Skip to main content
Erschienen in: The Review of International Organizations 4/2013

01.12.2013

Political ideology, quality at entry and the success of economic reform programs

verfasst von: Lodewijk Smets, Stephen Knack, Nadia Molenaers

Erschienen in: The Review of International Organizations | Ausgabe 4/2013

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This study investigates how government ideology matters for the success of World Bank economic policy loans, which typically support market-liberalizing reforms. A simple model predicts that World Bank staff will invest more effort in designing an economic policy loan when faced with a left-wing government. Empirically, estimates from a Heckman selection model show that the quality at entry of an economic policy loan is significantly higher for governments with a left-wing party orientation. This result is robust to changes in the sample, alternative measures of ideology, different estimation techniques and the inclusion of additional control variables. Next, robust findings from estimating a recursive triangular system of equations indicate that leftist governments comply more fully with loan agreements. Results also suggest that World Bank resources are more productive—in terms of reform success—in the design of policy operations than in their supervision. Anecdotal evidence from several country cases is consistent with the finding that left-wing governments receive higher quality loans.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
Interviews were conducted in August 2011 at the World Bank Headquarters in Washington D.C.
 
2
A number of interesting studies in this respect are Wittman (1983), Alesina (1988), Glazer and Grofman (1989), Alesina and Cukierman (1990), Roemer (1997, 1999) and Terai (2006). Both Drazen (2000) and Persson and Tabellini (2000) provide an extensive overview on the political economy of economic reform.
 
3
A partial listing includes Beck (1982), Bjørnskov (2005, 2008), Bortolotti and Pinotti (2008), Dutt and Mitra (2005, 2006), Frey and Schneider (1978), Hibbs (1977), Pitlik (2007), and Potrafke (2010).
 
4
Policy decisions are not influenced solely by ideology, of course; staying in office and other considerations also matter. See for example Persson and Tabellini (2000).
 
5
According to the theory of cognitive dissonance, a person who behaves in a way contrary to his beliefs is motivated by resulting discomfort or anxiety to reduce this “cognitive dissonance,” e.g., by changing his beliefs. Cognitive dissonance theory has been widely applied in social science research. For applications in the field of economics, see among others Akerlof and Dickens (1982) and Gilad et al. (1987). Hirschman (1965) and James and Gutkind (1985) have applied it to claim that the coercive nature of conditional aid hinders reform.
 
6
For multi-tranche operations a Tranche Release Document is prepared on the basis of which the decision is taken to release subsequent tranches.
 
7
A DPL task team leader interviewed for this study suggested that matching World Bank staff with governments might not be random; for example, more capable staff members might be assigned to work with more ‘difficult’ governments. On the other hand, to the extent higher-quality staff have more leverage in choosing their assignments, they might opt to work with less difficult governments, where their advice is more welcome. Data limitations prevent us from measuring staff quality. Denizer et al. (2011) control for the impact of task leader fixed effects on project success, but our sample of policy loans is too small to implement this approach.
 
8
In our model we assume a positive mapping from effort to program quality, which in turn positively affects the expected returns of a loan. However, it is conceivable that World Bank effort might reduce quality at entry—by, e.g., ignoring local conditions—as to accomodate to unfriendly governments. Yet, the cases presented in Section 5 do not seem consistent with this hypothesis and rather indicate a positive mapping between effort and program quality. Furthermore, the effort put in does not merely serve to design a program the recipient government will agree to, but also Bank management and the Board of Directors, who demand at least some minimum expected returns.
 
9
The salary incentive can be generalized to non-pecuniary sources of utility, such as the utility World Bank staff receive from continued policy dialogue with high-level government officials. Arguably, the policy dialogue with a left-wing government would be damaged more by a failed policy reform program, so staff have an added incentive to design a higher-quality loan.
 
10
This assumption holds if \(u(s) + \delta \cdot u(S) - \psi (1)>0\).
 
11
A case in point is post-apartheid South Africa, where the COSATU-backed ANC government for a long time disagreed with the World Bank’s lending proposals.
 
12
The Country Policy and Institutional Assessments (CPIA) are subjective ratings of 16 indicators updated annually by World Bank staff, and used for allocating IDA loans.
 
13
We have also included party orientation as a selection variable, yet it did not turn out to influence receipt of DPL.
 
14
The IEG uses the Bank’s Implementation Completion and Results Reports (ICRs) as a starting point to evaluate the different stages of a reform program. The validity of the IEG measures might be questioned (see, e.g., Dreher et al. 2010). However, Kilby (2000, pp. 239–247), Dollar and Svensson (2000, pp. 897–899) and Denizer et al. (2011, pp. 7–10) persuasively defend the IEG ratings as valid measures of program success. They provide the following arguments (among others): (i) the IEG is independent of the Bank’s senior management; (ii) the outcome variables are highly correlated with improvements in observed economic performance; (iii) IEG ratings do not significantly differ from the more in-depth and detailed “Project Performance Audit Reports.” Unfortunately, the latter ratings are available only for a very limited sample of DPLs. While there surely is still remaining measurement error, there is no reason to believe the IEG ratings are biased, particularly with respect to government ideology. The latter view is supported by interviews of experienced IEG staff members. Nevertheless, to control for a potential political bias of World Bank ratings, we have included the overall CPIA rating in one of the robustness tests. That is, if IEG staff are biased then regular Bank staff—who generate the CPIA ratings—should produce similar biases.
 
15
The Database of Political Institutions was constructed in 2001 and initially covered 177 countries for the period 1975–1995. The database is periodically updated: the most recent version dating to 2010 contains information from 1975 through 2009.
 
16
Following Dreher and Sturm (2012), we consider the G-7 as a country group. The variable reflects the average G-7 vote by weighing each G-7 countries’ vote with its quota in the IMF.
 
17
Given that our sample contains a limited number of countries and a limited number of observations per country, we have opted to include regional fixed effects instead of country fixed effects.
 
18
The model’s predictions mainly apply to quality at entry and not to the other stages of the reform process. Extending the model to those other stages is beyond the scope of this paper but may be an interesting area for further research.
 
19
For the triangular model to be fully recursive, we assume a diagonal variance covariance matrix \(\Sigma \). It is conceivable that this assumption is violated as an omitted variable may simultaneously affect the left-hand side variables. However, a likelihood ratio test of uncorrelated errors yields a \(\chi ^2\) statistic of 2.87 with corresponding p-value of 0.4123. Triangular systems also assume a certain ordering of endogenous variabes in a sense that the ith equation may contain endogenous variables whose position is lower than i (Lahiri and Schmidt 1978). As the World Bank formulates monitoring and evaluation arrangements in the preparation stage of the program, they signal their supervision intentions before the start of the program. Next, part of the supervision effort includes an evaluative review to identify problems during implementation and recommendations to resolve them. For these reasons we include Bank supervision on the right hand side of the second (compliance) equation. On the other hand, it is standard operating procedure to supervise loan agreements irrespective of the extent of borrower compliance. However, Dollar and Svensson (2000) assume that exogenous shocks that reduce the probability of compliance also influence the allocation of World Bank resources (for supervision). As such they claim that donor variables are endogenous to DPL success. Malesa and Silarszky (2005) statistically test this reasoning but fail to find any evidence that supervision costs (and other donor variables) are endogenous to the probability of success. They explain this by the fact that resources for supervision are budgeted in advance. That is why we have opted to exclude compliance from the first equation.
 
20
See Besley and Case (2003) for a detailed literature review on how political factors affect (economic) policy choice.
 
21
Dreher et al. (2009a) find that market-liberalizing policy reforms are inversely related to the chief executive’s time in office.
 
22
Additionally, we have tested our model by including a set of dummies reflecting the sectoral target of policy loans and find that results change very little. Regression results are not tabulated but are available upon request.
 
23
However, an omitted variable such as staff capacity may well affect quality at entry and supervision in the same way. Yet, it is not uncommon in World Bank practice to have various staff teams working on the different stages of one DPL.
 
24
The authors identify three conditions for such a policy switch to occur: firstly, the desirability of the policy switch should be considerable and relatively rare. Second, policy reversals are more prone to occur when voters are uncertain about the government’s preferences. Finally, the outcomes of the policies under consideration take place in the future. However, Cowen and Sutter (1998) have shown that similar policy reversals also hold under less stringent conditions.
 
25
The results of the model with time fixed effects are line with the base model, but are not included due to space considerations.
 
26
In three other cases, interviews suggested that ideology was less salient. The four cases discussed, and the 7 selected in total, are not necessarily representative of all DPLs. A form of “convenience sampling” was employed, in which the authors selected task team leaders who were judged most likely to respond favorably to interview requests. Whether representative or not, the cases are illustrative of the main arguments and intuition behind the model.
 
27
Note that at that time FRELIMO already discarded its radical Marxist-Leninist ideology—-yet still situated firmly on the left—which allowed the World Bank the opportunity to discuss market reforms. In terms of the model, it was no longer the case that \((B-C)<\underline {U}_{Moz}\).
 
28
During the interviews a team task manager mentioned that attitude change was also crucial in successfully supporting the economic reform programs in Vietnam.
 
29
Within the MMD there were outspoken differences concerning the impact of market reforms. President Levy Mwanawasa opposed privatization arguing that market policies “had brought untold suffering to the workers” while his Finance Minister Emmanuel Kasonde maintained that it was inevitable to redress the situation where state-owned enterprises continue to depend on the state for subventions. Following these differences over privatization, Emmanuel Kasonde was relieved of his ministerial position by the Mwanawasa Government (World Bank 2004).
 
30
In terms of the model: a government with low reservation utility for accepting the reform program.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Akerlof, G.A., & Dickens, W.T. (1982). The economic consequences of cognitive dissonance. The American Economic Review, 72(3), 307–319. Akerlof, G.A., & Dickens, W.T. (1982). The economic consequences of cognitive dissonance. The American Economic Review, 72(3), 307–319.
Zurück zum Zitat Alesina, A. (1988). Credibility and policy convergence in a two-party system with rational voters. The American Economic Review, 78(4), 796–805. Alesina, A. (1988). Credibility and policy convergence in a two-party system with rational voters. The American Economic Review, 78(4), 796–805.
Zurück zum Zitat Alesina, A., & Cukierman, A. (1990). The politics of ambiguity. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105(4), 829–850.CrossRef Alesina, A., & Cukierman, A. (1990). The politics of ambiguity. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105(4), 829–850.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Andersen, T.B., Hansen, H., Markussen, H. (2006). US politics and World Bank IDA-lending. The Journal of Development Studies, 42(5), 772–794.CrossRef Andersen, T.B., Hansen, H., Markussen, H. (2006). US politics and World Bank IDA-lending. The Journal of Development Studies, 42(5), 772–794.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Beck, N. (1982). Parties, administrations, and American macroeconomic outcomes. The American Political Science Review, 76(1), 83–93.CrossRef Beck, N. (1982). Parties, administrations, and American macroeconomic outcomes. The American Political Science Review, 76(1), 83–93.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Besley, T., & Case, A. (2003). Political institutions and policy choices: evidence from the United States. Journal of Economic Literature, 41(1), 7–73.CrossRef Besley, T., & Case, A. (2003). Political institutions and policy choices: evidence from the United States. Journal of Economic Literature, 41(1), 7–73.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Besley, T., Montalvo, J.G., Reynal-Querol, M. (2011). Do educated leaders matter? Economic Journal, 121(554), F205–F227.CrossRef Besley, T., Montalvo, J.G., Reynal-Querol, M. (2011). Do educated leaders matter? Economic Journal, 121(554), F205–F227.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bienen, H., & Van De Walle, N. (1989). Time and power in Africa. The American Political Science Review, 83(1), 19–34.CrossRef Bienen, H., & Van De Walle, N. (1989). Time and power in Africa. The American Political Science Review, 83(1), 19–34.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bjørnskov, C. (2005). Does political ideology affect economic growth? Public Choice, 123, 133–146.CrossRef Bjørnskov, C. (2005). Does political ideology affect economic growth? Public Choice, 123, 133–146.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bjørnskov, C. (2008). The growth-inequality association: government ideology matters. Journal of Development Economics, 87(2), 300–308.CrossRef Bjørnskov, C. (2008). The growth-inequality association: government ideology matters. Journal of Development Economics, 87(2), 300–308.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bortolotti, B., & Pinotti, P. (2008). Delayed privatization. Public Choice, 136(3), 331–351.CrossRef Bortolotti, B., & Pinotti, P. (2008). Delayed privatization. Public Choice, 136(3), 331–351.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bueno de Mesquita, B., Morrow, J.D., Siverson, R.M., Smith, A. (2002). Political institutions, policy choice and the survival of leaders. British Journal of Political Science, 32(4), 559–590.CrossRef Bueno de Mesquita, B., Morrow, J.D., Siverson, R.M., Smith, A. (2002). Political institutions, policy choice and the survival of leaders. British Journal of Political Science, 32(4), 559–590.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chai, S.-K. (1998). Endogenous ideology formation and economic policy in former colonies. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 46(2), 263–90.CrossRef Chai, S.-K. (1998). Endogenous ideology formation and economic policy in former colonies. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 46(2), 263–90.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chauvet, L., Collier, P., Fuster, A. (2006). Supervision and project performance: A principal-agent approach. University of Oxford: Centre for the Study of African Economies. Chauvet, L., Collier, P., Fuster, A. (2006). Supervision and project performance: A principal-agent approach. University of Oxford: Centre for the Study of African Economies.
Zurück zum Zitat Cowen, T., & Sutter, D. (1998). Why only Nixon could go to China. Public Choice, 97(4), 605–615.CrossRef Cowen, T., & Sutter, D. (1998). Why only Nixon could go to China. Public Choice, 97(4), 605–615.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cukierman, A., & Tommasi, M. (1998). When does it take a Nixon to go to China? American Economic Review, 88, 180–197. Cukierman, A., & Tommasi, M. (1998). When does it take a Nixon to go to China? American Economic Review, 88, 180–197.
Zurück zum Zitat Denizer, C., Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A. (2011). Good countries or good projects? Macro and micro correlates of World Bank project performance. Policy Research Working Paper Series 5646, The World Bank. Denizer, C., Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A. (2011). Good countries or good projects? Macro and micro correlates of World Bank project performance. Policy Research Working Paper Series 5646, The World Bank.
Zurück zum Zitat Dijkstra, G.A. (2002). The effectiveness of policy conditionality: eight countries experiences. Development and Change, 33(2), 307–334.CrossRef Dijkstra, G.A. (2002). The effectiveness of policy conditionality: eight countries experiences. Development and Change, 33(2), 307–334.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dollar, D., & Svensson, J. (2000). What explains the success or failure of structural adjustment programmes?The Economic Journal, 110, 894–917.CrossRef Dollar, D., & Svensson, J. (2000). What explains the success or failure of structural adjustment programmes?The Economic Journal, 110, 894–917.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Drazen, A. (2000). Political economy in macroeconomics. New Jersey: Princeton University Press. Drazen, A. (2000). Political economy in macroeconomics. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Dreher, A., Klasen, S., Vreeland, J.R.,Werker, E. (2010). The costs of favoritism: is politically-driven aid less effective? CESifo Working Paper Series 2993, CESifo Group Munich. Dreher, A., Klasen, S., Vreeland, J.R.,Werker, E. (2010). The costs of favoritism: is politically-driven aid less effective? CESifo Working Paper Series 2993, CESifo Group Munich.
Zurück zum Zitat Dreher, A., Lamla, M.J., Lein, S.M., Somogyi, F. (2009a). The impact of political leaders’ profession and education on reforms. Journal of Comparative Economics, 37(1), 169–193.CrossRef Dreher, A., Lamla, M.J., Lein, S.M., Somogyi, F. (2009a). The impact of political leaders’ profession and education on reforms. Journal of Comparative Economics, 37(1), 169–193.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dreher, A., & Sturm, J.-E. (2012). Do the IMF and the World Bank influence voting in the UN General Assembly? Public Choice, 151(1), 363–397.CrossRef Dreher, A., & Sturm, J.-E. (2012). Do the IMF and the World Bank influence voting in the UN General Assembly? Public Choice, 151(1), 363–397.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dreher, A., Sturm, J.-E., Vreeland, J.R. (2009b). Development aid and international politics: does membership on the UN security council influence World Bank decisions?Journal of Development Economics, 88(1), 1–18.CrossRef Dreher, A., Sturm, J.-E., Vreeland, J.R. (2009b). Development aid and international politics: does membership on the UN security council influence World Bank decisions?Journal of Development Economics, 88(1), 1–18.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dutt, P., & Mitra, D. (2005). Political ideology and endogenous trade policy: an empirical investigation. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 87(1), 59–72.CrossRef Dutt, P., & Mitra, D. (2005). Political ideology and endogenous trade policy: an empirical investigation. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 87(1), 59–72.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dutt, P., & Mitra, D. (2006). Labor versus capital in trade-policy: the role of ideology and inequality. Journal of International Economics, 69(2), 310–320.CrossRef Dutt, P., & Mitra, D. (2006). Labor versus capital in trade-policy: the role of ideology and inequality. Journal of International Economics, 69(2), 310–320.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Frey, B.S., & Schneider, F. (1978). An empirical study of politico-economic interaction in the United States. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 60(2), 174–183.CrossRef Frey, B.S., & Schneider, F. (1978). An empirical study of politico-economic interaction in the United States. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 60(2), 174–183.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gilad, B., Kaish, S., Loeb, P.D. (1987). Cognitive dissonance and utility maximization: a general framework. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 8(1), 61–73.CrossRef Gilad, B., Kaish, S., Loeb, P.D. (1987). Cognitive dissonance and utility maximization: a general framework. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 8(1), 61–73.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Glazer, A., & Grofman, B. (1989). Why representatives are ideologists though voters are not. Public Choice, 61(1), 29–39.CrossRef Glazer, A., & Grofman, B. (1989). Why representatives are ideologists though voters are not. Public Choice, 61(1), 29–39.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Haggard, S., & Webb, S. (Eds.) (1994). Voting for reform: Democracy, political liberalisation, and economic adjustment. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Haggard, S., & Webb, S. (Eds.) (1994). Voting for reform: Democracy, political liberalisation, and economic adjustment. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Heckman, J.J. (1979). Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica, 47(1), 153–161.CrossRef Heckman, J.J. (1979). Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica, 47(1), 153–161.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hibbs, D.A. (1977). Political parties and macroeconomic policy. The American Political Science Review, 71(4), 1467–1487.CrossRef Hibbs, D.A. (1977). Political parties and macroeconomic policy. The American Political Science Review, 71(4), 1467–1487.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hirschman, A.O. (1965). Obstacles to development: a classification and a quasi-vanishing act. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 13(4), 385.CrossRef Hirschman, A.O. (1965). Obstacles to development: a classification and a quasi-vanishing act. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 13(4), 385.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat IEG. (2006). . Washington, D.C.: World Bank. IEG. (2006). . Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Zurück zum Zitat James, J., & Gutkind, E. (1985). Attitude change revisited: cognitive dissonance theory and development policy. World Development, 13(10–11), 1139–1149.CrossRef James, J., & Gutkind, E. (1985). Attitude change revisited: cognitive dissonance theory and development policy. World Development, 13(10–11), 1139–1149.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Jones, B.F., & Olken, B.A. (2005). Do leaders matter? National leadership and growth since World War II. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(3), 835–864. Jones, B.F., & Olken, B.A. (2005). Do leaders matter? National leadership and growth since World War II. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(3), 835–864.
Zurück zum Zitat Kapur, D., Lewis, J.P., Webb, R. (1997). The World Bank: Its first half century. Volume 1. History. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press. Kapur, D., Lewis, J.P., Webb, R. (1997). The World Bank: Its first half century. Volume 1. History. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Kilby, C. (2000). Supervision and performance: the case of World Bank projects. Journal of Development Economics, 62(1), 233–259.CrossRef Kilby, C. (2000). Supervision and performance: the case of World Bank projects. Journal of Development Economics, 62(1), 233–259.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kilby, C. (2009). The political economy of conditionality: an empirical analysis of World Bank loan disbursements. Journal of Development Economics, 89(1), 51–61.CrossRef Kilby, C. (2009). The political economy of conditionality: an empirical analysis of World Bank loan disbursements. Journal of Development Economics, 89(1), 51–61.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kilby, C. (2011). The political economy of project preparation: An empirical analysis of world bank projects. Villanova School of Business Department of Economics and Statistics Working Paper Series 14, Villanova School of Business Department of Economics and Statistics. Kilby, C. (2011). The political economy of project preparation: An empirical analysis of world bank projects. Villanova School of Business Department of Economics and Statistics Working Paper Series 14, Villanova School of Business Department of Economics and Statistics.
