Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 4/2014

01.11.2014 | Original Research

Valuation of tax loss carryforwards

verfasst von: Sudipto Sarkar

Erschienen in: Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting | Ausgabe 4/2014

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Tax loss carryforwards (TLC) are a valuable asset because they can potentially reduce a company’s future tax payments. However, there is often a great deal of uncertainty regarding the probability and timing of these tax savings. We propose a contingent-claim model to value this asset. The value is determined primarily by the size of accumulated carryforwards relative to earnings. We show that, for poorly performing firms with large TLC, (1) the realizable (or fair) value of the tax losses can be significantly smaller than the book value, and (2) the tax losses can account for a significant fraction of the company’s equity value. The model is illustrated by calibrating it to a couple of companies with large carryforwards. Finally, we show how the model can be used to compute the marginal tax rate of a company with carryforwards.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
A large number of firms have accumulated tax losses (Graham 1996a; Miller and Skinner 1998; Bauman and Das 2004); a look at the 2008–2009 annual statements in Compustat reveals that, after deleting firms with missing data, about 75 % of US firms (3,989 out of 5,291) were carrying tax losses. Moreover, tax losses can be significant in terms of magnitude; for instance, tax carryforwards accounted for 30.4 % of total assets in the Bauman and Das (2004) sample of internet firms, while firms in the Miller and Skinner (1998) sample had average deferred tax assets of about 10 % of total assets.
 
2
There are some papers on this topic that use a random walk process to model the earnings stream, e.g., Graham (1996a, b), Shevlin (1990). However, this way of modeling earnings has a significant drawback, i.e., earnings volatility will be significantly under-estimated under the random walk process. This has been pointed out and discussed at some length in a recent paper by Blouin et al. (2010). Given this weakness of the random walk process, it is not surprising that the contingent-claim modeling literature has extensively used the lognormal process for this purpose, including the papers just mentioned above. If we had used the random walk process instead of lognormal, the earnings volatility would have been under-estimated in our model; as a result, both the TLC value and the marginal tax rate (MTR) would have been over-estimated by our model.
 
3
The lognormal process, while a popular way of modeling earning in the Finance literature, is not the only process that can be used to depict the earnings process. In the early Accounting literature, for instance, some papers showed empirical support for the random walk, seasonal random walk with drift and other AR processes (Lev 1983; Lang 1991), although other papers disagreed with this (Lieber et al. 1983; Freeman et al. 1982). Further, Lipe and Kormendi (1994) provided evidence of mean reversion in the earnings process. In the trade-off between tractability and realism, we use the lognormal process that is commonly used in the Finance literature.
 
4
Constant coupon payment is a simplifying assumption for reasons of tractability. In real life, companies tend to reduce debt level when the benefits of debt are smaller (as in the case of large TLC). Reducing debt level will result in higher TLC values, since (as shown later in the paper) a lower leverage ratio increases TLC value, everything else remaining unchanged. On the other hand, companies with large TLC are generally in financial trouble and might not have the necessary cash to buy back debt. Hence the final effect of this is not clear and must be evaluated on a case-by-case basis.
 
5
Even if earnings are negative, the company does not necessarily default on its debt. This assumption might raise the question: where does the money to make coupon payment come from? We make the implicit assumption, as in Leland (1994), Goldstein et al. (2001), etc., that this money comes from shareholders. The argument is as follows. As long as the equity has some value, rational shareholders will keep the company alive even if they have to make out-of-pocket payments (see Leland 1994 for the detailed argument). This argument also has empirical support (Bhagat et al. 2005).
 
6
There is also some statutory progressivity, as pointed out by Graham and Smith (1999, p. 2243), because there are two tax rates: 15 % if profits are below $100,000 and 34 % if profits exceed $100,000. We examine the effect of this statutory progressivity in Sect. 3.2.
 
7
We assume, as in Leland (1994), that cash shortfalls are met by shareholders. Thus, when cash from operations fall short of the company’s coupon obligation (x < c), shareholders keep the company alive by paying the difference. If, however, earnings fall to a sufficiently low level, shareholders will not find it worthwhile to keep the company alive, and the company will file for bankruptcy (as in Leland 1994; Goldstein et al. 2001). This is consistent with actual corporate and shareholder behavior; as Bhagat et al. (2005) show, in loss-making firms it is the equity holders who invest in the company in order to keep it alive.
 
8
In Shevlin’s (1990) study of marginal corporate tax rates with NOL, there are four scenarios (see his Table 1): (a) negative taxable income and zero NOL, (b) negative taxable income and positive NOL, (c) positive taxable income and zero NOL, and (d) positive taxable income and positive NOL. In our model, the corresponding scenarios are (4), (2), (3) and (1) respectively.
 
9
This is because of the continuous-time nature of the model. In a discrete-time model, at year-end the outstanding TLC might be smaller than the taxable profit, in which case there would be a tax liability. In a continuous-time model, tax is paid continuously, but only after L is exhausted; therefore, when the company pays taxes, we must have L = 0. After L is exhausted, the firm is in region (3) and will be paying tax.
 
10
Bonds of companies with interest coverage ratio of over 8.5 (12.5 for smaller and riskier firms) are rated AAA, which is the highest safety rating possible and denotes negligible bankruptcy risk (for bond ratings and associated coverage ratios, please see http://​pages.​stern.​nyu.​edu/​~adamodar/​New_​Home_​Page/​datafile/​ratings.​htm). Therefore, a coverage ratio of 50 should imply negligible bankruptcy risk.
 
11
While it might be doubtful that Office Max’s expected long-term earnings growth rate was actually −5 %, we used this figure for illustration purposes since it is based on publicly available historical data and we did not have any information on expected growth rates.
 
12
A rigorous empirical study could, of course, use market (analyst) expectations, if available, to compare model and market values to examine the usefulness of the model. However, such a study is beyond the scope of our paper.
 
13
Note that our main objective is to value TLC and not the value of the firm’s equity. However, TLC are not traded, making it very difficult to evaluate the model’s performance. Therefore, to check for model’s reliability, we look at model versus market values for equity, since the equity market values are available.
 
14
The particular solution will depend on the function ς(x).
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Baez-Diaz A, Alam P (2013) Tax conformity of earnings and the pricing of accruals. Rev Quant Financ Account 40(3):509–538CrossRef Baez-Diaz A, Alam P (2013) Tax conformity of earnings and the pricing of accruals. Rev Quant Financ Account 40(3):509–538CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bauman MP, Das S (2004) Stock market valuation of deferred tax assets: evidence from internet firms. J Bus Financ Account 31(9–10):1223–1260CrossRef Bauman MP, Das S (2004) Stock market valuation of deferred tax assets: evidence from internet firms. J Bus Financ Account 31(9–10):1223–1260CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bhagat S, Moyen N, Suh I (2005) Investment and internal funds of distressed firms. J Corp Financ 11(3):449–472CrossRef Bhagat S, Moyen N, Suh I (2005) Investment and internal funds of distressed firms. J Corp Financ 11(3):449–472CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Blouin J, Core JE, Guay W (2010) Have the tax benefits of debt been overstated? J Financ Econ 98(2):195–213CrossRef Blouin J, Core JE, Guay W (2010) Have the tax benefits of debt been overstated? J Financ Econ 98(2):195–213CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Broadie M, Chernov M, Sundaresan S (2007) Optimal dent and equity values in the presence of chapter 7 and chapter 11. J Financ 62(3):1341–1377CrossRef Broadie M, Chernov M, Sundaresan S (2007) Optimal dent and equity values in the presence of chapter 7 and chapter 11. J Financ 62(3):1341–1377CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Couch R, Dothan M, Wu W (2012) Interest tax shields: a barrier options approach. Rev Quant Financ Account 39(1):123–146CrossRef Couch R, Dothan M, Wu W (2012) Interest tax shields: a barrier options approach. Rev Quant Financ Account 39(1):123–146CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat De Waegenaere A, Sansing RC, Wielhouwer JL (2003) Valuation of a firm with a tax loss carryover. J Am Tax Assoc 25(S-1): 65–82 De Waegenaere A, Sansing RC, Wielhouwer JL (2003) Valuation of a firm with a tax loss carryover. J Am Tax Assoc 25(S-1): 65–82
Zurück zum Zitat Frank MM, Rego SO (2006) Do managers use the valuation allowance account to manage earnings around certain earnings targets? J Am Tax Assoc 28(1):43–65CrossRef Frank MM, Rego SO (2006) Do managers use the valuation allowance account to manage earnings around certain earnings targets? J Am Tax Assoc 28(1):43–65CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Freeman RN, Ohlson JA, Penman SH (1982) Book rate-of-return and prediction of earnings changes: an empirical investigation. J Account Res 20(2):639–653CrossRef Freeman RN, Ohlson JA, Penman SH (1982) Book rate-of-return and prediction of earnings changes: an empirical investigation. J Account Res 20(2):639–653CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Goldstein RN, Ju N, Leland HE (2001) An EBIT-based model of dynamic capital structure. J Bus 74(4):483–512CrossRef Goldstein RN, Ju N, Leland HE (2001) An EBIT-based model of dynamic capital structure. J Bus 74(4):483–512CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Graham JR (1996a) Debt and the marginal tax rate. J Financ Econ 41(1):41–73CrossRef Graham JR (1996a) Debt and the marginal tax rate. J Financ Econ 41(1):41–73CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Graham JR (1996b) Proxies for the corporate marginal tax rate. J Financ Econ 42(2):187–221CrossRef Graham JR (1996b) Proxies for the corporate marginal tax rate. J Financ Econ 42(2):187–221CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Graham JR, Smith CW (1999) Tax incentives to hedge. J Financ 54(6):2241–2262CrossRef Graham JR, Smith CW (1999) Tax incentives to hedge. J Financ 54(6):2241–2262CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hackbarth D, Mauer DC (2012) Optimal priority structure, capital structure, and investment. Rev Financ Stud 25(3):747–796CrossRef Hackbarth D, Mauer DC (2012) Optimal priority structure, capital structure, and investment. Rev Financ Stud 25(3):747–796CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hackbarth D, Hennessy C, Leland HE (2007) Can the trade-off theory explain debt structure? Rev Financ Stud 20(5):1389–1428CrossRef Hackbarth D, Hennessy C, Leland HE (2007) Can the trade-off theory explain debt structure? Rev Financ Stud 20(5):1389–1428CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hull JC (2006) Options, futures, and other derivatives. Pearson Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River Hull JC (2006) Options, futures, and other derivatives. Pearson Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River
Zurück zum Zitat Jeter D, Chaney P, Daley M (2008) Joint accounting choices: an examination of firms’ adoption strategies for SFAS No. 106 and SFAS No. 109. Rev Quant Financ Account 30(2): 153–185 Jeter D, Chaney P, Daley M (2008) Joint accounting choices: an examination of firms’ adoption strategies for SFAS No. 106 and SFAS No. 109. Rev Quant Financ Account 30(2): 153–185
Zurück zum Zitat Lang M (1991) Time-varying stock price response to earnings induced by uncertainty about the time-series process of earnings. J Account Res 29(2):229–257CrossRef Lang M (1991) Time-varying stock price response to earnings induced by uncertainty about the time-series process of earnings. J Account Res 29(2):229–257CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lee K-J, Shyu DS, Dai M-L (2009) The valuation of information technology investments by real options analysis. Rev Pac Basin Financ Mark Policies 12(4):611–628CrossRef Lee K-J, Shyu DS, Dai M-L (2009) The valuation of information technology investments by real options analysis. Rev Pac Basin Financ Mark Policies 12(4):611–628CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lei ACH, Yick MHY, Lam KSK (2013) Does tax convexity matter for risk? A dynamic study of tax asymmetry and equity beta. Rev Quant Financ Account 41(1):131–147CrossRef Lei ACH, Yick MHY, Lam KSK (2013) Does tax convexity matter for risk? A dynamic study of tax asymmetry and equity beta. Rev Quant Financ Account 41(1):131–147CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leland HE (1994) Corporate debt value, bond covenants, and optimal capital structure. J Financ 49(4):1213–1252CrossRef Leland HE (1994) Corporate debt value, bond covenants, and optimal capital structure. J Financ 49(4):1213–1252CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lev B (1983) Some economic determinants of time-series properties of earnings. J Account Econ 5(1):31–48CrossRef Lev B (1983) Some economic determinants of time-series properties of earnings. J Account Econ 5(1):31–48CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lieber Z, Melnick E, Ronen J (1983) The filtering of transitory noise in earnings numbers. J Forecasting 2(4):331–350CrossRef Lieber Z, Melnick E, Ronen J (1983) The filtering of transitory noise in earnings numbers. J Forecasting 2(4):331–350CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lipe R, Kormendi R (1994) Mean reversion in annual earnings and its implications for security valuation. Rev Quant Financ Account 4(1):27–46CrossRef Lipe R, Kormendi R (1994) Mean reversion in annual earnings and its implications for security valuation. Rev Quant Financ Account 4(1):27–46CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Miller GS, Skinner DJ (1998) Determinants of the valuation allowance for deferred tax assets under SFAS No. 109. Account Rev 73(2): 213–233 Miller GS, Skinner DJ (1998) Determinants of the valuation allowance for deferred tax assets under SFAS No. 109. Account Rev 73(2): 213–233
Zurück zum Zitat Pakes A (1986) Patents as options: some estimates of the value of holding European patent stocks. Econometrica 54(4):755–784CrossRef Pakes A (1986) Patents as options: some estimates of the value of holding European patent stocks. Econometrica 54(4):755–784CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Parrino R, Poteshman AM, Weisbach MS (2005) Measuring investment distortions when risk-averse managers decide whether to undertake risky projects. Financ Manag 34(1):21–60CrossRef Parrino R, Poteshman AM, Weisbach MS (2005) Measuring investment distortions when risk-averse managers decide whether to undertake risky projects. Financ Manag 34(1):21–60CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Purnanandam A (2008) Financial distress and corporate risk management: theory and evidence. J Financ Econ 87(3):706–739CrossRef Purnanandam A (2008) Financial distress and corporate risk management: theory and evidence. J Financ Econ 87(3):706–739CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Schwartz ES (2004) Patents and R&D as real options. Econ Notes 33(1):23–54CrossRef Schwartz ES (2004) Patents and R&D as real options. Econ Notes 33(1):23–54CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Shevlin T (1990) Estimating corporate marginal tax rates with asymmetric tax treatment of gains and losses. J Am Tax Assoc 11(2):51–67 Shevlin T (1990) Estimating corporate marginal tax rates with asymmetric tax treatment of gains and losses. J Am Tax Assoc 11(2):51–67
Zurück zum Zitat Tserlukevich Y (2008) Can real options explain financing behavior? J Financ Econ 89(2):232–252CrossRef Tserlukevich Y (2008) Can real options explain financing behavior? J Financ Econ 89(2):232–252CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Valuation of tax loss carryforwards
verfasst von
Sudipto Sarkar
Publikationsdatum
01.11.2014
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting / Ausgabe 4/2014
Print ISSN: 0924-865X
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7179
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-013-0393-5

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 4/2014

Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 4/2014 Zur Ausgabe