Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Public Choice 3-4/2015

01.09.2015

From Caesar to Tacitus: changes in early Germanic governance circa 50 BC-50 AD

verfasst von: Andrew T. Young

Erschienen in: Public Choice | Ausgabe 3-4/2015

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Julius Caesar and Cornelius Tacitus provide characterizations of early Germanic (barbarian) society around, respectively, 50 BC and 50 AD. The earlier date corresponds to expansion of Rome to the Rhine and Danube. During the subsequent century Germanic governance institutions changed in a number of ways. In particular, (1) temporary military commanders elected from the nobility gave way to standing retinues under the leadership of professional commanders, (2) public assemblies met more frequently and regularly, (3) councils made up of nobility gained agenda control in the assemblies, and (4) these councils relinquished their control over the allocations of land. I account for these constitutional exchanges in light of Rome’s encroachment. This encroachment brought new sources of wealth as well as constraints on the expansion of Germans into new lands. Incentives favored a reallocation of resources away from pastoralism and towards both sedentary farming and raids across the frontier.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
Other scholars have insisted on explorations of how government (just or not) actually emerged from anarchy (e.g., de Jassay 1985, 1990, 1997; Mueller 1988).
 
2
Other researchers have documented episodes of existing governments encroaching upon previously anarchic areas of society. For example, Benson (1990, 1994, 1998) and Ekelund and Dorton (2003) study the evolution of English law enforcement and the role of the state. For an excellent survey of the economics of anarchy, both theoretical and empirical, see Powell and Stringham (2009).
 
3
By government I mean a monopoly on coercion that functions as the final arbiter of disputes.
 
4
Demsetz’s (1967) work on the emergence of property rights (or lack thereof) in different Native American populations was early and seminal. See Stringham (2015) for a discussion of a number of examples of emergent private governance and citations to numerous related studies.
 
5
Even when Evans-Pritchard (1947 [1940]) made his classic observations of the Nuer people, centered in southern Sudan, they were in the midst of (or closely surrounded by) British, Egyptian, and Ethiopian political structures.
 
6
An exception to this may be the laboratory. Experimental studies document norms and other patterns of human interactions arising from constructed states of nature (e.g., Powell and Wilson 2008; Kimbrough et al. 2010; Smith et al. 2012). However, the participants in these experiments all have government-based institutional templates ready in hand.
 
7
The details in Tacitus’ Germania may be based partly on observations up to about 100 AD; more on this below.
 
8
Most of Germania’s inhabitants spoke languages belonging to the Germanic branch of the Indo-European language family. That branch broke off from what linguists refer to as the Proto-Indo-European (PIE) language around 3000 BC, as did the Italic and Celtic branches. The Germanic branch includes not only modern German but also, among others, English, Norwegian, Danish, Swedish, and Flemish. See Anthony (2007) for a discussion of the reconstruction of the PIE language and efforts to locate its speakers temporally and geographically.
 
9
Arminius double-crossed the Roman general Publius Quinctilius Varus, leading him into a narrow path between high ground to the south and bogs to the north. After 3 days of battle nearly all of the Romans were slaughtered and Varus committed suicide. So the story goes, Caesar Augustus “was so beside himself that for months he let his hair and beard grow and sometimes hit his head against the doors crying out, ‘Quinctilius Varus! Give me back my legions!” (Suetonius 2011, p. 62). This appealingly romantic explanation for Rome’s halt at the Rhine was put to great (and unfortunate) use by 19th and 20th century German nationalists (Krebs 2011).
 
10
The general’s name actually was Julius but he is known to history by the honorific he posthumously received in acknowledgement of his military victories over Germanic barbarians.
 
11
See Todd (2004, p. 49) on the paucity of wealth to be extracted: “There were no deposits of precious metals, no great expanses of cornfields. [Germania’s] major resources were in manpower and these, for the greater part, were ranged against Rome.” See Wells (1999, p. 93) on the difficulties involved in further conquest: “The communities in these lands showed nothing of the centralization of manufacturing, trade, and […] collection and storage of food and other goods. Hence the Romans could not acquire the sources of supply they needed in the field”.
 
12
The analysis that follows, then, is in the spirit of Demsetz (1967). He accounts for institutional change amongst the Montages tribe of Native Americans as means to internalize innovations to the economic environment.
 
13
In this sense, this paper is related to Kurrild-Klitgaard and Svendsen’s (2003) and Baker and Bulte’s (2010) studies of Vikings (circa 800 AD to 1100 AD). They argue that the agglomeration of Viking groups was part of a transition of those groups from roving to stationary bandits (Olson 1993). In Young (2015) I document how a confederacy of fourth century Germanic barbarian groups (the Visigoths) made a similar transition in the fifth century (becoming the Visigothic Kingdom). I argue that the transition involved the provision of different collective goods as well as the redefinition of group membership and interests.
Also, the Icelandic Free State ended in 1262 AD when Iceland was absorbed formally into the kingdom of Norway. The institutional changes from Caesar to Tacitus occurred without a serious threat of Roman subjugation.
 
14
The initial invasion appears to have consisted of 15,000 Germanic people.
 
15
As we shall see below (in Sect. 3) by the middle of the first century AD the role of Germanic kings as violent entrepreneurs (or formeteurs: Congleton 2011b) has grown in importance. Note that proximate to the reference to brigandage Caesar refers to a dux while rex is reserved for a small number specific individuals mentioned, including Ariovistus who had been “saluted as king and friend by the Senate” in 59 BC, the year of Caesar’s consulship (Caesar, Book I, p. 55). Tacitus, as we shall see, is clearer regarding his use of dux versus rex and the difference between the two.
 
16
Caesar, when referring to a political rather than kindred unit, uses the word pagus, translated as: “a village or country district; a canton” (University of Notre Dame online Latin to English dictionary: http://​www.​archives.​nd.​edu/​cgi-bin/​lookup.​pl?​stem=​pagus Accessed May 5 2014). He is referring to a small unit, a tribe or clan. This is the interpretation of Thompson (1965 Chap. 1, Sect. 2). Caesar also attributes to the Suebi “a hundred cantons from which they draw one thousand armed men yearly.” A pagus was small relative to what was represented by a king such as Ariovistus or at the council of principes at which such a rex would be elected.
 
17
References to the Germania text generally will be from the (1970) Penguin edition; I have used the (1869) Macmillan and Co. edition to confirm the original Latin for key words.
 
18
Aside from nobles (principes), Caesar’s earlier account does not elaborate on other distinctions of rank or class amongst the Germans. However, similar degrees of social stratification likely existed circa 50 BC. Caesar does discuss the “two classes of persons of definite account and dignity” amongst the Gauls and the fact that “[a]s for the common folk, they are treated almost as slaves” (Caesar book VI, p. 335). The two classes of distinction are druids and knights. The former were a class of priests who also acted as judges “in almost all disputes, public and private” and were excused from military service (Caesar book VI, p. 337). Knights, as the term would suggest, comprised the warrior class.
 
19
These horses remained “undefiled by any toil in the service of man” (Tacitus Chap. 9, p. 108). They were maintained continuously as sources of public goods provided in the form of insights regarding the future.
 
20
The economic theory of clubs is rooted in the work of Buchanan (1965). Sandler and Tschirhart (1997) survey the subsequent literature.
 
21
Clubs with a religious basis often rely on stigmas and requirements of sacrifice to ferret out potential defectors (e.g., Berman and Laitin 2008; Iannaconne 1992).
 
22
In Young (2015), I provide a case study of how a confederacy of Gothic retinues, initially under the leadership of Alaric I, eventually became the Visigothic Kingdom in Gaul and the Iberian Peninsula.
 
23
Leeson (2007b, 2009a, 2009b) elaborates on eighteenth century pirate outfits as constitutionalized roving bandits. Leeson has the benefit of much better documentation of the workings of piratical governance (including formal constitutions (i.e., the “pirate code”).
 
24
“With the replacement of tribal kings by kings of migrating armies, the representatives of the new kingship had to take on rights and responsibilities of the older form of rule” (Wolfram 1997, pp. 17–18). Wolfram is referring to the barbarian migrations of the fourth and fifth centuries, but his comments characterize where the evolution of Germanic kingship from Caesar to Tacitus ultimately was heading.
 
25
Smith (1928, p. 32) notes that what Tacitus observed is echoed by later Germanic law codes: “Besides the composition obtained by suit in court or included in such composition, there was definite smaller sum to be paid to the people or to the prince or king, which was called ‘peace money,’ in the Anglo Saxon wite, and in Danish England ‘law breach.” Smith (pp. 36–37) also notes that the earliest written Germanic laws indicate that a “law speaker” or a “wise man” would propose judgments to an assembly and receive a share—e.g., one ninth amongst the Bavarians and Swabians—of any imposed fine[;] the lawyer “seems to have been chosen by the people from some prominent and distinguished family”.
 
26
These names are found in various chapters of the Germania. Examples include the Cherusci, the Chatti, the Frisii, the Langobardi, and the Teutoni. See Heather (2006, map 2, pp. 50–51) for a sense of where literary sources geographically locate these tribes.
 
27
Consistent with this assertion is the fact that the public assembly (i.e., a formal meeting of all adult freemen) is also characteristic of later Germanic groups (for examples, the placitum of the Franks and Lombards; the conventus of the Burgundians; the gemot of the Anglo-Saxons; the thing of the Scandinavians) (Wickham 2009, pp. 100–101; Barnwell and Mostert 2003).
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Acemoglu, D. (2003). Why not a political Coase theorem? social conflict, commitment, and politics. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31, 620–652.CrossRef Acemoglu, D. (2003). Why not a political Coase theorem? social conflict, commitment, and politics. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31, 620–652.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2000). Why did the West extend the franchise? Democracy, inequality, and growth in historical perspective. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, 1167–1199.CrossRefMATH Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2000). Why did the West extend the franchise? Democracy, inequality, and growth in historical perspective. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, 1167–1199.CrossRefMATH
Zurück zum Zitat Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). A theory of political transitions. American Economic Review, 91, 938–963.CrossRef Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). A theory of political transitions. American Economic Review, 91, 938–963.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2008). Persistence of power, elites, and institutions. American Economic Review, 98, 267–293.CrossRef Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2008). Persistence of power, elites, and institutions. American Economic Review, 98, 267–293.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Anderson, T. L., & Hill, P. J. (2004). The not so wild, wild west: Property rights on the frontier. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Anderson, T. L., & Hill, P. J. (2004). The not so wild, wild west: Property rights on the frontier. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Anthony, D. W. (2007). The horse, the wheel, and language: How bronze-age riders from the Eurasian steppes shaped the modern world. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Anthony, D. W. (2007). The horse, the wheel, and language: How bronze-age riders from the Eurasian steppes shaped the modern world. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Baker, M. J., & Bulte, E. H. (2010). Kings and Vikings: On the dynamics of competitive agglomeration. Economics of Governance, 11, 207–227.CrossRef Baker, M. J., & Bulte, E. H. (2010). Kings and Vikings: On the dynamics of competitive agglomeration. Economics of Governance, 11, 207–227.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Barnwell, P. S., & Mostert, M. (Eds.). (2003). Political assemblies in the earlier middle ages. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Barnwell, P. S., & Mostert, M. (Eds.). (2003). Political assemblies in the earlier middle ages. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Benson, B. L. (1990). The enterprise of law: Justice without the state. San Francisco: Pacific Research Institute for Public Policy. Benson, B. L. (1990). The enterprise of law: Justice without the state. San Francisco: Pacific Research Institute for Public Policy.
Zurück zum Zitat Benson, B. L. (1994). Are public goods really common pools? considerations of the evolution of policing and highways in England. Economic Inquiry, 32, 249–271.CrossRef Benson, B. L. (1994). Are public goods really common pools? considerations of the evolution of policing and highways in England. Economic Inquiry, 32, 249–271.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Benson, B. L. (1998). To serve and protect: Privatization and community in criminal justice. New York: New York University Press. Benson, B. L. (1998). To serve and protect: Privatization and community in criminal justice. New York: New York University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Berman, E. (2009). Radical, religious, and violent: The new economics of terrorism. Cambridge: MIT Press. Berman, E. (2009). Radical, religious, and violent: The new economics of terrorism. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Berman, E., & Laitin, D. (2008). Religion, terrorism, and public goods: Testing the club model. Journal of Public Economics, 98, 1942–1967.CrossRef Berman, E., & Laitin, D. (2008). Religion, terrorism, and public goods: Testing the club model. Journal of Public Economics, 98, 1942–1967.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Buchanan, J. M. (1965). An economic theory of clubs. Economica, 32, 1–14.CrossRef Buchanan, J. M. (1965). An economic theory of clubs. Economica, 32, 1–14.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Buchanan, J. M. (1975). The limits of liberty. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Buchanan, J. M. (1975). The limits of liberty. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund. Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.
Zurück zum Zitat Burns, T. S. (2003). Rome and the barbarians. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press. Burns, T. S. (2003). Rome and the barbarians. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Bury, J. B. (1967). The invasion of Europe by the barbarians. New York: W. W. Norton and Co. Bury, J. B. (1967). The invasion of Europe by the barbarians. New York: W. W. Norton and Co.
Zurück zum Zitat Caesar, J. (1939). In H. J. Edward (Ed.), The Gallic war. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Caesar, J. (1939). In H. J. Edward (Ed.), The Gallic war. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Clay, K. (1997). Trade, institutions, and credit. Explorations in Economic History, 34, 495–521.CrossRef Clay, K. (1997). Trade, institutions, and credit. Explorations in Economic History, 34, 495–521.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Congleton, R. D. (2001). On the durability of king and council: The continuum between dictatorship and democracy. Constitutional Political Economy, 12, 193–215.CrossRef Congleton, R. D. (2001). On the durability of king and council: The continuum between dictatorship and democracy. Constitutional Political Economy, 12, 193–215.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Congleton, R. D. (2007). From royal to parliamentary rule without revolution: The economics of constitutional exchange within divided governments. European Journal of Political Economy, 23, 261–284.CrossRef Congleton, R. D. (2007). From royal to parliamentary rule without revolution: The economics of constitutional exchange within divided governments. European Journal of Political Economy, 23, 261–284.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Congleton, R. D. (2011a). Perfecting parliament: Constitutional reform, liberalism, and the rise of western democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Congleton, R. D. (2011a). Perfecting parliament: Constitutional reform, liberalism, and the rise of western democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Congleton, R. D. (2011b). Why local government do not maximize profits: On the value-added by the representative institutions of town and city governance. Public Choice, 149, 187–201.CrossRef Congleton, R. D. (2011b). Why local government do not maximize profits: On the value-added by the representative institutions of town and city governance. Public Choice, 149, 187–201.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat De Jasay, A. (1985). The state. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund. De Jasay, A. (1985). The state. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.
Zurück zum Zitat De Jasay, A. (1990). Social contract, free ride: A study of the public goods problem. Oxford: Oxford University Press. De Jasay, A. (1990). Social contract, free ride: A study of the public goods problem. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat De Jasay, A. (1997). Against politics: On government, anarchy, and order. New York: Routledge. De Jasay, A. (1997). Against politics: On government, anarchy, and order. New York: Routledge.
Zurück zum Zitat Demsetz, H. (1967). Toward a theory of property rights. American Economic Review, 57, 347–359. Demsetz, H. (1967). Toward a theory of property rights. American Economic Review, 57, 347–359.
Zurück zum Zitat Dixit, A. K. (2004). Lawlessness and economics: Alternative modes of governance. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Dixit, A. K. (2004). Lawlessness and economics: Alternative modes of governance. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Ekelund, R., & Dorton, C. (2003). Criminal justice institutions as a common pool: The 19th century analysis of Edwin Chadwick. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 50, 271–294.CrossRef Ekelund, R., & Dorton, C. (2003). Criminal justice institutions as a common pool: The 19th century analysis of Edwin Chadwick. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 50, 271–294.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Evans-Pritchard, E. E. (1947). The Nuer. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Evans-Pritchard, E. E. (1947). The Nuer. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Fink, A. (2011). Under what conditions may social contracts arise? evidence from the Hanseatic League. Constitutional Political Economy, 22, 173–190.CrossRef Fink, A. (2011). Under what conditions may social contracts arise? evidence from the Hanseatic League. Constitutional Political Economy, 22, 173–190.