Skip to main content

2015 | OriginalPaper | Buchkapitel

10. Methodology from the Viewpoint of an Economic Theorist: Fifty Years On

verfasst von : Rudolf Richter

Erschienen in: Essays on New Institutional Economics

Verlag: Springer International Publishing

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Modern political economy, as part of social sciences, has been started by Scottish moral philosophers, among them David Hume with his Treatise of Human Nature (1740). He treats, what is called today, the problem of social control under the assumption of egoistic behaviour of individuals. What got lost in classical economics (as defined by Keynes 1936) was that Hume started essentially from the problem of future uncertainties of individual human beings. How are human individuals able to deal with future uncertainties despite their physical weaknesses? Comparing humans in the state of nature with animals, Hume (1739/1740, 1984, 536 ff.) writes:

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
Cf. H. Albert (1978, p. 63): “The representatives of this tradition were looking for the foundations of the physical reasons of the phenomena in question and for the regularity, which they are subject to. In this way, they tried to integrate the sphere of human and thus social life into the epistemological program of theoretical ‘Real Sciences’ … hence transferring the research style of natural sciences to that of social life: Political Economics.” (Own translation)
 
2
Though, Hume does not use the term “uncertainty of the future,” he rather speaks of the relative weakness of man (compared with “all the animals”) and that “…as his force and success are not all times equal, the least failure in either of these particulars must be attended with inevitable ruin and misery.” (loc.cit. 537)
 
3
Vide Hollander (1998, p. 184) referring to Jaffé (1983, p. 101) “From the age of 19 on, when Walras first read Louis Poinsot’s Eléments de Statistique (1842), he had thought to create a theory of economics with the same formal properties that characterized celestial mechanics.”
 
4
Mirowski (1984, p. 363) explains the later genesis of neoclassical theory by developments in physics in the mid-nineteenth century (see also Hollander 1998, p. 170). For Mirowski (1984, p. 377) “neoclassical economic theory is bowdlerised nineteenth century physics.”
 
5
Cass and Shell (1976) on the Hamiltonian approach as applied in quantum mechanics.
 
6
Camerer et al. (2004).
 
7
That appears not to be clear to some professional forecaster. Thus, e.g., distinguishes Granger (2012, p. 317) between only two systems, a deterministic one “if its progress can be fully described without the use of probabilities (other than zero and one)” and a “stochastic system [that is] one that has to use probabilistic concepts in describing its progress”!
 
8
The final, clarifying word on the infamous German Methodenstreit seems to have had Lionel Robbins (1932) with his circumspective and clear written defence of neoclassical microeconomics. The standard definition of the object of economics are based since then on Robbins:
Economics is the science which studies human behaviour as a relationship between ends and scarce means which have alternative uses. (Robbins 1932, p. 16)
This definition, though, narrows the object of economics to known “ends and scarce means.” The problem of “uncertainty of the future” is neglected. It emerged again towards the end of the Lange-Lerner debate on market socialism. In this context, Hayek (1945, p. 524) defines the central problem of economics to be ability of society of “rapid adaptation to changes in the particular circumstances of time and place.” North (1990, p. 80) speaks later of the “adaptive efficiency” of organisations or institutions.
 
9
Richter (1965). References to at that time relevant literature are to found there.
 
10
I referred to McCloskey already in my ‘Swansong’that dealt with methodological developments during the preceding 30 years (see Richter 1994). At that time I took McCloskey not as serious as I do now.
 
11
This is exactly the problem in response to which David Hume (1739/1740, 536 f.) developed his idea of some self-enforcing “social control mechanism.” Game theorists like Ken Binmore (1992, p. 21) interpret the result as Nash equilibrium.
 
12
Cf., e.g., Allen and Gale (2006, p. 17), who write: if “there are enough derivatives and contracts, markets will effectively be complete and allocation of risk will be the same as in the Arrow-Debreu equilibrium. This is the sense in which credit risk transfer is desirable.”
 
13
Cf., e.g., the reminder of Koopmans (1957, p. 147) “…our economic knowledge has not yet been carried to the point where it sheds much light on the core problem of economic organization of society: the problem of how to face and deal with uncertainty. ….Meanwhile, the best safeguard against overestimation of the range of applicability of economic propositions is a careful spelling out of the premises on which they rest.” Very clearly also Arrow (1970, p. 137).
 
14
Whose statements depend are independent of the details of the relevant social background. “Ergodic” is a technical term of statistic mechanics used by Samuelson (1968, p. 12). He writes: “Technically speaking, we theorists hoped not to introduce hysteresis phenomena into our model…”.
 
15
And further: “…why should a country like Spain still look after its public budget if loans can be refinanced at such low interest rates?” (NZZ 01. 07. 2014).
 
16
Keynes understands as “classic economists” is explained in the only footnote oft he first chapter of General Theory (1936).
 
17
The “dual decision hypothesis” by Clower (1965, p. 118) consists in the assumption that “If the price mechanism stops working, consumers switch to ‘quantity rationing’ (Malinvaud 1977, 4 ff.). i.e., they buy the quantity of (present and future) goods that maximizes their utility given their present (national) income Y. Similarly firms maximize in this case their profit given employment N.
 
18
On more details see Richter (2009).
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Albert, H. (1978). Traktat über rationale Praxis. Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck). Albert, H. (1978). Traktat über rationale Praxis. Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck).
Zurück zum Zitat Allen, F., & Gale, D. (2006). Systemic risk and regulation. NBER conference on The Risk of Financial Institutions, Woodstock, Vermont, October 22–23, 2004. Allen, F., & Gale, D. (2006). Systemic risk and regulation. NBER conference on The Risk of Financial Institutions, Woodstock, Vermont, October 22–23, 2004.
Zurück zum Zitat Arrow, K. J. (1970). Essays in the theory of risk-bearing. Amsterdam: North-Holland. Arrow, K. J. (1970). Essays in the theory of risk-bearing. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Zurück zum Zitat Bernanke, B. (2000). Essays on the great depression. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Bernanke, B. (2000). Essays on the great depression. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Bernanke, B. (2002). Remarks by governor Ben S. Bernanke before the national economists club. Washington, DC, November 2, 2002—im Internet verfügbar. Bernanke, B. (2002). Remarks by governor Ben S. Bernanke before the national economists club. Washington, DC, November 2, 2002—im Internet verfügbar.
Zurück zum Zitat Binmore, K. (1992). Fun and games. A text on game theory. Lexington, MA: D.C. Heath. Binmore, K. (1992). Fun and games. A text on game theory. Lexington, MA: D.C. Heath.
Zurück zum Zitat Camerer, C. F., Loewenstein, G., & Prelec, D. (2004). Neuroeconomics: Why economics needs brains. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 106(3), 555–579.CrossRef Camerer, C. F., Loewenstein, G., & Prelec, D. (2004). Neuroeconomics: Why economics needs brains. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 106(3), 555–579.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cass, D., & Shell, K. (Eds.). (1976). The Hamiltonian approach to dynamic economics. New York, NY: Academic. Cass, D., & Shell, K. (Eds.). (1976). The Hamiltonian approach to dynamic economics. New York, NY: Academic.
Zurück zum Zitat Clower, R. W. (1965). The Keynesian counterrevolution: A theoretical appraisal. In R. H. Hahn & F. P. R. Brechling (Eds.), The theory of interest rates (pp. 103–125). London: Macmillan. Clower, R. W. (1965). The Keynesian counterrevolution: A theoretical appraisal. In R. H. Hahn & F. P. R. Brechling (Eds.), The theory of interest rates (pp. 103–125). London: Macmillan.
Zurück zum Zitat Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4, 386–405.CrossRef Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4, 386–405.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dilthey, W. (2010). Understanding the human world, selected works (Vol. 2, R. A. Makkreland & F. Rodi, Eds.). Princeton: Princeton University Press. Dilthey, W. (2010). Understanding the human world, selected works (Vol. 2, R. A. Makkreland & F. Rodi, Eds.). Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Fisher, I. (1933). The debt-deflation theory of great depressions. Econometrica, 1(4), 337–357.CrossRef Fisher, I. (1933). The debt-deflation theory of great depressions. Econometrica, 1(4), 337–357.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Giersch, H., & Borchardt, K. (Eds.). (1962). Diagnose und Prognose als wirtschaftswissenschaftliches Methodenproblem. Verhandlungen auf der Arbeitstagung des Vereins für Socialpoliotik in Garmisch-Partenkirchen 1961. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot. Giersch, H., & Borchardt, K. (Eds.). (1962). Diagnose und Prognose als wirtschaftswissenschaftliches Methodenproblem. Verhandlungen auf der Arbeitstagung des Vereins für Socialpoliotik in Garmisch-Partenkirchen 1961. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot.
Zurück zum Zitat Granger, C. W. J. (2012). The philosophy of economic forecasting. S. 311 – 327. (In: Mäki 2012). Granger, C. W. J. (2012). The philosophy of economic forecasting. S. 311 – 327. (In: Mäki 2012).
Zurück zum Zitat Hayek, F. A. (1945). The use of knowledge in society. American Economic Review, 35, 519–530. Hayek, F. A. (1945). The use of knowledge in society. American Economic Review, 35, 519–530.
Zurück zum Zitat Hollander, S. (1998). The literature of political economy: Collected essays II. 2nd ed. New York, NY: Routledge. Hollander, S. (1998). The literature of political economy: Collected essays II. 2nd ed. New York, NY: Routledge.
Zurück zum Zitat Hume, D. (1739/1740, 1984). In E. C. Mossner (Ed.), A treatise of human nature. London: Penguin Hume, D. (1739/1740, 1984). In E. C. Mossner (Ed.), A treatise of human nature. London: Penguin
Zurück zum Zitat Jaffé, W. (1983). William jaffé’s essays on Walras (D. A. Walker Ed.). Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press. Jaffé, W. (1983). William jaffé’s essays on Walras (D. A. Walker Ed.). Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Keynes, J. M. (1936). The general theory of employment, interest and money. London: Macmillan. Keynes, J. M. (1936). The general theory of employment, interest and money. London: Macmillan.
Zurück zum Zitat Keynes, J. M. (1937). The general theory. Quarterly Journal of Economics. (Reprinted in D. Moggridge (Ed.), The collected writings of John Maynard Keynes, pp. 109–124, XIV, 1973, London: Macmillan). Keynes, J. M. (1937). The general theory. Quarterly Journal of Economics. (Reprinted in D. Moggridge (Ed.), The collected writings of John Maynard Keynes, pp. 109–124, XIV, 1973, London: Macmillan).
Zurück zum Zitat Koopmans, T. C. (1957). Three essays on the state of economic science. NewYork, NY: McGraw-Hill. Koopmans, T. C. (1957). Three essays on the state of economic science. NewYork, NY: McGraw-Hill.
Zurück zum Zitat Kroeber-Riel, W. (1992). Konsumentenverhalten, 5. Aufl., München: Vahlen. Kroeber-Riel, W. (1992). Konsumentenverhalten, 5. Aufl., München: Vahlen.
Zurück zum Zitat Laidler, D., & Parkin, M. (1975). Inflation: A survey. Economic Journal, 85, 741–809.CrossRef Laidler, D., & Parkin, M. (1975). Inflation: A survey. Economic Journal, 85, 741–809.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Malinvaud, E. (1977). The theory of unemployment reconsidered, Yrjö Johnson Lectures, Oxford: Basil Blackwell. Malinvaud, E. (1977). The theory of unemployment reconsidered, Yrjö Johnson Lectures, Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Zurück zum Zitat McCloskey, D. N. (1983). The rhetoric of economics. Journal of Economic Literature, 21, 481–517. McCloskey, D. N. (1983). The rhetoric of economics. Journal of Economic Literature, 21, 481–517.
Zurück zum Zitat Mirowski, P. (1984). Physics and the‚ marginalist revolution. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 8(4), 361–79. Mirowski, P. (1984). Physics and the‚ marginalist revolution. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 8(4), 361–79.
Zurück zum Zitat Newton, I. (1687/1999). Philosophiae Naturalis Principia Mathematica (written in Latin) (revised editions 1713, 1726, first English translation in 1729. A recent English translation by I. B. Cohen and A. Whitman, Berkeley et al.). Berkeley: University of California Press. Newton, I. (1687/1999). Philosophiae Naturalis Principia Mathematica (written in Latin) (revised editions 1713, 1726, first English translation in 1729. A recent English translation by I. B. Cohen and A. Whitman, Berkeley et al.). Berkeley: University of California Press.
Zurück zum Zitat North, D. C. (1990/1992). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge, MA (deutsch: Institutionen, institutioneller Wandel und Wirtschaftsleistung, Tübingen 1992). North, D. C. (1990/1992). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge, MA (deutsch: Institutionen, institutioneller Wandel und Wirtschaftsleistung, Tübingen 1992).
Zurück zum Zitat Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Cambridge (deutsche Übersetzung: Die Logik des kollektiven Handelns. Kollektivgüter und die Theorie der Gruppen, 3. Aufl. (durchgesehen), Tübingen 1992.) Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Cambridge (deutsche Übersetzung: Die Logik des kollektiven Handelns. Kollektivgüter und die Theorie der Gruppen, 3. Aufl. (durchgesehen), Tübingen 1992.)
Zurück zum Zitat Popper, K. R. (1959). The logic of scientific discovery. London: Hutchinson. Popper, K. R. (1959). The logic of scientific discovery. London: Hutchinson.
Zurück zum Zitat Richter, R. (1965). Methodologie aus der Sicht des Wirtschaftstheoretikers. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 95, 242–261 (Wieder abgedruckt in: R. Jochimsen und H. Knobel, Hrsg. (1971), Gegenstand und Methoden der Nationalökonomie, S. 188–203, Köln: Kiepenheuer & Witsch). Richter, R. (1965). Methodologie aus der Sicht des Wirtschaftstheoretikers. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 95, 242–261 (Wieder abgedruckt in: R. Jochimsen und H. Knobel, Hrsg. (1971), Gegenstand und Methoden der Nationalökonomie, S. 188–203, Köln: Kiepenheuer & Witsch).
Zurück zum Zitat Richter, R. (1994). Methodology from the viewpoint of the economic theorist—Thirty years on. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics (JITE), 150, 589–608. Richter, R. (1994). Methodology from the viewpoint of the economic theorist—Thirty years on. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics (JITE), 150, 589–608.
Zurück zum Zitat Richter, R. (2009). Who listened? Unappreciated teachings of new institutional economics related to the financial crisis 2008. Kredit und Kapital, 42, 473–486.CrossRef Richter, R. (2009). Who listened? Unappreciated teachings of new institutional economics related to the financial crisis 2008. Kredit und Kapital, 42, 473–486.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Robbins, L. (1932). An essay on the nature and significance of economic science. London: Macmillan. Robbins, L. (1932). An essay on the nature and significance of economic science. London: Macmillan.
Zurück zum Zitat Samuelson, P. A. (1968). Classical and neoclassical theory. In R. W. Closer (Ed.), Monetary theory. London: Penguin. Samuelson, P. A. (1968). Classical and neoclassical theory. In R. W. Closer (Ed.), Monetary theory. London: Penguin.
Zurück zum Zitat Sims, C. A. (1996). Macroeconomics and methodology. Jounral of Economic Perspectives, 10(1), 105–120.CrossRef Sims, C. A. (1996). Macroeconomics and methodology. Jounral of Economic Perspectives, 10(1), 105–120.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Walras, L. (1874). Éléments d‘économie politique pure, ou théorie de la richesse sociale. Lausanne: L. Corbaz & cie. Walras, L. (1874). Éléments d‘économie politique pure, ou théorie de la richesse sociale. Lausanne: L. Corbaz & cie.
Zurück zum Zitat Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. New York (deutsch: Die ökonomischen Institutionen des Kapitalismus, Tübingen 1990). Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. New York (deutsch: Die ökonomischen Institutionen des Kapitalismus, Tübingen 1990).
Metadaten
Titel
Methodology from the Viewpoint of an Economic Theorist: Fifty Years On
verfasst von
Rudolf Richter
Copyright-Jahr
2015
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-14154-1_10

Premium Partner