies” (Erhard et al. 2009, see also Erhard et al. 2016) acknowledges that stick and carrot systems designed to address defection and non-cooperative behavior do not serve to raise trust. Referring to integrity and morality in this sense is an alignment to the humanistic insight that only mutual trust and faith serve to raise what Elinor Ostrom and Richard Sennett call the social capital that is needed if a business wants to excel (Ostrom 2000; Sennett 2006).
 
9
This self-fulfilling prophecy becomes most apparent in our mental model of who and what man is. We can see opposite ideas of the nature of humankind: on the one side Thomas Hobbes’ homo homini lupus, assuming that our bio-psycho-social conditioning makes us inherently evil and our actions selfish, uncivilized, and self-interested (Duerr 1988; Dawkins 1976) and, on the other side, the emancipated and enlightened idea of Jean-Jacques Rousseau and Immanuel Kant, who considered man to be empathetic and good by nature, capable of behaving in a civilized and cooperative fashion in normal circumstances (Elias 1939; Bauer 2006, 2008). In fact, and on well-established biological and historical grounds, we have to acknowledge that we are both (de Waal 2005; Harari 2015). Even though this is true, it still remains the case that individual people tend to think one way or the other. And this mere belief alone already triggers an expectancy loop which most often leads to its own fulfillment.
 
10
Robert Frank understands this race about relative gains to be the basic principle of the present day “Darwin economy”. Its internal logics consists in “the fact that individual and collective incentives diverge when relative income” or gains matter (Frank 2011, p. 44). Since in most economic games of competition, relative gains of individuals matter more than absolute gains of the group or the whole system, these divergent interests of individuals and groups trigger behaviors and “arms races” that not only cause enormous harm to the group, but tend to lead systematically to market failures which, in the end, offset any lasting advantages even for the most successful individuals in the system (Frank 2011, 30ff).
 
11
As Bernhard Kegel says with a nod to Gilbert et al. (2012), the biological concept of individuals should be dropped in favor of the idea of holobionts, that is, of symbiotic systems that engage in value-adding interactions with other similarly symbiotic systems (Kegel 2015, p. 309). Even though this statement is highly problematic if we see it from the human cognitive perspective—i.e. if we take into account that most of our ethical, philosophical, psychological, religious, social, and economic concepts, theories and world views and thus our basic understanding of rights, duties, liabilities, and responsibilities depend on the concept of a conscious, self-reliant and free-willed person—the cognitively necessary concept of an individual can be challenged in biological terms. This is due to the fact that all species of a higher order, such as mammals, birds, insects or fish, have to be understood as complex systems of living entities (cells, bacteria …) which need to interact symbiotically if those smaller entities (cells, bacteria …) and the higher system they constitute want to stay alive. This holds true for all living systems of a higher order, be it a rabbit, a bee, a wolf, or indeed homo sapiens. Another example of this would be the complex root systems of forests. We now know that trees not only live and thrive in symbiosis with mycorrhizae, but actually use that symbiotic network to communicate with other trees to protect each other’s survival (Hachtel 1998).
 
12
A good example is Wincor Nixdorf. With its branch of automated teller machines, it competed on a global level with only two rivals, Diebold and NCR. After years of fruitless effort to step up from global number three to either number two or number one, Wincor decided in 2015/2016 to sell its business to the market’s number two, Diebold, as they believed that remaining number three would not suffice to reach the planned turnover targets that could sustain Wincor in the long run.
 
13
The micro-level concerns the relationships between companies and people (employees, customers, suppliers, and business partners); the meso-level concerns the relations between companies (suppliers, clients, or competitors); the macro-level covers the relationships between companies and the systems surrounding them, be they external stakeholders, politics, or society at large; and the supra-level concerns the relations between companies and the environment.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Ayres, R., & Warr, B. (2009). The economic growth engine: How energy and work drive material prosperity. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRef Ayres, R., & Warr, B. (2009). The economic growth engine: How energy and work drive material prosperity. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bauer, J. (2006). Prinzip Menschlichkeit: Warum wir von Natur aus kooperieren. Munich: Heyne (2008). Bauer, J. (2006). Prinzip Menschlichkeit: Warum wir von Natur aus kooperieren. Munich: Heyne (2008).
Zurück zum Zitat Bauer, J. (2008). Das kooperative Gen. Abschied vom Darwinismus. Hamburg: Hoffmann & Campe. Bauer, J. (2008). Das kooperative Gen. Abschied vom Darwinismus. Hamburg: Hoffmann & Campe.
Zurück zum Zitat Bourdieu, P. (1982). Die feinen Unterschiede. Kritik der gesellschaftlichen Urteilskraft. Frankfurt/Main: Suhrkamp (4th ed., 1987). Bourdieu, P. (1982). Die feinen Unterschiede. Kritik der gesellschaftlichen Urteilskraft. Frankfurt/Main: Suhrkamp (4th ed., 1987).
Zurück zum Zitat Braungart, M., & McDonough, W. (2002). Cradle to cradle: Remaking the way we make things. New York: North Point Press. Braungart, M., & McDonough, W. (2002). Cradle to cradle: Remaking the way we make things. New York: North Point Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Braungart, M., & McDonough, W. (2013). The upcycle. Beyond sustainability – Designing for abundance. New York: Melcher/North Point Press [deutsch: Intelligente Verschwendung. The Ubcycle: Auf dem Weg in eine neue Überflussgesellschaft. (oekom) Munich]. Braungart, M., & McDonough, W. (2013). The upcycle. Beyond sustainability – Designing for abundance. New York: Melcher/North Point Press [deutsch: Intelligente Verschwendung. The Ubcycle: Auf dem Weg in eine neue Überflussgesellschaft. (oekom) Munich].
Zurück zum Zitat Bryan, L., & Farrell, D. (1996). Market unbound: Unleashing global capitalism. New York: Wiley. Bryan, L., & Farrell, D. (1996). Market unbound: Unleashing global capitalism. New York: Wiley.
Zurück zum Zitat Brynjolfsson, E., & McAfee, A. (2014). The second machine age. Work, progress, and prosperity in a time of brilliant technologies. New York: Norton. Brynjolfsson, E., & McAfee, A. (2014). The second machine age. Work, progress, and prosperity in a time of brilliant technologies. New York: Norton.
Zurück zum Zitat Capra, F. (1996). The web of life: A new scientific understanding of living systems. New York: Anchor/Random House [deutsch: Lebensnetz. Ein neues Verständnis der lebendigen Welt. (Schwerz) Bern, Munich, Vienna]. Capra, F. (1996). The web of life: A new scientific understanding of living systems. New York: Anchor/Random House [deutsch: Lebensnetz. Ein neues Verständnis der lebendigen Welt. (Schwerz) Bern, Munich, Vienna].
Zurück zum Zitat Capra, F., & Luisi, P. L. (2014). The systems view of life. A unifiying vision (3rd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge Univeristy Press.CrossRef Capra, F., & Luisi, P. L. (2014). The systems view of life. A unifiying vision (3rd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge Univeristy Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dawes, R. H. (1980): Social dilemmas. Annual Review of Psychology, 31, 163–193. Dawes, R. H. (1980): Social dilemmas. Annual Review of Psychology, 31, 163–193.
Zurück zum Zitat Dawkins, R. (1976). The selfish gene. Oxford: Oxford University Press (30th Anniversary ed., 2006). Dawkins, R. (1976). The selfish gene. Oxford: Oxford University Press (30th Anniversary ed., 2006).
Zurück zum Zitat de Waal, F. (2005). Our inner ape. A leading primatologist explains why we are who we are. New York: Riverhead. de Waal, F. (2005). Our inner ape. A leading primatologist explains why we are who we are. New York: Riverhead.
Zurück zum Zitat Derman, E. (2011). Models behaving badly. Why confusing illusion with reality can lead to disaster, on wall street and in life. New York: Free Press. Derman, E. (2011). Models behaving badly. Why confusing illusion with reality can lead to disaster, on wall street and in life. New York: Free Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Dierksmeier, C. (2016). Reframing economic ethics. The philosophical foundations of humanistic management. New York: Palgrave MacMillan. Dierksmeier, C. (2016). Reframing economic ethics. The philosophical foundations of humanistic management. New York: Palgrave MacMillan.
Zurück zum Zitat Duerr, H.-P. (1988). Der Mythos vom Zivilisationsprozeß – Vol. 1: Nacktheit und Scham. Frankfurt/Main: Suhrkamp. Duerr, H.-P. (1988). Der Mythos vom Zivilisationsprozeß – Vol. 1: Nacktheit und Scham. Frankfurt/Main: Suhrkamp.
Zurück zum Zitat Duhem, P. (1908). Ziel und Struktur der Physikalischen Theorien. Hamburg: Meiner (1978). Duhem, P. (1908). Ziel und Struktur der Physikalischen Theorien. Hamburg: Meiner (1978).
Zurück zum Zitat Elegido, J. (2009). Business education and erosion of character. African Journal of Business Ethics, 4(1), 16–24. Elegido, J. (2009). Business education and erosion of character. African Journal of Business Ethics, 4(1), 16–24.
Zurück zum Zitat Elias, N. (1939). Über den Prozeß der Zivilisation. Soziogenetische und psychogenetische Untersuchungen. Frankfurt/Main: Suhrkamp (1976). Elias, N. (1939). Über den Prozeß der Zivilisation. Soziogenetische und psychogenetische Untersuchungen. Frankfurt/Main: Suhrkamp (1976).
Zurück zum Zitat Erhard, W.H., Jensen, M.W., & Zaffron, S. (2009). A new model of integrity: An actionable pathway to trust, productivity and value (PDF File of Keynote Slides). Barbados Group Working Paper No. 07-01, Harvard NOM Working Paper No. 07-01, 1st IESE Conference on “Humanizing the Firm and the Management Profession” Presentation. Retrieved June 16, 2016, from http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=932255 Erhard, W.H., Jensen, M.W., & Zaffron, S. (2009). A new model of integrity: An actionable pathway to trust, productivity and value (PDF File of Keynote Slides). Barbados Group Working Paper No. 07-01, Harvard NOM Working Paper No. 07-01, 1st IESE Conference on “Humanizing the Firm and the Management Profession” Presentation. Retrieved June 16, 2016, from http://​papers.​ssrn.​com/​sol3/​papers.​cfm?​abstract_​id=​932255
Zurück zum Zitat Erhard, W.H., Jensen, M.W., Zaffron, S. (2016). Integrity: A positive model that incorporates the normative phenomena of morality, ethics, and legality – Abgridged. Harvard Business School NOM Working Paper No. 10-061, Barbados Group Working Paper No. 10-01, Simon School of Business Working Paper No. 10-07. Retrieved June 16, 2016, from http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1542759 Erhard, W.H., Jensen, M.W., Zaffron, S. (2016). Integrity: A positive model that incorporates the normative phenomena of morality, ethics, and legality – Abgridged. Harvard Business School NOM Working Paper No. 10-061, Barbados Group Working Paper No. 10-01, Simon School of Business Working Paper No. 10-07. Retrieved June 16, 2016, from http://​papers.​ssrn.​com/​sol3/​papers.​cfm?​abstract_​id=​1542759
Zurück zum Zitat Feyerabend, P. (1975). Against method: Outline of an anarchist theory of knowledge. London: Verso (4th ed., 2010). Feyerabend, P. (1975). Against method: Outline of an anarchist theory of knowledge. London: Verso (4th ed., 2010).
Zurück zum Zitat Foster, R., & Kaplan, S. (2002). Creative destruction. Why companies that are built to last underperform the market – and how to successfully transform them. New York: Currency. Foster, R., & Kaplan, S. (2002). Creative destruction. Why companies that are built to last underperform the market – and how to successfully transform them. New York: Currency.
Zurück zum Zitat Frank, R. H. (2011). The Darwin economy. Liberty, competition, and the common good. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Frank, R. H. (2011). The Darwin economy. Liberty, competition, and the common good. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Gilbert, C. Eyring, M., & Foster, R.N. (2013). Duale transformation. Harvard Business Manager, S. 34–44. Gilbert, C. Eyring, M., & Foster, R.N. (2013). Duale transformation. Harvard Business Manager, S. 34–44.
Zurück zum Zitat Glauner, F. (2016). Future viability, business models, and values. Strategy, business management and economy in disruptive markets. Heidelberg: Springer. Glauner, F. (2016). Future viability, business models, and values. Strategy, business management and economy in disruptive markets. Heidelberg: Springer.
Zurück zum Zitat Glauner, F. (2017a). Values cockpits. On measuring and steering corporate cultures. Berlin: Springer. Glauner, F. (2017a). Values cockpits. On measuring and steering corporate cultures. Berlin: Springer.
Zurück zum Zitat Glauner, F. (2017b). Compliance, global ethos and corporate wisdom: Values strategies as an increasingly critical competitive advantage. In J. D. Rendtorff (Ed.), Perspectives on philosophy of management and business ethics, series ethical economy. Studies in economic ethics and philosophy 51 (pp. 121–137). Berlin: Springer. Glauner, F. (2017b). Compliance, global ethos and corporate wisdom: Values strategies as an increasingly critical competitive advantage. In J. D. Rendtorff (Ed.), Perspectives on philosophy of management and business ethics, series ethical economy. Studies in economic ethics and philosophy 51 (pp. 121–137). Berlin: Springer.
Zurück zum Zitat Glauner, F. (2018). Redefining economics: Why sharing value is not enough. Accepted to be published in the Competitiveness Review Special Issue Call “Creating Shared Value: Restoring the Legitimacy of Business and Advancing Competitiveness”. Glauner, F. (2018). Redefining economics: Why sharing value is not enough. Accepted to be published in the Competitiveness Review Special Issue Call “Creating Shared Value: Restoring the Legitimacy of Business and Advancing Competitiveness”.
Zurück zum Zitat Harari, Y. N. (2015). Sapiens. A brief history of humankind. New York: HarperColins. Harari, Y. N. (2015). Sapiens. A brief history of humankind. New York: HarperColins.
Zurück zum Zitat Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behaviour, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), 305–360.CrossRef Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behaviour, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), 305–360.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1994). The nature of man. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 7(2), 4–19.CrossRef Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1994). The nature of man. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 7(2), 4–19.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kaplan, R. S., & Norton, D. P. (1996). The balanced scorecard: Translating strategy into action. Boston, MA: Harvard Business Review Press. Kaplan, R. S., & Norton, D. P. (1996). The balanced scorecard: Translating strategy into action. Boston, MA: Harvard Business Review Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Kegel, B. (2015). Die Herrscher der Welt. Wie Mikroben unser Leben bestimmen. Cologne: Dumont. Kegel, B. (2015). Die Herrscher der Welt. Wie Mikroben unser Leben bestimmen. Cologne: Dumont.
Zurück zum Zitat Kuhn, T.S. (1962). The structure of scientific revolutions (50th Anniversary Edition). Chicago: University of Chicago (2012). Kuhn, T.S. (1962). The structure of scientific revolutions (50th Anniversary Edition). Chicago: University of Chicago (2012).
Zurück zum Zitat Küng, H. (2012). Handbuch Weltethos. Eine vision und ihre Umsetzung. Munich: Pieper. Küng, H. (2012). Handbuch Weltethos. Eine vision und ihre Umsetzung. Munich: Pieper.
Zurück zum Zitat Lobe, A. (2016, April 29). Wird Facebook Donald Trump verhindern? Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung, 17. Lobe, A. (2016, April 29). Wird Facebook Donald Trump verhindern? Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung, 17.
Zurück zum Zitat Miller, D. T. (1999). The norm of self-interest. American Psychologist, 54(12), 1053–1060.CrossRef Miller, D. T. (1999). The norm of self-interest. American Psychologist, 54(12), 1053–1060.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Müller-Stewens, G., & Lechner, C. (2003). Strategisches Management. Wie strategische Initiativen zum Wandel führen. Der St. Galler General Management Navigator. Stuttgart: Schaeffer-Poeschel (2nd revised ed.). Müller-Stewens, G., & Lechner, C. (2003). Strategisches Management. Wie strategische Initiativen zum Wandel führen. Der St. Galler General Management Navigator. Stuttgart: Schaeffer-Poeschel (2nd revised ed.).
Zurück zum Zitat Ostrom, E. (2000). Social capital: A fad or a fundamental concept. In D. Partha & I. Serageldin (Eds.), Social capital. A multifaceted perspective (pp. 172–214). Washington: The World Bank. Ostrom, E. (2000). Social capital: A fad or a fundamental concept. In D. Partha & I. Serageldin (Eds.), Social capital. A multifaceted perspective (pp. 172–214). Washington: The World Bank.
Zurück zum Zitat Otto, K.-S., Nolting, U., & Bässler, C. (2007). Evolutionsmangagement. Von der Natur lernen: Unternehmen entwicklen und langfristig steuern. München: Hanser. Otto, K.-S., Nolting, U., & Bässler, C. (2007). Evolutionsmangagement. Von der Natur lernen: Unternehmen entwicklen und langfristig steuern. München: Hanser.
Zurück zum Zitat Pauli, G. (2010). The blue economy. 10 years, 100 innovations, 100 million jobs. Taos, NM: Paradigm. Pauli, G. (2010). The blue economy. 10 years, 100 innovations, 100 million jobs. Taos, NM: Paradigm.
Zurück zum Zitat Pirson, M. (2017). Humanistic management: Protecting dignity and promoting well-being. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Pirson, M. (2017). Humanistic management: Protecting dignity and promoting well-being. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Popper, K.R. (1935). Die Logik der Forschung. Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck) (8th ed., 1984). Popper, K.R. (1935). Die Logik der Forschung. Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck) (8th ed., 1984).
Zurück zum Zitat Porter, M. E. (1980). Competitive strategy: Techniques for analyzing industries and competitors. New York: Free Press. Porter, M. E. (1980). Competitive strategy: Techniques for analyzing industries and competitors. New York: Free Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). Capitalism, socialism, and democracy (p. 1994). London: Routledge. Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). Capitalism, socialism, and democracy (p. 1994). London: Routledge.
Zurück zum Zitat Searle, J.R. (1969). Speech acts. An essay in the philosophy of language. London: Cambridge University Press (11th ed., 1984). Searle, J.R. (1969). Speech acts. An essay in the philosophy of language. London: Cambridge University Press (11th ed., 1984).
Zurück zum Zitat Searle, J. R. (1995). The construction of social reality. New York: The Free Press. Searle, J. R. (1995). The construction of social reality. New York: The Free Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Searle, J. R. (2010). Making the social reality. The structure of human civilization. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRef Searle, J. R. (2010). Making the social reality. The structure of human civilization. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Seba, T. (2006). Winners take all. The 9 fundamental rules of high tech strategy. San Francisco, CA. Seba, T. (2006). Winners take all. The 9 fundamental rules of high tech strategy. San Francisco, CA.
Zurück zum Zitat Seba, T. (2014). Clean disruption of energy and transportation. How Silicon Valley will make oil, nuclear, natural gas, coal, electric utilities and conventional cars obsolete by 2030. San Francisco, CA. Seba, T. (2014). Clean disruption of energy and transportation. How Silicon Valley will make oil, nuclear, natural gas, coal, electric utilities and conventional cars obsolete by 2030. San Francisco, CA.
Zurück zum Zitat Sennett, R. (2006). The culture of the new capitalism. New Haven: Yale University Press. Sennett, R. (2006). The culture of the new capitalism. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Simon, H. A. (1985). Human nature in politics: The dialogue of psychology with political science. The American Political Science Review, 79(2), 293–304.CrossRef Simon, H. A. (1985). Human nature in politics: The dialogue of psychology with political science. The American Political Science Review, 79(2), 293–304.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stuchtey, M., Enkvist, P.-A., & Zumwinkel, K. (2016). A good disruption. Redefining growth in the twenty-first century. London: Bloomsbury. Stuchtey, M., Enkvist, P.-A., & Zumwinkel, K. (2016). A good disruption. Redefining growth in the twenty-first century. London: Bloomsbury.
Zurück zum Zitat Taleb, N. N. (2008). Der Schwarze Schwan. Die Macht höchst unwahrscheinlicher Ereignisse. München: Hanser.CrossRef Taleb, N. N. (2008). Der Schwarze Schwan. Die Macht höchst unwahrscheinlicher Ereignisse. München: Hanser.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tetlock, P. E. (2000). Cognitive biases and organizational correctives: Do both disease and cure depend on the politics of the beholder? Administrative Science Quarterly, 45, 293–329.CrossRef Tetlock, P. E. (2000). Cognitive biases and organizational correctives: Do both disease and cure depend on the politics of the beholder? Administrative Science Quarterly, 45, 293–329.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Van Orman Quine, W. (1960). Word and object. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press. Van Orman Quine, W. (1960). Word and object. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Van Orman Quine, W. (1969). Ontological relativity and other essays. New York: Columbia University Press. Van Orman Quine, W. (1969). Ontological relativity and other essays. New York: Columbia University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat von Foerster, H. (1972). Bemerkungen zu einer Epistemologie des Lebendigen. In ders. (1993) Wissen und Gewissen. Versuch einer Brücke. Frankfurt/Main: Suhrkamp (8th ed., 2011, pp. 116–133). von Foerster, H. (1972). Bemerkungen zu einer Epistemologie des Lebendigen. In ders. (1993) Wissen und Gewissen. Versuch einer Brücke. Frankfurt/Main: Suhrkamp (8th ed., 2011, pp. 116–133).
Zurück zum Zitat von Foerster, H. (1987). Kybernetik. In idem (1993) Wissen und Gewissen. Versuch einer Brücke. Frankfurt/Main: Suhrkamp (8th ed., 2011, pp. 72–76). von Foerster, H. (1987). Kybernetik. In idem (1993) Wissen und Gewissen. Versuch einer Brücke. Frankfurt/Main: Suhrkamp (8th ed., 2011, pp. 72–76).
Zurück zum Zitat von Glasersfeld, E. (1995). Radikaler Konstruktivismus. Ideen, Ergebnisse, Probleme. Frankfurt/Main: Suhrkamp (7th ed., 2011). von Glasersfeld, E. (1995). Radikaler Konstruktivismus. Ideen, Ergebnisse, Probleme. Frankfurt/Main: Suhrkamp (7th ed., 2011).
Zurück zum Zitat von Weizsäcker, E.U., Lovins, A.B., & Lovins, L.H. (1995). Faktor Vier. Doppelter Wohlstand – halbierter Verbrauch. Der neue Bericht an den Club of Rome München: Droemer Knaur (Engl. Factor four: Doubling wealth, halving resource use). The new report to the Club of Rome. London: Earthscan (1998). von Weizsäcker, E.U., Lovins, A.B., & Lovins, L.H. (1995). Faktor Vier. Doppelter Wohlstand – halbierter Verbrauch. Der neue Bericht an den Club of Rome München: Droemer Knaur (Engl. Factor four: Doubling wealth, halving resource use). The new report to the Club of Rome. London: Earthscan (1998).
Zurück zum Zitat Watts, R. G. (2007). Global warming and the future of the earth. Synthesis lectures on energy and the environment: Technology, science, and society #1. San Rafael, CA: Morgan & Claypool. Watts, R. G. (2007). Global warming and the future of the earth. Synthesis lectures on energy and the environment: Technology, science, and society #1. San Rafael, CA: Morgan & Claypool.
Zurück zum Zitat Wilson, E.O. (1992). The diversity of life. London: Penguin (2001). Wilson, E.O. (1992). The diversity of life. London: Penguin (2001).
Metadaten
Titel
Innovation, Business Models, and Catastrophe: Reframing the Mental Model for Innovation Management
verfasst von
Friedrich Glauner
Copyright-Jahr
2018
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-93629-1_7

Premium Partner