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fitzsimons, M. A. (1976). The mind of Tacitus. Review of Politics, 38, 473–493.CrossRef Fitzsimons, M. A. (1976). The mind of Tacitus. Review of Politics, 38, 473–493.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fleck, R. K., & Hanssen, F. A. (2006). The origins of democracy: A model with an application to ancient Greece. Journal of Law and Economics, 49, 115–146.CrossRef Fleck, R. K., & Hanssen, F. A. (2006). The origins of democracy: A model with an application to ancient Greece. Journal of Law and Economics, 49, 115–146.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Friedman, D. (1979). Private creation and enforcement of law: A historical case. Journal of Legal Studies, 8, 399–415.CrossRef Friedman, D. (1979). Private creation and enforcement of law: A historical case. Journal of Legal Studies, 8, 399–415.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Grief, A. (1993). Contract enforceability and economic institutions in early trade: The Maghribi traders’ coalition. American Economic Review, 83, 525–548. Grief, A. (1993). Contract enforceability and economic institutions in early trade: The Maghribi traders’ coalition. American Economic Review, 83, 525–548.
Zurück zum Zitat Grief, A. (2002). Institutions and impersonal exchange: From communal to individual responsibility. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 158, 168–204.CrossRef Grief, A. (2002). Institutions and impersonal exchange: From communal to individual responsibility. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 158, 168–204.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gudeman, A. (1900). The sources of the Germania of Tacitus. Transactions and Proceedings of the American Philological Association, 31, 93–111.CrossRef Gudeman, A. (1900). The sources of the Germania of Tacitus. Transactions and Proceedings of the American Philological Association, 31, 93–111.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hadfield, G. K., & Weingast, B. R. (2013). Legal attributes and the coordination of decentralized collective punishment. Journal of Law and Courts, 1, 3–34.CrossRef Hadfield, G. K., & Weingast, B. R. (2013). Legal attributes and the coordination of decentralized collective punishment. Journal of Law and Courts, 1, 3–34.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Heather, P. (1998). The goths. Oxford: Blackwell Publishing. Heather, P. (1998). The goths. Oxford: Blackwell Publishing.
Zurück zum Zitat Heather, P. (2006). The fall of the Roman Empire: A new history of Rome and the barbarians. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Heather, P. (2006). The fall of the Roman Empire: A new history of Rome and the barbarians. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Heather, P. (2010). Empires and barbarians: The fall of Rome and the birth of Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Heather, P. (2010). Empires and barbarians: The fall of Rome and the birth of Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Iannaconne, L. (1992). Sacrifice and stigma: Reducing free riding in cults, communes, and other collectives. Journal of Political Economy, 100, 271–291.CrossRef Iannaconne, L. (1992). Sacrifice and stigma: Reducing free riding in cults, communes, and other collectives. Journal of Political Economy, 100, 271–291.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kerekes, C. B., & Williamson, C. R. (2012). Discovering law: Hayekian competition in medieval Iceland. Griffith Law Review, 21, 432–447.CrossRef Kerekes, C. B., & Williamson, C. R. (2012). Discovering law: Hayekian competition in medieval Iceland. Griffith Law Review, 21, 432–447.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kimbrough, E. O., Smith, V. L., & Wilson, B. J. (2010). Exchange, theft, and the social formation of property. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 74, 206–229.CrossRef Kimbrough, E. O., Smith, V. L., & Wilson, B. J. (2010). Exchange, theft, and the social formation of property. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 74, 206–229.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Krebs, C. B. (2011). A most dangerous book: Tacitus’s Germania from the Roman Empire to the Reich. New York: W. W. Norton & Co. Krebs, C. B. (2011). A most dangerous book: Tacitus’s Germania from the Roman Empire to the Reich. New York: W. W. Norton & Co.