Zurück zum Zitat Killick, T. (1997). Principals, agents and the failings of conditionality. Journal of International Development, 9(4), 483–495.CrossRef Killick, T. (1997). Principals, agents and the failings of conditionality. Journal of International Development, 9(4), 483–495.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Knack, S. (2012). When do donors trust recipient country systems? Policy Research Working Paper Series 6019, The World Bank. Knack, S. (2012). When do donors trust recipient country systems? Policy Research Working Paper Series 6019, The World Bank.
Zurück zum Zitat Krueger, A.O. (1993). Political economy of policy reform in developing countries. Cambridge, MA and London: The MIT Press. Krueger, A.O. (1993). Political economy of policy reform in developing countries. Cambridge, MA and London: The MIT Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Lahiri, K., & Schmidt, P. (1978). On the estimation of triangular structural systems. Econometrica, 46(5), 1217–21.CrossRef Lahiri, K., & Schmidt, P. (1978). On the estimation of triangular structural systems. Econometrica, 46(5), 1217–21.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Malesa, T., & Silarszky, P. (2005). Does World Bank Effort matter for success of adjustment operations? Conditionality revisited: Concepts, experiences, and lessons (pp. 127–141). Washington, D.C.: World Bank. Malesa, T., & Silarszky, P. (2005). Does World Bank Effort matter for success of adjustment operations? Conditionality revisited: Concepts, experiences, and lessons (pp. 127–141). Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Zurück zum Zitat Meseguer, C. (2006). Learning and economic policy choices. European Journal of Political Economy, 22(1), 156–178.CrossRef Meseguer, C. (2006). Learning and economic policy choices. European Journal of Political Economy, 22(1), 156–178.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mosley, P., Harrigan, J., Toye, J. (1991). Aid and power: The World Bank and policy-based lending Volume 1. Analysis and policy proposals. London and New York: Routledge. Mosley, P., Harrigan, J., Toye, J. (1991). Aid and power: The World Bank and policy-based lending Volume 1. Analysis and policy proposals. London and New York: Routledge.
Zurück zum Zitat Murshed, S.M. (2009). On the non-contractual nature of donor-recipient interaction in development assistance. Review of Development Economics, 13(s1), 416–428.CrossRef Murshed, S.M. (2009). On the non-contractual nature of donor-recipient interaction in development assistance. Review of Development Economics, 13(s1), 416–428.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Navia, P., & Velasco, A. (2003). The politics of second-generation reforms. In P.-P. Kuczynski, & J. Williamson (Eds.) After the Washington consensus: Restarting growth and reform in Latin America. Institute for International Economics. Navia, P., & Velasco, A. (2003). The politics of second-generation reforms. In P.-P. Kuczynski, & J. Williamson (Eds.) After the Washington consensus: Restarting growth and reform in Latin America. Institute for International Economics.
Zurück zum Zitat Noorbakhsh, F., & Paloni, A. (2007). Learning from structural adjustment: why selectivity may not be the key to successful programmes in Africa. Journal of International Development, 19(7), 927– 948.CrossRef Noorbakhsh, F., & Paloni, A. (2007). Learning from structural adjustment: why selectivity may not be the key to successful programmes in Africa. Journal of International Development, 19(7), 927– 948.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2000). Political economics, explaining economic policy. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press. Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2000). Political economics, explaining economic policy. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Pitlik, H. (2007). A race to liberalization? Diffusion of economic policy reform among OECD-economies. Public Choice, 132(1), 159–178.CrossRef Pitlik, H. (2007). A race to liberalization? Diffusion of economic policy reform among OECD-economies. Public Choice, 132(1), 159–178.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Potrafke, N. (2010). Does government ideology influence deregulation of product markets? Empirical evidence from OECD countries. Public Choice, 143(1), 135–155.CrossRef Potrafke, N. (2010). Does government ideology influence deregulation of product markets? Empirical evidence from OECD countries. Public Choice, 143(1), 135–155.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ranis, G., & Mahmood, S.A. (1992). The political economy of development policy change. Cambridge, MA and Oxford: Basil Blackwell. Ranis, G., & Mahmood, S.A. (1992). The political economy of development policy change. Cambridge, MA and Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Zurück zum Zitat Rodrik, D. (2006). Goodbye Washington consensus, hello Washington confusion? Journal of Economic Literature, 44(4), 973–987.CrossRef Rodrik, D. (2006). Goodbye Washington consensus, hello Washington confusion? Journal of Economic Literature, 44(4), 973–987.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Roemer, J.E. (1997). Politicaleconomic equilibrium when parties represent constituents: the unidimensional case. Social Choice and Welfare, 14, 479–502.CrossRef Roemer, J.E. (1997). Politicaleconomic equilibrium when parties represent constituents: the unidimensional case. Social Choice and Welfare, 14, 479–502.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Roemer, J.E. (1999). The democratic political economy of progressive income taxation. Econometrica, 67(1), 1–19.CrossRef Roemer, J.E. (1999). The democratic political economy of progressive income taxation. Econometrica, 67(1), 1–19.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Shirk, D.A. (2004). Mexico’s new politics: the PAN and democratic change. Lynne Riener. Shirk, D.A. (2004). Mexico’s new politics: the PAN and democratic change. Lynne Riener.
Zurück zum Zitat Stromberg, D. (2007). Natural disasters, economic development, and humanitarian aid. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21(3), 199–222.CrossRef Stromberg, D. (2007). Natural disasters, economic development, and humanitarian aid. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21(3), 199–222.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Svensson, J. (2000). When is foreign aid policy credible? Aid dependence and conditionality. Journal of Development Economics, 61(1), 61–84.CrossRef Svensson, J. (2000). When is foreign aid policy credible? Aid dependence and conditionality. Journal of Development Economics, 61(1), 61–84.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Svensson, J. (2003). Why conditional aid does not work and what can be done about it? Journal of Development Economics, 70(2), 381–402.CrossRef Svensson, J. (2003). Why conditional aid does not work and what can be done about it? Journal of Development Economics, 70(2), 381–402.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Terai, K. (2006). Parties with policy preferences and uncertainty over voter behavior. Social Choice and Welfare, 27, 155–172.CrossRef Terai, K. (2006). Parties with policy preferences and uncertainty over voter behavior. Social Choice and Welfare, 27, 155–172.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wane, W. (2004). The quality of foreign aid: Country selectivity or donors incentives? Policy Research Working Paper Series 3325, The World Bank. Wane, W. (2004). The quality of foreign aid: Country selectivity or donors incentives? Policy Research Working Paper Series 3325, The World Bank.
Zurück zum Zitat Williamson, J. (1994). The political economy of policy reform. No. 68 in Peterson Institute Press: All Books. Peterson Institute for International Economics. Williamson, J. (1994). The political economy of policy reform. No. 68 in Peterson Institute Press: All Books. Peterson Institute for International Economics.
Zurück zum Zitat Wittman, D. (1983). Candidate motivation: a synthesis of alternative theories. The American Political Science Review, 77(1), 142–157.CrossRef Wittman, D. (1983). Candidate motivation: a synthesis of alternative theories. The American Political Science Review, 77(1), 142–157.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat World Bank. (2002). Mexico country economic memorandum: Challenges and prospects for tax reform. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. World Bank. (2002). Mexico country economic memorandum: Challenges and prospects for tax reform. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Zurück zum Zitat World Bank. (2004). Zambia country economic memorandum: Policies for growth and diversification. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. World Bank. (2004). Zambia country economic memorandum: Policies for growth and diversification. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Zurück zum Zitat World Bank. (2005). Mozambique country economic memorandum: Sustaining growth and reducing poverty. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. World Bank. (2005). Mozambique country economic memorandum: Sustaining growth and reducing poverty. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Metadaten
Titel
Political ideology, quality at entry and the success of economic reform programs
verfasst von
Lodewijk Smets
Stephen Knack
Nadia Molenaers
Publikationsdatum
01.12.2013
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
The Review of International Organizations / Ausgabe 4/2013
Print ISSN: 1559-7431
Elektronische ISSN: 1559-744X
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-013-9164-2

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 4/2013

The Review of International Organizations 4/2013 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner