Skip to main content

2020 | OriginalPaper | Buchkapitel

12. The Enforcement of Competition Law—A Behavioral Law and Economics Perspective

verfasst von : Jingyuan Ma

Erschienen in: Competition Law in China

Verlag: Springer Singapore

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

The choice of enforcement instruments in competition law has become a major debate around the world. In recent years, many competition authorities commentators have argued for a more “mixed” approach in antitrust enforcement, acknowledging that three enforcement instruments—private, administrative and criminal enforcement—are not substitutes to each other, but rather compliments, and should be better coordinated based on the strengths and weaknesses of each mechanism. This chapter address the insights of this issue by incorporating the recent development of behavioral economics and examine to what extent those insights lead to a different optimal mix of enforcement instruments. Behavioral findings can explain the ineffectiveness of some of the existing mechanisms and allow to provide more balanced criteria for determining the optimal mix of instruments in antitrust enforcement. This chapter discusses the optimal mix of enforcement instruments from the perspective of public and private enforcers. The findings of behavioral studies provided a more nuanced criteria when assessing the pros and cons of each instrument, and may be relevant to explain some of the reasons why the enforcement mechanisms become ineffective.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
Korobkin and Ulen (2000, p. 1067), McAdams and Ulen (2009).
 
2
Kahneman et al. (1982); For a summary of the research findings by Tversky and Kahneman, see Kahneman (2003, pp. 1449–1475); research by other psychologists, see for example, Evans (1984, p. 451).
 
3
For example, Babcock and Loewenstein (1997, p. 109), Benartzi and Thaler (1995, pp. 73–92), Camerer and Hogarth (1999, pp. 7–42).
 
4
For example, Fiske and Taylor (1991), Weinstein (1980, p. 806).
 
5
The selection of these biases are based on Langevoort (1998, pp. 1503–1506), Faure (2008).
 
6
Rachlinski claimed that the methods that behavioural law and economics uses rely on the concepts that Tversky and Kahneman developed, such as endowment effect, framing, anchoring and hindsight bias. See also Korobkin and Ulen (2000).
 
7
Simon (1957), Simon (1955, p. 99).
 
8
Korobkin and Ulen (2000, p. 1075).
 
9
Korobkin and Ulen (2000, p. 1076).
 
10
Simon (1979, p. 503).
 
11
Robinson and Darley (2004, p. 193), Baron and Kennedy (1998).
 
12
McAdams and Ulen (2009).
 
13
Reeves and Stucke (2011, p. 1542), Stucke (2007).
 
14
Van den Bergh (2013).
 
15
Simon (1979, p. 493).
 
16
Anchoring effects: a randomly chosen starting point that will influence the estimates. See Tversky and Kahneman (1974). Tversky and Kahneman (1974).
 
17
Prospect theory: people value losses more than the gains (Kahneman and Tversky 1979, p. 263).
 
18
Loss aversion: there is an asymmetry between the losses and gains, people suffer more utility loss to give up an object than the amount to acquire it. This effect may affect decision making process in many domains of policy issues. See examples provided by Samuelson and Zeckhauser (1988, pp. 7–59).
 
19
Framing: individual’s decisions are affected by how future losses and gains are framed. Kahneman and Tversky (1984, p. 343).
 
20
Kahneman et al. 1990, p. 1325; Knetsch 1989, pp. 1277–1284; Kahneman et al. 1990, pp. 1325–1348.
 
21
Kahneman et al. (1990).
 
22
Knetsch (1989, pp. 1277–1284).
 
23
For an overview of these experiments, see Tversky and Kahneman (1991, pp. 1055–1056), Novemsky and Kahneman (2005, pp. 119–120).
 
24
See examples provided by Samuelson and Zeckhauser (1988, pp. 7–59).
 
25
Samuelson and Zeckhauser (1988).
 
26
Samuelson and Zeckhauser (1988, p. 8).
 
27
Camerer and Kunreuther (1989, p. 577).
 
28
Camerer and Kunreuther (1989, p. 577).
 
29
Fischhoff (1975, pp. 288–299).
 
30
Hindsight bias: People are likely to over-estimate the likelihood of an event’s occurrence after knowing it happened (Fischhoff 1975). Kamin and Rachlinski (1995, p. 91); Korobkin and Ulen (2000, pp. 1095–1100).
 
31
Kamin and Rachlinski (1995, p. 91).
 
32
Weinstein (1980, pp. 806–820), Taylor and Brown (1988, pp. 193–210).
 
33
Jolls (1998, pp. 1658–1663), Sunstein (1997, pp. 1182–1184).
 
34
Babcock et al. (1997, p. 915); for an overview of these psychological research on overconfidence, see Camerer and Lovallo (1999, p. 306, footnote 1).
 
35
Svenson (1981, pp. 143–148).
 
36
Jolls (1998, p. 1659).
 
37
Viscusi and Magat (1987).
 
38
Baker and Emery (1993, p. 439).
 
39
Hastorf and Cantril (1954, pp. 129–134).
 
40
Tversky and Kahneman (1973).
 
41
Combs and Slovic (1974, pp. 837–849).
 
42
Tversky and Kahneman, pp. 92–93, Sunstein (1997, pp. 1188–1189), Hanson and Kysar (1999, p. 630).
 
43
Psychologists’ research shows that over-confidence exists when people consider their own activities and their futures. See Weinstein(1980), Taylor and Brown(1988). Unrealistic optimism may lead to under-estimation of the probability that unpleasant events will happen to one self. See Jolls (1998, pp. 1658–1663), Sunstein (1997, pp. 1182–1184).
 
44
Tversky and Kahneman (1973, p. 207).
 
45
Samuelson and Zeckhauser (1988, p. 7).
 
46
Simonson and Tversky (1992, pp. 281, 290).
 
47
Cooper and Kovacic (2012a, p. 784), Lucas Jr. and Tasic (2015, p. 217) (“voters and politicians do not evaluate policies globally by considering all angles, including the interrelationships among policies. Instead, their analyses are subject to pervasive framing, salience, and vividness effects.”); See also Hirschleifer (2008, p. 856).
 
48
Cooper and Kovacic (2012a, p. 784).
 
49
Cowen (2005, p. 445) (“All voters will be excessively attracted to policies that make citizens “feel good about themselves”. Individuals on all sides of the political spectrum will be unwilling to confront difficult trade-offs”). Lucas Jr. and Tasic (2015, p. 218).
 
50
Anthony Patt and Richard Zeckhauser found that “take action”—such as cleaning up a polluted resource, is more favourable to the public than inaction—for example preserving the source, because taking action is easier to be visualized. See Patt and Zeckhauser (2000, p. 45); see also Lucas Jr. and Tasic (2015, p. 230).
 
51
Coate et al. (1995).
 
52
Muris (2005, p. 166) (“For an agency like the FTC, the most attention is paid publicly to the prosecution of cases, preferably “big” ones, or to the launching of “tough” regulations, while non litigation activities that have a major impact on public policy or less obviously significant cases and rules that do not tackle large players, but that alter doctrine in important ways, are usually overlooked.”).
 
53
Sokol (2012a, p. 701).
 
54
Camerer found that when New York taxi drivers set daily income targets, they will stop working once the target is met Camerer et al. (1997).
 
55
Kovacic et al. (2011).
 
56
Kovacic (2009, pp. 903, 922–923).
 
57
For example, the competition authority in Russia has a strong bias on merely increasing the number of case decisions. See Paneiakh and Novikov (2014).
 
58
The judicial capacity restraint of assessing economic evidence has been named by Frank Easterbrook as the “limits of antitrust”, details see Chap. 11 of this book.
 
59
Crowley (1987, pp. 266–267), Humphries and Songer (1999, p. 209).
 
60
Crowley (1987), Sheehan (1990, pp. 875–85).
 
61
Rozenblit and Keil (2002).
 
62
See also Tasic (2009, p. 428).
 
63
Kruger and Dunning (1999, p. 1121).
 
64
Tasic (2009, p. 430).
 
65
Also in the area of tort law when assessing damages there is substantial evidence of bias in the judgement of experts. For an overview see Faure and Visscher (2011, p. 376).
 
66
Friedman argues that the crucial difference between public and private actors is that there is no similar market competition among regulators. See Friedman (2009, p. 127).
 
67
Cooper and Kovacic (2012b, p. 47).
 
68
Cooper and Kovacic (2012a, b, pp. 47, 791) (“Once a regulator takes a position on a particular policy, she will want to filter future matters in a way that supports her initial wisdom”).
 
69
Simon (2004), Simon and Scurich (2011, p. 711).
 
70
Simon and Scurich (2011, p. 711).
 
71
Cooper and Kovacic (2012a, p. 788).
 
72
Kovacic (2015, p. 257).
 
73
In antitrust law, see Shugart II (1995, pp. 7–8) (“Legislative and policy decisions in the realm of antitrust are shaped not by some ideal conception of the public interest, but rather by the interaction between well-organized private interest groups seeking protection from the forces of competition and politicians and other government officials seeking to maximize their own personal welfare.”).
 
74
Cooper and Kovacic (2012a, p. 791).
 
75
Cooper and Kovacic (2012b, p. 50).
 
76
The biased decisions of regulators may come directly from the biased preferences of their political overseers. Some argues that politicians are more biased than regulators. Choi and Pritchard (2003, p. 38) (“Politicians themselves may face their own behavioural biases, and there is no reason to think that the politicians’ biases are any less than those facing regulators”) Lucas Jr. and Tasic (2015, p. 203) (“Because political actors have little incentive to behave rationally, irrationality is common in politics, and it has a substantial negative effect on the law”).
 
77
Kovacic et al. (2011, p. 40), Hyman and Kovacic, p. 2172).
 
78
Seidenfeld (2002, p. 486).
 
79
Choi and Pritchard (2003, p. 38).
 
80
Joshua Davis and Robert Lande found that the benefits of private enforcement were substantial. In the 60 largest successful private US antitrust cases since 1990, private action has recovered USD 33.8 to 35.8 billion for victims of anti-competitive conduct. See Davis and Lande (2013, p. 1272).
 
81
For a summary of the criticisms on private enforcement of the US Antitrust Law, See Lande and Davis (2008, pp. 883–887).
 
82
Roth and Murnighan (1982, p. 1123).
 
83
Babcock et al. (1995a, p. 1337).
 
84
Loewenstein et al. (1992); Note that theorists may reach a similar conclusion. For example, Bourjade et al. (2009) argued that “It should be the violators who settle and the innocent firms that refuse.” Bourjade et al. (2009, p. 372).
 
85
Babcock et al. (1997, p. 915).
 
86
Babcock et al. (1997, p. 914).
 
87
Dunning et al. (1989, p. 1082).
 
88
Loewenstein and Moore (2004, pp. 37, 38).
 
89
Babcock et al. (1997, p. 915).
 
90
Babcock et al. (1995a, b, p. 1337).
 
91
Loewenstein et al. (1992, p. 135).
 
92
Babcock and Pogarsky (1999, p. 341).
 
93
Korobkin and Guthrie (1994, pp. 109–110).
 
94
Kahneman and Tversky (1979, p. 263), Tversky and Kahneman (1992, p. 297).
 
95
This is named as the Framing Theory of Litigation, Guthrie (2000, pp. 167–168). For details, see Rachlinski (1996, p. 113), Korobkin and Guthrie (1997, p. 77), Babcock et al. (1995b, p. 289), Korobkin and Guthrie (1994, p. 107).
 
96
Roth and Murnighan (1982, p. 1123).
 
97
Loewenstein et al. (1992, pp. 135–159); Note that theorists may reach a similar conclusion. For example, Bourjade et al. argued that “It should be the violators who settle and the innocent firms that refuse.” See Bourjade et al. (2009, p. 372).
 
98
Loewenstein and Moore (2004, pp. 37, 38).
 
99
Babcock and Loewenstein (1997, p. 109).
 
100
Babcock et al. (1997, pp. 913, 915).
 
101
Babcock et al. (1997, p. 914).
 
102
Babcock et al. (1997, p. 915).
 
103
Babcock et al. (1995a, pp. 1337–1343).
 
104
Loewenstein et al. (1992, p. 135).
 
105
Lillard and Viscusi (1990).
 
106
Rubinfeld, p. 176.
 
107
For a summary of the literature, see Babcock et al. (1997, p. 916).
 
108
Babcock et al. (1997, p. 921).
 
109
Nisbett et al. (1976, pp. 107–116).
 
110
Guthrie (2000, p. 210).
 
111
Slovic and Fishhoff (1977, p. 544).
 
112
Koriat et al. (1980).
 
113
Lord et al. (1984, p. 1231).
 
114
Babcock et al. (1997, p. 913).
 
115
Robinson and Darley (2004, p. 174).
 
116
Cook (1980).
 
117
Matsueda et al. (2006, p. 950).
 
118
Connor and Lande (2012).
 
119
Robinson and Darley (2004, p. 187).
 
120
Robinson and Darley (2004, p. 186); The adaptation effect is named by Brickman and Campbell as ‘Hedonic treadmill’ See Brickman and Campbell (1971, p. 287).
 
121
Kahneman (1999, p. 4), Redelmeier and Kahneman (1996, p. 3).
 
122
In particular, it is important to increase the maximum intensity and the end intensity of the painful experience. However, the punishment with high intensity, short duration and with the most intensive, painful punishment at the end is usually defined as ‘torture’ (Robinson and Darley 2004, pp. 190–191).
 
123
Guthrie et al. (2001, p. 784).
 
124
Sokol (2012b, p. 203).
 
125
Lucas Jr. and Tasic (2015, pp. 199–264), Berggren (2012, p. 199).
 
126
Tasic (2009, p. 423).
 
127
For example, Cass Sunstein said “For every bias identified for individuals, there is an accompanying bias in the public sphere.” Sunstein (2014, p. 102), Liaison and Zeckhauser raised this point earlier (1998, p. 7).
 
128
Englich et al. (2006, pp. 188–200).
 
129
Guthrie et al. (2001, p. 784).
 
130
Rachlinski and Farina (2002, p. 549).
 
131
Kuran and Sunstein (1999, p. 683).
 
132
Hirshleifer (2008, p. 856).
 
133
Viscusi and Gayer (2015, p. 978).
 
134
Rachlinski and Farina (2002).
 
135
Caplan (2007).
 
136
Viscusi (1995, pp. 50–54).
 
137
Viscusi and Hamilton (1999, pp. 1010, 1025).
 
138
Lucas Jr. and Tasic (2015, p. 4).
 
139
Schnellenbach and Schubert (2015, pp. 395, 396).
 
140
Tor (2013, p. 6).
 
141
Van den Bergh (2013, p. 211).
 
142
Reeves and Stucke (2011, p. 1542).
 
143
List (2004, p. 615).
 
144
Glaeser (2006, pp. 140–141, 144–146).
 
145
Rubin (1998, pp. 1705, 1715), Stucke (2007, p. 515).
 
146
Cooper and Kovacic (2012a, p. 792).
 
147
Back to 1948 Judge Prettyman pointed out that “The tribunal does the best it can to decipher the truth from the resultant welter. Nothing could be sillier.” Prettyman, ‘Needed: New Trial Technique: Suggestions for the Trial of Complicated Cases’, 34 ABA J 766, 770 (1948) cited by Massel (1962, p. 48).
 
148
Epstein et al. (2011, pp. 104, 106).
 
149
Fruytier et al. (2013, p. 46), Holvast and Doornbos (2015, p. 50).
 
150
Holvast and Doombos (2015, p. 58).
 
151
Huang (2011, p. 1116).
 
152
Driskell and Salas (1991, p. 474).
 
153
Klein (1976).
 
154
Behavioural market failure could be considered as an extension of market failure, see Bar-Gill (2002). (“The behavioral market failure, with its emphasis on misperception and bias, is a direct extension of the imperfect information problem.”) Oren Bar-Gill, Competition and Consumer Protection: A Behavioral Economics Account, in Swedish Competition Authority, the Pros and Cons of Consumer Protection, December 19, 2011, available at http://​papers.​ssrn.​com/​sol3/​papers.​cfm?​abstract_​id=​1974499. For the relationship between behavioural government failure and public choice theory, see Rachlinsky and Farina (2002).
 
155
Schumpeter (1942), Buchanan and Tullock (1962, Chap. 4).
 
156
Glaeser (2006), p.133.
 
157
Mueller (2003).
 
158
Lucas Jr. and Tasic (2015, p. 259).
 
159
Polinsky (1980, p. 110).
 
160
Lucas Jr. and Tasic (2015, p. 259).
 
161
Shavell (1984, p. 357).
 
162
Segal and Winston (2007, p. 206).
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Babcock, L., & Loewenstein, G. (1997). Explaining bargaining impasse: The role of self-serving biases. Journal of Economic Perspective, 11, 109–126.CrossRef Babcock, L., & Loewenstein, G. (1997). Explaining bargaining impasse: The role of self-serving biases. Journal of Economic Perspective, 11, 109–126.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Babcock, L., & Pogarsky, G. (1999). Damage caps and settlement: A behavioral approach. The Journal of Legal Studies, 28, 341–370.CrossRef Babcock, L., & Pogarsky, G. (1999). Damage caps and settlement: A behavioral approach. The Journal of Legal Studies, 28, 341–370.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Babcock, L., Loewenstein, G., Issacharoff, S., & Camerer, C. (1995a). Biased judgements of fairness in bargaining. American Economic Review, 85, 1337–1343. Babcock, L., Loewenstein, G., Issacharoff, S., & Camerer, C. (1995a). Biased judgements of fairness in bargaining. American Economic Review, 85, 1337–1343.
Zurück zum Zitat Babcock, L., Farber, H. S., Fobian, C., & Shafir, E. (1995b). Forming beliefs about adjudicated outcomes: Perceptions of risk and reservation values. International Review of Law and Economics, 15(3), 289–303.CrossRef Babcock, L., Farber, H. S., Fobian, C., & Shafir, E. (1995b). Forming beliefs about adjudicated outcomes: Perceptions of risk and reservation values. International Review of Law and Economics, 15(3), 289–303.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Babcock, L., Loewenstein, G., & Issacharoff, S. (1997). Creating convergence: Debiasing biased litigants. Law and Social Inquiry, 22(4), 401–413.CrossRef Babcock, L., Loewenstein, G., & Issacharoff, S. (1997). Creating convergence: Debiasing biased litigants. Law and Social Inquiry, 22(4), 401–413.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Baker, L. A., & Emery, R. E. (1993). When every relationship is above average: Perceptions and expectations of divorce at the time of marriage. Law and Human Behavior, 17, 439–450.CrossRef Baker, L. A., & Emery, R. E. (1993). When every relationship is above average: Perceptions and expectations of divorce at the time of marriage. Law and Human Behavior, 17, 439–450.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Baron, S., & Kennedy, L. W. (1998). Deterrence and homeless male street youths. Canadian Journal of Criminology, 40(1), 27–60.CrossRef Baron, S., & Kennedy, L. W. (1998). Deterrence and homeless male street youths. Canadian Journal of Criminology, 40(1), 27–60.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Benartzi, S., & Thaler, R. H. (1995). Myopic loss aversion and the equity premium puzzle. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(1), 73–92.CrossRef Benartzi, S., & Thaler, R. H. (1995). Myopic loss aversion and the equity premium puzzle. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(1), 73–92.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Berggren, N. (2012). The time for behavioral political economy? An analysis of articles in behavioral economics. Review of Austrian Economics, 25, 199–221.CrossRef Berggren, N. (2012). The time for behavioral political economy? An analysis of articles in behavioral economics. Review of Austrian Economics, 25, 199–221.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bourjade, S., Rey, P., & Seabright, P. (2009). Private antitrust enforcement in the presence of pre-trial bargaining. Journal of Industrial Economics, 57(3), 372–409.CrossRef Bourjade, S., Rey, P., & Seabright, P. (2009). Private antitrust enforcement in the presence of pre-trial bargaining. Journal of Industrial Economics, 57(3), 372–409.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brickman, P., & Campbell, D. (1971). Hedonic relativism and planning the good society. In M. H. Appley (Ed.), Adaptation-level theory: A symposium (pp. 287–302). Brickman, P., & Campbell, D. (1971). Hedonic relativism and planning the good society. In M. H. Appley (Ed.), Adaptation-level theory: A symposium (pp. 287–302).
Zurück zum Zitat Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent: Logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Chapter 4. Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent: Logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Chapter 4.
Zurück zum Zitat Camerer, C. F., & Hogarth, R. M. (1999). The effect of financial incentives. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 19, 7–42.CrossRef Camerer, C. F., & Hogarth, R. M. (1999). The effect of financial incentives. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 19, 7–42.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Camerer, C. F., & Kunreuther, H. (1989). Decision processes for low probability events: Policy implications. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 8(4), 565–592.CrossRef Camerer, C. F., & Kunreuther, H. (1989). Decision processes for low probability events: Policy implications. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 8(4), 565–592.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Camerer, C., & Lovallo, D. (1999). Overconfidence and excess entry: An experimental approach. The American Economic Review, 89(1), 306–318.CrossRef Camerer, C., & Lovallo, D. (1999). Overconfidence and excess entry: An experimental approach. The American Economic Review, 89(1), 306–318.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Camerer, C., Babcock, L., Loewenstein, G., & Thaler, R. H. (1997). Labor supply of New York City cabdrivers: One day at a time. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 407–441.CrossRef Camerer, C., Babcock, L., Loewenstein, G., & Thaler, R. H. (1997). Labor supply of New York City cabdrivers: One day at a time. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 407–441.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Caplan, B. (2007). The myth of the rational voter: Why democracies choose bad policies. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Caplan, B. (2007). The myth of the rational voter: Why democracies choose bad policies. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Choi, S. J., & Pritchard, A. C. (2003). Behavioral economics and the SEC. Stanford Law Review, 56(1), 1–73. Choi, S. J., & Pritchard, A. C. (2003). Behavioral economics and the SEC. Stanford Law Review, 56(1), 1–73.
Zurück zum Zitat Coate, M. B., Higgins, R. S., & McChesney, F. S. (1995). Bureaucracy and politics in FTC merger challenges. In F. S. McChesney & W. F. Shughart II (Eds.), The causes and consequences of antitrust: The public-choice perspective. Coate, M. B., Higgins, R. S., & McChesney, F. S. (1995). Bureaucracy and politics in FTC merger challenges. In F. S. McChesney & W. F. Shughart II (Eds.), The causes and consequences of antitrust: The public-choice perspective.
Zurück zum Zitat Combs, B., & Slovic, P. (1974). Causes of death: Biased newspaper coverage and biased judgements. Journalism Quarterly, 56, 837–849.CrossRef Combs, B., & Slovic, P. (1974). Causes of death: Biased newspaper coverage and biased judgements. Journalism Quarterly, 56, 837–849.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Connor, J. M., & Lande, R. H. (2012). Cartels as rational business strategy: New data demonstrates that crime pays. Cardozo Law Review, 34, 427–490. Connor, J. M., & Lande, R. H. (2012). Cartels as rational business strategy: New data demonstrates that crime pays. Cardozo Law Review, 34, 427–490.
Zurück zum Zitat Cook, P. (1980). Research in criminal deterrence: Laying the groundwork for the second decade. In N. Morris & M. Tonry (Eds.), Crime and justice: An annual review of research (Vol. 2). Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Cook, P. (1980). Research in criminal deterrence: Laying the groundwork for the second decade. In N. Morris & M. Tonry (Eds.), Crime and justice: An annual review of research (Vol. 2). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Cooper, J. C., & Kovacic, W. E. (2012a). Behavioral economics and its meaning for antitrust agency decision making. Journal of Law, Economics and Policy, 8(4), 779–800. Cooper, J. C., & Kovacic, W. E. (2012a). Behavioral economics and its meaning for antitrust agency decision making. Journal of Law, Economics and Policy, 8(4), 779–800.
Zurück zum Zitat Cooper, J. C., & Kovacic, W. E. (2012b). Behavioral economics: Implications for regulatory behavior. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 41, 41–58.CrossRef Cooper, J. C., & Kovacic, W. E. (2012b). Behavioral economics: Implications for regulatory behavior. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 41, 41–58.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cowen, T. (2005). Self-deception as the root of political failure. Public Choice, 124(3), 437–451.CrossRef Cowen, T. (2005). Self-deception as the root of political failure. Public Choice, 124(3), 437–451.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Crowley, D. W. (1987). Judicial review of administrative agencies: Does the type of agency matter? The Western Political Quarterly, 40(2)/31(June), 265–283. Crowley, D. W. (1987). Judicial review of administrative agencies: Does the type of agency matter? The Western Political Quarterly, 40(2)/31(June), 265–283.
Zurück zum Zitat Davis, J. P., & Lande, R. H. (2013). Toward an empirical and theoretical assessment of private antitrust enforcement. Seattle University Law Review, 36, 1269–1335. Davis, J. P., & Lande, R. H. (2013). Toward an empirical and theoretical assessment of private antitrust enforcement. Seattle University Law Review, 36, 1269–1335.
Zurück zum Zitat Driskell, J. E., & Salas, E. (1991). Group decision making under stress. Journal of Applied Psychology, 76(3), 473–478.CrossRef Driskell, J. E., & Salas, E. (1991). Group decision making under stress. Journal of Applied Psychology, 76(3), 473–478.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dunning, D., Meyerowitz, J. A., & Holzberg, A. D. (1989). Ambiguity and self-evaluation: The role of idiosyncratic trait definitions in self-serving assessments of ability. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 57(6), 1082–1090.CrossRef Dunning, D., Meyerowitz, J. A., & Holzberg, A. D. (1989). Ambiguity and self-evaluation: The role of idiosyncratic trait definitions in self-serving assessments of ability. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 57(6), 1082–1090.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Englich, B., Mussweiler, T., & Strack, F. (2006). Playing dice with criminal sentences: The influence of irrelevant anchors on experts’ judicial decision making. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 32, 188–200.CrossRef Englich, B., Mussweiler, T., & Strack, F. (2006). Playing dice with criminal sentences: The influence of irrelevant anchors on experts’ judicial decision making. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 32, 188–200.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Epstein, L., Landes, W. M., & Posner, R. A. (2011). Why (and when) judges dissent: A theoretical and empirical analysis. Journal of Legal Analysis, 3(1), 101–137.CrossRef Epstein, L., Landes, W. M., & Posner, R. A. (2011). Why (and when) judges dissent: A theoretical and empirical analysis. Journal of Legal Analysis, 3(1), 101–137.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Evans, J. St. B. T. (1984). Heuristic and analytic processes in reasoning. British Journal of Psychology, 75(4), 451–468. Evans, J. St. B. T. (1984). Heuristic and analytic processes in reasoning. British Journal of Psychology, 75(4), 451–468.
Zurück zum Zitat Faure, M. (2008). Calabresi and behavioral tort law and economics. Erasmus Law Review, 4, 75–102. Faure, M. (2008). Calabresi and behavioral tort law and economics. Erasmus Law Review, 4, 75–102.
Zurück zum Zitat Faure, M. G., & Visscher, L. (2011). The role of experts in assessing damages—A law and economics account. European Journal of Risk Regulation, 3, 376–396.CrossRef Faure, M. G., & Visscher, L. (2011). The role of experts in assessing damages—A law and economics account. European Journal of Risk Regulation, 3, 376–396.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fischhoff, B. (1975). Hindsight & foresight: The effect of outcome knowledge on judgment under uncertainty. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance, 1, 288–299. Fischhoff, B. (1975). Hindsight & foresight: The effect of outcome knowledge on judgment under uncertainty. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance, 1, 288–299.
Zurück zum Zitat Fiske, S. T., & Taylor, S. E. (1991). Social cognition (2nd ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill. Fiske, S. T., & Taylor, S. E. (1991). Social cognition (2nd ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill.
Zurück zum Zitat Friedman, J. (2009). A crisis of politics, not economics: Complexity, ignorance, and regulatory failure. Critical Review, 21. Friedman, J. (2009). A crisis of politics, not economics: Complexity, ignorance, and regulatory failure. Critical Review, 21.
Zurück zum Zitat Fruytier, B. G. M., Dikkers, J., Keesen, M., Janssen, J., van den Berg, I., Valeton, N., & Schouteten, R. L. J. (2013). Werkdruk bewezen. Eindrapport werkdrukonderzoek rechterlijke macht. Utrecht/Nijmegen: Hogeschool Utrecht/Radboud Universiteit Nijmegen. External research report. Retrieved from https://repository.ubn.ru.nl/handle/2066/126420. Fruytier, B. G. M., Dikkers, J., Keesen, M., Janssen, J., van den Berg, I., Valeton, N., & Schouteten, R. L. J. (2013). Werkdruk bewezen. Eindrapport werkdrukonderzoek rechterlijke macht. Utrecht/Nijmegen: Hogeschool Utrecht/Radboud Universiteit Nijmegen. External research report. Retrieved from https://​repository.​ubn.​ru.​nl/​handle/​2066/​126420.
Zurück zum Zitat Glaeser, E. L. (2006). Paternalism and psychology. University of Chicago Law Review, 73, 133–156. Glaeser, E. L. (2006). Paternalism and psychology. University of Chicago Law Review, 73, 133–156.
Zurück zum Zitat Guthrie, C. (2000). Framing frivolous litigation: a psychological theory. The University of Chicago Law Review, 67(1), 163–215.CrossRef Guthrie, C. (2000). Framing frivolous litigation: a psychological theory. The University of Chicago Law Review, 67(1), 163–215.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Guthrie, C., Rachlinski, J. J., & Wistrich, A. J. (2001). Inside the judicial mind. Cornell Law Review, 86(4), 777–830. Guthrie, C., Rachlinski, J. J., & Wistrich, A. J. (2001). Inside the judicial mind. Cornell Law Review, 86(4), 777–830.
Zurück zum Zitat Hanson, J. D., & Kysar, D. A. (1999). Taking behavioralism seriously: The problem of market manipulation. NYU Law Review, 74, 630–749. Hanson, J. D., & Kysar, D. A. (1999). Taking behavioralism seriously: The problem of market manipulation. NYU Law Review, 74, 630–749.
Zurück zum Zitat Hastorf, A., & Cantril, H. (1954). They saw a game: A case study. Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology, 49(1), 129–134.CrossRef Hastorf, A., & Cantril, H. (1954). They saw a game: A case study. Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology, 49(1), 129–134.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hirshleifer, D. A. (2008). Psychological bias as a driver of financial regulation. European Financial Management, 14(5), 856–874.CrossRef Hirshleifer, D. A. (2008). Psychological bias as a driver of financial regulation. European Financial Management, 14(5), 856–874.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Holvast, N. L., & Doornbos, N. (2015). Exit, voice, and loyalty within the judiciary: Judges’ responses to new managerialism in the Netherlands. Utrecht Law Review, 11(2), 49–63.CrossRef Holvast, N. L., & Doornbos, N. (2015). Exit, voice, and loyalty within the judiciary: Judges’ responses to new managerialism in the Netherlands. Utrecht Law Review, 11(2), 49–63.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Huang, B. I. (2011). Lightened Scrutiny. Harvard Law Review, 124(5), 1109–1152. Huang, B. I. (2011). Lightened Scrutiny. Harvard Law Review, 124(5), 1109–1152.
Zurück zum Zitat Humphries, M. A., & Songer, D. R. (1999). Law and politics in judicial oversight of federal administrative agencies. The Journal of Politics, 61(1), 207–220.CrossRef Humphries, M. A., & Songer, D. R. (1999). Law and politics in judicial oversight of federal administrative agencies. The Journal of Politics, 61(1), 207–220.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hyman, D., & Kovacic, W. (2013). Institutional design, agency life cycle, and the goals of competition law. Fordham Law Review, 81(5), 2163–2174. Hyman, D., & Kovacic, W. (2013). Institutional design, agency life cycle, and the goals of competition law. Fordham Law Review, 81(5), 2163–2174.
Zurück zum Zitat Jolls, C. (1998). Behavioral economic analysis of redistributive legal rules. Vanderbilt Law Review, 51, 1658–1663. Jolls, C. (1998). Behavioral economic analysis of redistributive legal rules. Vanderbilt Law Review, 51, 1658–1663.
Zurück zum Zitat Kahneman, D. (1999). Objective happiness. In D. Kahneman, E. Deiner, & N. Schwartz (Eds.), Well-being: The foundations of hedonic psychology. New York: Russell Sage Foundation. Kahneman, D. (1999). Objective happiness. In D. Kahneman, E. Deiner, & N. Schwartz (Eds.), Well-being: The foundations of hedonic psychology. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Zurück zum Zitat Kahneman, D. (2003). Maps of bounded rationality: Psychology for behavioral economics. The American Economic Review, 93(5), 1449–1475.CrossRef Kahneman, D. (2003). Maps of bounded rationality: Psychology for behavioral economics. The American Economic Review, 93(5), 1449–1475.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–291.CrossRef Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–291.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1984). Choices, values and frames. American Psychologist, 39, 341–350.CrossRef Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1984). Choices, values and frames. American Psychologist, 39, 341–350.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kahneman, D., Slovic, P., & Tversky, A. (Eds.). (1982). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Cambridge University Press. Kahneman, D., Slovic, P., & Tversky, A. (Eds.). (1982). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., & Thaler, R. (1990). Experimental tests of the endowment effect and the Coase theorem. Journal of Political Economy, 98, 1325–1348.CrossRef Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., & Thaler, R. (1990). Experimental tests of the endowment effect and the Coase theorem. Journal of Political Economy, 98, 1325–1348.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kamin, K. A., & Rachlinski, J. J. (1995). Ex post ≠ ex ante: Determining liability in hindsight. Law and Human Behavior, 19(1), 89–104.CrossRef Kamin, K. A., & Rachlinski, J. J. (1995). Ex post ≠ ex ante: Determining liability in hindsight. Law and Human Behavior, 19(1), 89–104.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Klein, A. L. (1976). Changes in leadership appraisal as a function of the stress of a simulated panic situation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 34, 1143–1154.CrossRef Klein, A. L. (1976). Changes in leadership appraisal as a function of the stress of a simulated panic situation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 34, 1143–1154.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Knetsch, J. L. (1989). The endowment effect and evidence of nonreversible indifference curves. American Economic Review, LXXIX, 1277–1284. Knetsch, J. L. (1989). The endowment effect and evidence of nonreversible indifference curves. American Economic Review, LXXIX, 1277–1284.
Zurück zum Zitat Koriat, A., Lichtenstein, S., & Fischhoff, B. (1980). Reasons for confidence. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Learning and Memory, 6(2), 107–118. Koriat, A., Lichtenstein, S., & Fischhoff, B. (1980). Reasons for confidence. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Learning and Memory, 6(2), 107–118.
Zurück zum Zitat Korobkin, R., & Guthrie, C. (1994). Psychological barriers to litigation settlement: An experimental approach. Michigan Law Review, 93, 107–192.CrossRef Korobkin, R., & Guthrie, C. (1994). Psychological barriers to litigation settlement: An experimental approach. Michigan Law Review, 93, 107–192.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Korobkin, R., & Guthrie, C. (1997). Psychology, economics and settlement: A new look at the role of the lawyer. Texas Law Review, 76, 77–121. Korobkin, R., & Guthrie, C. (1997). Psychology, economics and settlement: A new look at the role of the lawyer. Texas Law Review, 76, 77–121.
Zurück zum Zitat Korobkin, R. B., & Ulen, T. S. (2000). Law and behavioral science: Removing the rationality assumption from law and economics. California Law Review, 88(4), 1051–1144. Korobkin, R. B., & Ulen, T. S. (2000). Law and behavioral science: Removing the rationality assumption from law and economics. California Law Review, 88(4), 1051–1144.
Zurück zum Zitat Kovacic, W. (2009). Rating the competition agencies: What constitutes good performance? George Mason Law Review, 16, 903–926. Kovacic, W. (2009). Rating the competition agencies: What constitutes good performance? George Mason Law Review, 16, 903–926.
Zurück zum Zitat Kovacic, W. (2015). Creating a respected brand: How regulatory agencies signal quality. George Mason Law Review, 22, 237–258. Kovacic, W. (2015). Creating a respected brand: How regulatory agencies signal quality. George Mason Law Review, 22, 237–258.
Zurück zum Zitat Kovacic, W. E., Hollman, H. M., & Patricia, G. (2011). How does your competition agency measure up? European Competition Journal, 7, 25–45.CrossRef Kovacic, W. E., Hollman, H. M., & Patricia, G. (2011). How does your competition agency measure up? European Competition Journal, 7, 25–45.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kruger, J., & Dunning, D. (1999). Unskilled and unaware of it: How difficulties in recognizing one’s own incompetence lead to inflated self-Assessments. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 77(6), 1121–1134.CrossRef Kruger, J., & Dunning, D. (1999). Unskilled and unaware of it: How difficulties in recognizing one’s own incompetence lead to inflated self-Assessments. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 77(6), 1121–1134.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kuran, T., & Sunstein, C. R. (1999). Availability cascades and risk regulation. Stanford Law Review, 51(4), 683–768.CrossRef Kuran, T., & Sunstein, C. R. (1999). Availability cascades and risk regulation. Stanford Law Review, 51(4), 683–768.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lande, R. H., & Davis, J. P. (2008). Benefits from private antitrust enforcement: An analysis of forty cases. University of San Francisco Law Review, 42, 879–918. Lande, R. H., & Davis, J. P. (2008). Benefits from private antitrust enforcement: An analysis of forty cases. University of San Francisco Law Review, 42, 879–918.
Zurück zum Zitat Langevoort. (1998). Behavioral theories of judgment and decision making in legal scholarship: A literature review. Vanderbilt Law Review, 51, 1499–1540. Langevoort. (1998). Behavioral theories of judgment and decision making in legal scholarship: A literature review. Vanderbilt Law Review, 51, 1499–1540.
Zurück zum Zitat Liaison, D. I., & Zeckhauser, R. (1998). Amos Tversky and the ascent of behavioral economics. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 16(1), 7–47.CrossRef Liaison, D. I., & Zeckhauser, R. (1998). Amos Tversky and the ascent of behavioral economics. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 16(1), 7–47.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lillard, L. A., & Viscusi, W. K. (1990). The bargaining structure of the litigation process. Lillard, L. A., & Viscusi, W. K. (1990). The bargaining structure of the litigation process.
Zurück zum Zitat List, J. A. (2004). Neoclassical theory versus prospect theory: Evidence from the marketplace. Econometrica, 72(2), 615–625.CrossRef List, J. A. (2004). Neoclassical theory versus prospect theory: Evidence from the marketplace. Econometrica, 72(2), 615–625.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Loewenstein, G., & Moore, D. A. (2004). When ignorance is bliss: Information exchange and inefficiency in bargaining. The Journal of Legal Studies, 33, 37–58.CrossRef Loewenstein, G., & Moore, D. A. (2004). When ignorance is bliss: Information exchange and inefficiency in bargaining. The Journal of Legal Studies, 33, 37–58.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Loewenstein, G., Issacharoff, S., Camerer, C., & Babcock, L. (1992). Self-serving assessments of fairness and pretrial bargaining. Journal of Legal Studies, 22, 135–159.CrossRef Loewenstein, G., Issacharoff, S., Camerer, C., & Babcock, L. (1992). Self-serving assessments of fairness and pretrial bargaining. Journal of Legal Studies, 22, 135–159.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lord, C., Lepper, M., & Preston, E. (1984). Considering the opposite, a corrective strategy for social judgment. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 47(6), 1231–1243.CrossRef Lord, C., Lepper, M., & Preston, E. (1984). Considering the opposite, a corrective strategy for social judgment. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 47(6), 1231–1243.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lucas, G. M., Jr., & Tasic, S. (2015). Behavioral public choice and the law. West Virginia Law Review, 118, 199–264. Lucas, G. M., Jr., & Tasic, S. (2015). Behavioral public choice and the law. West Virginia Law Review, 118, 199–264.
Zurück zum Zitat Massel, M. S. (1962). Economic Analysis in Judicial Antitrust Decisions. ABA Antitrust Section, 20, 46–61. Massel, M. S. (1962). Economic Analysis in Judicial Antitrust Decisions. ABA Antitrust Section, 20, 46–61.
Zurück zum Zitat Matsueda, R., Kreager, D., & Huizinga, D. (2006). Deterring delinquents: A rational choice model of theft and violence. American Sociological Review, 71(1), 95–122.CrossRef Matsueda, R., Kreager, D., & Huizinga, D. (2006). Deterring delinquents: A rational choice model of theft and violence. American Sociological Review, 71(1), 95–122.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat McAdams, R. H., & Ulen, T. S. (2009). Behavioral criminal law and economics. In Garoupa, N. (Ed.), Criminal law and economics. Edward Elgar. Chapter 18. McAdams, R. H., & Ulen, T. S. (2009). Behavioral criminal law and economics. In Garoupa, N. (Ed.), Criminal law and economics. Edward Elgar. Chapter 18.
Zurück zum Zitat Mueller, D. C. (2003). Public choice III. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Mueller, D. C. (2003). Public choice III. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Muris, T. J. (2005). Principles for a successful competition agency. The University of Chicago Law Review, 72(1), 165–187. Muris, T. J. (2005). Principles for a successful competition agency. The University of Chicago Law Review, 72(1), 165–187.
Zurück zum Zitat Nisbett, R. E., Borgida, E., Crandall, R., & Reed, H. (1976). Popular induction: Information is not always informative. In Carroll, J. & Payne, J. (Eds.), Cognition and social behavior. Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. Reprinted in Kahneman, D., Slovic, P., & Tversky, A. (Eds.). (1982). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Cambridge University Press. Nisbett, R. E., Borgida, E., Crandall, R., & Reed, H. (1976). Popular induction: Information is not always informative. In Carroll, J. & Payne, J. (Eds.), Cognition and social behavior. Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. Reprinted in Kahneman, D., Slovic, P., & Tversky, A. (Eds.). (1982). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Novemsky, N., & Kahneman, D. (2005). The boundaries of loss aversion. Journal of Marketing Research, 42(2), 119–128.CrossRef Novemsky, N., & Kahneman, D. (2005). The boundaries of loss aversion. Journal of Marketing Research, 42(2), 119–128.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Patt, A., & Zeckhauser, R. (2000). Action bias and environmental decisions. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 21, 45–72.CrossRef Patt, A., & Zeckhauser, R. (2000). Action bias and environmental decisions. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 21, 45–72.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Polinsky, M. (1980). Private versus public enforcement of fines. Journal of Legal Studies, 9(1), 105–127.CrossRef Polinsky, M. (1980). Private versus public enforcement of fines. Journal of Legal Studies, 9(1), 105–127.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Prettyman. (1948). Needed: new trial technique: Suggestions for the trial of complicated cases. American Bar Association Journal, 34(9), 766–660. Prettyman. (1948). Needed: new trial technique: Suggestions for the trial of complicated cases. American Bar Association Journal, 34(9), 766–660.
Zurück zum Zitat Rachlinski, J. J. (1996). Gains, losses and the psychology of litigation. Southern California Law Review, 70, 113–186. Rachlinski, J. J. (1996). Gains, losses and the psychology of litigation. Southern California Law Review, 70, 113–186.
Zurück zum Zitat Rachlinski, J. J., & Farina, C. F. (2002). Cognitive psychology and optimal government design. Cornell Law Review, 87(2), 549–615. Rachlinski, J. J., & Farina, C. F. (2002). Cognitive psychology and optimal government design. Cornell Law Review, 87(2), 549–615.
Zurück zum Zitat Redelmeier, D., & Kahneman, D. (1996). ‘Patients’ memories of painful medical treatments: Real time and retrospective evaluations of two minimally invasive procedures. Pain, 116, 3–8.CrossRef Redelmeier, D., & Kahneman, D. (1996). ‘Patients’ memories of painful medical treatments: Real time and retrospective evaluations of two minimally invasive procedures. Pain, 116, 3–8.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Reeves, A., & Stucke, M. (2011). Behavioral antitrust. Indiana Law Journal, 86, 1527–1586. Reeves, A., & Stucke, M. (2011). Behavioral antitrust. Indiana Law Journal, 86, 1527–1586.
Zurück zum Zitat Robinson, P. H., & Darley, J. M. (2004). Does criminal law deter? A behavioral science investigation. Oxford Journal of Legal Studies, 24(2), 173–205.CrossRef Robinson, P. H., & Darley, J. M. (2004). Does criminal law deter? A behavioral science investigation. Oxford Journal of Legal Studies, 24(2), 173–205.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Roth, A. E., & Murnighan, E. (1982). The role of information in bargaining: An experimental study. Econometrica, 50, 1123–1142.CrossRef Roth, A. E., & Murnighan, E. (1982). The role of information in bargaining: An experimental study. Econometrica, 50, 1123–1142.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rozenblit, L., & Keil, F. (2002). The misunderstood limits of folk science: An illusion of explanatory depth. Cognitive Science, 26, 521–562.CrossRef Rozenblit, L., & Keil, F. (2002). The misunderstood limits of folk science: An illusion of explanatory depth. Cognitive Science, 26, 521–562.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rubin, E. L. (1998). Putting rational actors in their place: Economics and phenomenology symposium: the legal implications of psychology: Human behavior, behavioral economics, and the law. Vanderbilt Law Review, 51(6), 1705–1728. Rubin, E. L. (1998). Putting rational actors in their place: Economics and phenomenology symposium: the legal implications of psychology: Human behavior, behavioral economics, and the law. Vanderbilt Law Review, 51(6), 1705–1728.
Zurück zum Zitat Rubinfeld, D. L. Antitrust settlements. In Blair, R. D., Sokol, D. D. (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of international antitrust economics (pp. 172–186). Rubinfeld, D. L. Antitrust settlements. In Blair, R. D., Sokol, D. D. (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of international antitrust economics (pp. 172–186).
Zurück zum Zitat Samuelson, W., & Zeckhauser, R. (1988). Status quo bias in decision making. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 1(1), 7–59.CrossRef Samuelson, W., & Zeckhauser, R. (1988). Status quo bias in decision making. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 1(1), 7–59.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Schnellenbach, J., & Schubert, C. (2015). Behavioral political economy: A survey. European Journal of Political Economy, 40. Schnellenbach, J., & Schubert, C. (2015). Behavioral political economy: A survey. European Journal of Political Economy, 40.
Zurück zum Zitat Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). Capitalism, socialism and democracy. London: Routledge. Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). Capitalism, socialism and democracy. London: Routledge.
Zurück zum Zitat Segal, I., & Winston, M. D. (2007). Public vs private enforcement of antitrust law: A survey. European Competition Law Review, 28, 323–332. Segal, I., & Winston, M. D. (2007). Public vs private enforcement of antitrust law: A survey. European Competition Law Review, 28, 323–332.
Zurück zum Zitat Seidenfeld, M. (2002). Cognitive loafing, social conformity, and judicial review of agency rulemaking. Cornell Law Review, 87(2), 486–548. Seidenfeld, M. (2002). Cognitive loafing, social conformity, and judicial review of agency rulemaking. Cornell Law Review, 87(2), 486–548.
Zurück zum Zitat Shavell, S. (1984). Liability for harm versus regulation of safety. Journal of Legal Studies, 13, 357–374.CrossRef Shavell, S. (1984). Liability for harm versus regulation of safety. Journal of Legal Studies, 13, 357–374.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sheehan, R. S. (1990). Administrative agencies and the court: A reexamination of the impact of agency type on decisional outcomes. Western Political Quarterly, 43(December), 875–85. Sheehan, R. S. (1990). Administrative agencies and the court: A reexamination of the impact of agency type on decisional outcomes. Western Political Quarterly, 43(December), 875–85.
Zurück zum Zitat Shugart II, W. F. (1995). Public choice theory and antitrust policy. In McChesney, F. S. & Shughart II, W. F. (Eds.), The causes and consequences of antitrust: The public-choice perspective. University of Chicago Press. Shugart II, W. F. (1995). Public choice theory and antitrust policy. In McChesney, F. S. & Shughart II, W. F. (Eds.), The causes and consequences of antitrust: The public-choice perspective. University of Chicago Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Simon, H. A. (1955). A behavioral model of rational choice. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 69, 99–118.CrossRef Simon, H. A. (1955). A behavioral model of rational choice. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 69, 99–118.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Simon, H. A. (1957). Rational choice and the structure of the environment. In Models of man: social and rational. New York: Wiley. Simon, H. A. (1957). Rational choice and the structure of the environment. In Models of man: social and rational. New York: Wiley.
Zurück zum Zitat Simon, H. A. (1979). Rational decision making in business organizations. American Economic Review, 69(4), 493–513. Simon, H. A. (1979). Rational decision making in business organizations. American Economic Review, 69(4), 493–513.
Zurück zum Zitat Simon, D. (2004). The third view of the black box: Cognitive coherence in legal decision making. The University of Chicago Law Review, 71(2), 511–586. Simon, D. (2004). The third view of the black box: Cognitive coherence in legal decision making. The University of Chicago Law Review, 71(2), 511–586.
Zurück zum Zitat Simon, D., & Scurich, N. (2011). Lay judgments of judicial decision making. Journal of Empirical Legal Studies, 8(4), 709–727.CrossRef Simon, D., & Scurich, N. (2011). Lay judgments of judicial decision making. Journal of Empirical Legal Studies, 8(4), 709–727.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Simonson, I., & Tversky, A. (1992). Choice in context: Tradeoff contrasts and extremeness aversion. Journal of Marketing Research, 29(3), 281–295.CrossRef Simonson, I., & Tversky, A. (1992). Choice in context: Tradeoff contrasts and extremeness aversion. Journal of Marketing Research, 29(3), 281–295.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Slovic, P., & Fishhoff, B. (1977). On the psychology of experimental surprises. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance, 3, 544–551. Slovic, P., & Fishhoff, B. (1977). On the psychology of experimental surprises. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance, 3, 544–551.
Zurück zum Zitat Sokol, D. (2012a). The strategic use of public and private litigation in antitrust. Southern California Law Review, 85, 689–732. Sokol, D. (2012a). The strategic use of public and private litigation in antitrust. Southern California Law Review, 85, 689–732.
Zurück zum Zitat Sokol, D. (2012b). Cartels, corporate compliance, and what practitioners really think about enforcement. Antitrust Law Journal, 78, 201–240. Sokol, D. (2012b). Cartels, corporate compliance, and what practitioners really think about enforcement. Antitrust Law Journal, 78, 201–240.
Zurück zum Zitat Stucke, M. E. (2007). Behavioral economics at the gate: Antitrust in the twenty-First century. Loyola University Chicago Law Journal, 38, 513–591. Stucke, M. E. (2007). Behavioral economics at the gate: Antitrust in the twenty-First century. Loyola University Chicago Law Journal, 38, 513–591.
Zurück zum Zitat Sunstein, C. (1997). Behavioral analysis of law. University of Chicago Law Review, 64, 1175–1196.CrossRef Sunstein, C. (1997). Behavioral analysis of law. University of Chicago Law Review, 64, 1175–1196.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sunstein, C. R. (2014). Why nudge? The politics of libertarian paternalism. Yale University Press. Sunstein, C. R. (2014). Why nudge? The politics of libertarian paternalism. Yale University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Svenson, O. (1981). Are we all less risky and more skillful than our fellow drivers? Acta Psychologica, 47(2), 143–148.CrossRef Svenson, O. (1981). Are we all less risky and more skillful than our fellow drivers? Acta Psychologica, 47(2), 143–148.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tasic, S. (2009). The illusion of regulatory competence. Critical Review, 21(4), 423–436.CrossRef Tasic, S. (2009). The illusion of regulatory competence. Critical Review, 21(4), 423–436.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Taylor, S. E., & Brown, J. D. (1988). Illusion and well-being: A social psychological perspective on mental health. Psychological Bulletin, 103(2), 193–210.CrossRef Taylor, S. E., & Brown, J. D. (1988). Illusion and well-being: A social psychological perspective on mental health. Psychological Bulletin, 103(2), 193–210.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1982). Judgements of and by representatives. In Kahneman, D., Slovic, P., & Tversky, A. (Eds.), Judgement under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Cambridge University Press. Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1982). Judgements of and by representatives. In Kahneman, D., Slovic, P., & Tversky, A. (Eds.), Judgement under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1973). Availability: A heuristic for judging frequency and probability. Cognitive Psychology, 4, 207–232.CrossRef Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1973). Availability: A heuristic for judging frequency and probability. Cognitive Psychology, 4, 207–232.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science, 185, 1124–1131.CrossRef Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science, 185, 1124–1131.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1991). Loss aversion in riskless choice: A reference-dependent model. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(4), 1039–1061.CrossRef Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1991). Loss aversion in riskless choice: A reference-dependent model. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(4), 1039–1061.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1992). Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5, 297–323.CrossRef Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1992). Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5, 297–323.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Van den Bergh, R. (2013). Behavioral antitrust: Not ready for the main stage. Journal of Competition Law and Economics, 9(1), 203–229.CrossRef Van den Bergh, R. (2013). Behavioral antitrust: Not ready for the main stage. Journal of Competition Law and Economics, 9(1), 203–229.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Viscusi, W. K. (1995). Carcinogen regulation: risk characteristics and biases in policy decisions. American Economic Review (Papers and Proceedings), 85(2), 50–54. Viscusi, W. K. (1995). Carcinogen regulation: risk characteristics and biases in policy decisions. American Economic Review (Papers and Proceedings), 85(2), 50–54.
Zurück zum Zitat Viscusi, W. K., & Gayer, T. (2015). Behavioral public choice: The behavioral paradox of government policy. Harvard Journal of Law and Public Policy, 38, 973–1007. Viscusi, W. K., & Gayer, T. (2015). Behavioral public choice: The behavioral paradox of government policy. Harvard Journal of Law and Public Policy, 38, 973–1007.
Zurück zum Zitat Viscusi, W. K., & Hamilton, J. T. (1999). Are risk regulators rational? Evidence from hazardous waste cleanup decisions. The American Economic Review, 89(4), 1010–1027.CrossRef Viscusi, W. K., & Hamilton, J. T. (1999). Are risk regulators rational? Evidence from hazardous waste cleanup decisions. The American Economic Review, 89(4), 1010–1027.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Viscusi, W. K., & Magat, W. A. (1987). Learning about risk: Consumer and worker responses to hazard information. Harvard University Press. Viscusi, W. K., & Magat, W. A. (1987). Learning about risk: Consumer and worker responses to hazard information. Harvard University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Weinstein, N. D. (1980). Unrealistic optimism about future life events. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 39(5), 806–820.CrossRef Weinstein, N. D. (1980). Unrealistic optimism about future life events. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 39(5), 806–820.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
The Enforcement of Competition Law—A Behavioral Law and Economics Perspective
verfasst von
Jingyuan Ma
Copyright-Jahr
2020
Verlag
Springer Singapore
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-15-5105-5_12

Premium Partner