Zurück zum Zitat Kurrild-Klitgaard, P., & Svendsen, G. T. (2003). Rational bandits: Plunder, public goods, and the Vikings. Public Choice, 117, 255–272.CrossRef Kurrild-Klitgaard, P., & Svendsen, G. T. (2003). Rational bandits: Plunder, public goods, and the Vikings. Public Choice, 117, 255–272.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Landa, J. T. (1994). Trust, ethnicity, and identity. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Landa, J. T. (1994). Trust, ethnicity, and identity. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Leeson, P. T. (2007a). Efficient anarchy. Public Choice, 130, 41–53.CrossRef Leeson, P. T. (2007a). Efficient anarchy. Public Choice, 130, 41–53.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leeson, P. T. (2007b). An-arrgh-chy: The law and economics of pirate organization. Journal of Political Economy, 115, 1049–1094.CrossRef Leeson, P. T. (2007b). An-arrgh-chy: The law and economics of pirate organization. Journal of Political Economy, 115, 1049–1094.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leeson, P. T. (2007c). Better off stateless: Somalia before and after government collapse. Journal of Comparative Economics, 35, 689–710.CrossRef Leeson, P. T. (2007c). Better off stateless: Somalia before and after government collapse. Journal of Comparative Economics, 35, 689–710.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leeson, P. T. (2007d). Trading with bandits. Journal of Law and Economics, 50, 303–321.CrossRef Leeson, P. T. (2007d). Trading with bandits. Journal of Law and Economics, 50, 303–321.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leeson, P. T. (2009a). The calculus of piratical choice: The myth of the myth of the social contract. Public Choice, 139, 443–459.CrossRef Leeson, P. T. (2009a). The calculus of piratical choice: The myth of the myth of the social contract. Public Choice, 139, 443–459.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leeson, P. T. (2009b). The laws of lawlessness. Journal of Legal Studies, 38, 471–503.CrossRef Leeson, P. T. (2009b). The laws of lawlessness. Journal of Legal Studies, 38, 471–503.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leeson, P. T. (2009c). The invisible hook: The hidden economics of pirates. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Leeson, P. T. (2009c). The invisible hook: The hidden economics of pirates. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Leeson, P. T. (2011). Government, clubs, and constitutions. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 80, 301–308.CrossRef Leeson, P. T. (2011). Government, clubs, and constitutions. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 80, 301–308.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leeson, P. T., & Williamson, C. R. (2009). Anarchy and development: An application of the theory of second best. Law and Development Review, 2, 77–96.CrossRef Leeson, P. T., & Williamson, C. R. (2009). Anarchy and development: An application of the theory of second best. Law and Development Review, 2, 77–96.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mueller, D. C. (1988). Anarchy, market, and the state. Southern Economic Journal, 54, 821–830.CrossRef Mueller, D. C. (1988). Anarchy, market, and the state. Southern Economic Journal, 54, 821–830.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nozick, R. (1974). Anarchy, state, and utopia. New York: Basic Books. Nozick, R. (1974). Anarchy, state, and utopia. New York: Basic Books.
Zurück zum Zitat Olson, M. (1993). Dictatorship, democracy, and development. American Political Science Review, 87, 567–576.CrossRef Olson, M. (1993). Dictatorship, democracy, and development. American Political Science Review, 87, 567–576.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Powell, B., Ford, R., & Nowratesh, A. (2008). Somalia after state collapse: Chaos or improvement. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 67, 657–670.CrossRef Powell, B., Ford, R., & Nowratesh, A. (2008). Somalia after state collapse: Chaos or improvement. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 67, 657–670.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Powell, B., & Stringham, E. P. (2009). Public choice and the economic analysis of anarchy. Public Choice, 140, 503–538.CrossRef Powell, B., & Stringham, E. P. (2009). Public choice and the economic analysis of anarchy. Public Choice, 140, 503–538.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Powell, B., & Wilson, B. J. (2008). An experimental investigation of Hobbesian jungles. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 66, 669–686.CrossRef Powell, B., & Wilson, B. J. (2008). An experimental investigation of Hobbesian jungles. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 66, 669–686.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rawls, J. (1999). A theory of justice: Revised edition. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Rawls, J. (1999). A theory of justice: Revised edition. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Sandler, T., & Tschirhart, J. (1997). Club theory: Thirty years later. Public Choice, 93, 335–355.CrossRef Sandler, T., & Tschirhart, J. (1997). Club theory: Thirty years later. Public Choice, 93, 335–355.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Seutonius. (2011). The caesars. (trans: Hurley, D. W.). Cambridge: Hackett Publishing Co. Seutonius. (2011). The caesars. (trans: Hurley, D. W.). Cambridge: Hackett Publishing Co.
Zurück zum Zitat Skarbek, D. (2010). Putting the “con” into constitutions: The economics of prison gangs. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 26, 183–211.CrossRef Skarbek, D. (2010). Putting the “con” into constitutions: The economics of prison gangs. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 26, 183–211.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Skarbek, D. (2011). Governance and prison gangs. American Political Science Review, 105, 702–716.CrossRef Skarbek, D. (2011). Governance and prison gangs. American Political Science Review, 105, 702–716.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Skarbek, D. (2014). The social order of the underworld: How prison gangs govern the American penal system. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRef Skarbek, D. (2014). The social order of the underworld: How prison gangs govern the American penal system. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Smith, M. (1928). The development of European law. New York: Columbia University Press. Smith, M. (1928). The development of European law. New York: Columbia University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Smith, A. C., Skarbek, D. B., & Wilson, B. J. (2012). Anarchy, groups, and conflict: An experiment on the emergence of protective associations. Social Choice and Welfare, 38, 325–353.MathSciNetCrossRef Smith, A. C., Skarbek, D. B., & Wilson, B. J. (2012). Anarchy, groups, and conflict: An experiment on the emergence of protective associations. Social Choice and Welfare, 38, 325–353.MathSciNetCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stringham, E. P. (2002). The emergence of the London stock exchange as a self-policing club. Journal of Private Enterprise, 17, 1–19. Stringham, E. P. (2002). The emergence of the London stock exchange as a self-policing club. Journal of Private Enterprise, 17, 1–19.
Zurück zum Zitat Stringham, E. P. (2003). The extralegal development of securities trading in seventeenth-century Amsterdam. Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 43, 321–344.CrossRef Stringham, E. P. (2003). The extralegal development of securities trading in seventeenth-century Amsterdam. Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 43, 321–344.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stringham, E. P. (2015). Private governance: Creating order in economic and social life. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRef Stringham, E. P. (2015). Private governance: Creating order in economic and social life. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tacitus, G. C. (1869). The Germania of Tacitus. (trans: Church, A. J., Brodribb, W. J.). Cambridge: Macmillan and Co. Tacitus, G. C. (1869). The Germania of Tacitus. (trans: Church, A. J., Brodribb, W. J.). Cambridge: Macmillan and Co.
Zurück zum Zitat Tacitus, G. C. (1970). The agricola and the Germania. (trans: Mattingly, H., Handford, S. A.). London: Penguin Books. Tacitus, G. C. (1970). The agricola and the Germania. (trans: Mattingly, H., Handford, S. A.). London: Penguin Books.
Zurück zum Zitat Thompson, E. A. (1957). Slavery in early Germany. Hermathena, 89, 17–29. Thompson, E. A. (1957). Slavery in early Germany. Hermathena, 89, 17–29.
Zurück zum Zitat Thompson, E. A. (1965). The early Germans. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Thompson, E. A. (1965). The early Germans. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Todd, M. (1987). The northern barbarians: 100 BC–AD 300. Oxford: Basil Blackwell. Todd, M. (1987). The northern barbarians: 100 BC–AD 300. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Zurück zum Zitat Todd, M. (2004). The early Germans. Oxford: Basil Blackwell. Todd, M. (2004). The early Germans. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Zurück zum Zitat Wallace-Hadrill, J. M. (1971). Early Germanic kingship in England and on the continent. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Wallace-Hadrill, J. M. (1971). Early Germanic kingship in England and on the continent. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Wells, P. S. (1999). The barbarians speak: How the conquered peoples shaped Roman Europe. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Wells, P. S. (1999). The barbarians speak: How the conquered peoples shaped Roman Europe. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Wickham, C. (2009). The inheritance of Rome: Illuminating the dark ages 400–1000. London: Penguin Books. Wickham, C. (2009). The inheritance of Rome: Illuminating the dark ages 400–1000. London: Penguin Books.
Zurück zum Zitat Wolfram, H. (1997). The Roman Empire and its Germanic peoples. (trans: Dunlap, T.). Berkley: University of California Press. Wolfram, H. (1997). The Roman Empire and its Germanic peoples. (trans: Dunlap, T.). Berkley: University of California Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Zerbe, R. O, Jr, & Anderson, C. L. (2001). Culture and fairness in the development of institutions in the California gold fields. Journal of Economic History, 61, 114–143.CrossRef Zerbe, R. O, Jr, & Anderson, C. L. (2001). Culture and fairness in the development of institutions in the California gold fields. Journal of Economic History, 61, 114–143.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
From Caesar to Tacitus: changes in early Germanic governance circa 50 BC-50 AD
verfasst von
Andrew T. Young
Publikationsdatum
01.09.2015
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Public Choice / Ausgabe 3-4/2015
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-015-0282-7

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 3-4/2015

Public Choice 3-4/2015 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner