Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Public Choice 1-2/2020

19.07.2019

The failure of a Nazi “killer” amendment

verfasst von: Andreas Kleiner, Benny Moldovanu

Erschienen in: Public Choice | Ausgabe 1-2/2020

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

We describe a remarkable instance of a motion-proposing and agenda-setting strategy by the Nazi party, NSDAP, during the Weimar Republic. Their purpose was to kill a motion of toleration of the new 1928 government, that would have allowed the government to continue in office without expressing confidence in it. The Nazi party was supported by their fiercest enemies on the far left, the communist party, but the combined killer strategy ultimately failed because of another agenda-setting counter-move undertaken by the Reichstag’s president. In order to understand and analyze that case we also briefly study killer amendments under various informational regimes and postulated voter behavior. In particular, the chances of success of killer amendments are shown to differ across several well-known binary, sequential voting procedures and across legislative agendas.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
Pedersen (2014) contains a rare case from outside the United States. The Danish parliament described there also uses an amendment procedure.
 
2
See, for example, Fenno (1978) and Denzau et al. (1985).
 
3
Since procedural rules in many European countries lead to similar agendas, our insight provides an additional rationale for the empirical rarity of killer amendments in those countries.
 
4
It is worth recalling here that Poole and Rosenthal (1997) actually test for the occurrence of such coalitions as a proxy for political “manipulations” involving insincere voting.
 
5
Adolf Trendelenburg, 1802–1872, was a well known philosopher, member of the parliament of Prussia and of the American Academy of Arts and Sciences. His lecture is the oldest essay specifically dealing with agenda formation in the successive voting procedure. It precedes the slightly better known work by Heckscher (1892).
 
6
The reverse order is logically equivalent.
 
7
Note that with single-peaked preferences, a voter with peak on S ranks A last.
 
8
More generally, even if preferences are not single-peaked, Enelow and Koehler (1980) showed that killer amendments can never be successful under sophisticated voting with complete information.
 
9
The conclusion also follows more generally form Proposition 1 in Miller (1977): similarly to sophisticated voting, sincere voting in the amendment procedure always selects an element in the Condorcet set (which contains a unique element in our setting with single-peaked preferences).
 
10
The article represented a significant generalization with respect to the standard literature on binary sequential voting that almost invariably assumes complete information. Important previous studies assuming incomplete information are Ordeshook and Palfrey (1988) and Gershkov et al. (2017).
 
11
Responsiveness is a very mild equilibrium refinement whose main role is to rule out equilibria where other strategies become optimal because they do not actually matter, for example, because all other voters always vote for the first motion.
 
12
Some cardinalization is needed here because, under incomplete information, lotteries among alternatives also must be considered in some cases.
 
13
Müller already served as Chancellor in the past, explaining the suffix “II”.
 
14
It is a peculiarity of the Weimar constitution that non-confidence motions also could be brought against individual ministers.
 
15
Spa is a well-known Belgian resort with thermal springs.
 
16
The Weimar Republic had 20 cabinets (and 13 chancellors) in less than 14 years. Ten of these governments had no majority support in parliament. See, for example, Winkler (1993).
 
17
The Wirtschaftspartei (WP) mainly focused on economic interests of landlords. Its members abstained in all relevant decisions pertaining to the case being considered.
 
18
The logic is not completely transparent here. President Löbe argued that both C and T contain the tabling of other motions and thus needed to be voted on before NC.
 
19
According to the post-National-Assembly interpretation of Article 54, a cabinet nominated by the republic’s president (after consultations with the parties) has parliament’s confidence until “factually” proven otherwise (see Huber 1981, p. 333); the question was whether defeat of a motion of confidence constituted factual proof or not.
 
20
Austen-Smith (1987) looks at a sequential agenda formation game when the agenda is built sequentially while motions are being proposed. Here, motions also were sequentially presented, but a vote to choose among different agendas was undertaken only after all motions had been presented. See also Dutta et al. (2004) and Barbera and Gerber (2017) for other games of endogenous agenda formation.
 
21
A few surviving communist members of the Reichstag, such as Walter Ulbricht, became top political figures in the post-WWII German Democratic Republic.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Austen-Smith, D. (1987). Sophisticated sincerity: Voting over endogenous agendas. American Journal of Political Science, 36, 68–95.CrossRef Austen-Smith, D. (1987). Sophisticated sincerity: Voting over endogenous agendas. American Journal of Political Science, 36, 68–95.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Barbera, S., & Gerber, A. (2017). Sequential voting and agenda manipulation. Theoretical Economics, 12, 211–247.CrossRef Barbera, S., & Gerber, A. (2017). Sequential voting and agenda manipulation. Theoretical Economics, 12, 211–247.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bilfinger, C. (1931). Die Geschäftsordnung der Reichstags und die Grenzen der parlamentarischen Systems. ZaöRV, 2, 439–454. Bilfinger, C. (1931). Die Geschäftsordnung der Reichstags und die Grenzen der parlamentarischen Systems. ZaöRV, 2, 439–454.
Zurück zum Zitat Denzau, A., Riker, W., & Shepsle, K. (1985). Farquharson and Fenno: Sophisticated voting and home style. The American Political Science Review, 79, 1117–1134.CrossRef Denzau, A., Riker, W., & Shepsle, K. (1985). Farquharson and Fenno: Sophisticated voting and home style. The American Political Science Review, 79, 1117–1134.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dutta, B., Jackson, M. O., & Le Breton, M. (2004). Equilibrium agenda formation. Social Choice and Welfare, 23, 21–57.CrossRef Dutta, B., Jackson, M. O., & Le Breton, M. (2004). Equilibrium agenda formation. Social Choice and Welfare, 23, 21–57.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Enelow, J., & Koehler, D. (1980). The amendment in legislative strategy: Sophisticated voting in the U.S. Congress. Journal of Politics, 42, 396–413.CrossRef Enelow, J., & Koehler, D. (1980). The amendment in legislative strategy: Sophisticated voting in the U.S. Congress. Journal of Politics, 42, 396–413.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Farquharson, R. (1969). The theory of voting. New Haven: Yale University Press. Farquharson, R. (1969). The theory of voting. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Fenno, R. F. (1978). Home style. Boston: Little Brown. Fenno, R. F. (1978). Home style. Boston: Little Brown.
Zurück zum Zitat Finocchiaro, C. J., & Jenkins, J. A. (2008). In search of killer amendments in the modern U.S. House. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 33(2), 263–294.CrossRef Finocchiaro, C. J., & Jenkins, J. A. (2008). In search of killer amendments in the modern U.S. House. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 33(2), 263–294.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gershkov, A., Moldovanu, B., & Shi, X. (2017). Optimal voting rules. Review of Economic Studies, 84(2), 688–717. Gershkov, A., Moldovanu, B., & Shi, X. (2017). Optimal voting rules. Review of Economic Studies, 84(2), 688–717.
Zurück zum Zitat Groseclose, T., & Milyo, J. (2010). Sincere versus sophisticated voting in Congress: Theory and evidence. The Journal of Politics, 72(1), 60–73.CrossRef Groseclose, T., & Milyo, J. (2010). Sincere versus sophisticated voting in Congress: Theory and evidence. The Journal of Politics, 72(1), 60–73.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Heckscher, A. (1892). Bidrag til grundlæggelse af en afstemningslære. Om methoderne ved udfindelse af stemmerflerhed i parlamenter (afsteming over ændringforslag m.v.) ved valg og domstole. Københa- ven: Universitetsboghandler G. E. C. Gad. Heckscher, A. (1892). Bidrag til grundlæggelse af en afstemningslære. Om methoderne ved udfindelse af stemmerflerhed i parlamenter (afsteming over ændringforslag m.v.) ved valg og domstole. Københa- ven: Universitetsboghandler G. E. C. Gad.
Zurück zum Zitat Huber, E. R. (1981). Deutsche Verfassungsgeschichte seit 1789 (Vol. 7). Stuttgart: Kohlhammer. Huber, E. R. (1981). Deutsche Verfassungsgeschichte seit 1789 (Vol. 7). Stuttgart: Kohlhammer.
Zurück zum Zitat Jenkins, J. A., & Munger, M. C. (2003). Investigating the incidence of killer amendments in congress. Journal of Politics, 65, 498–517.CrossRef Jenkins, J. A., & Munger, M. C. (2003). Investigating the incidence of killer amendments in congress. Journal of Politics, 65, 498–517.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kleiner, A., & Moldovanu, B. (2017). Content-based agendas and qualified majorities in sequential, binary voting. American Economic Review, 107(6), 1477–1506.CrossRef Kleiner, A., & Moldovanu, B. (2017). Content-based agendas and qualified majorities in sequential, binary voting. American Economic Review, 107(6), 1477–1506.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Miller, N. R. (1977). Graph-theoretical approaches to the theory of voting. American Journal of Political Science, 21(4), 769–803.CrossRef Miller, N. R. (1977). Graph-theoretical approaches to the theory of voting. American Journal of Political Science, 21(4), 769–803.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat McKelvey, R. D., & Niemi, R. G. (1978). A multi-stage game representation of sophisticated voting for binary procedures. Journal of Economic Theory, 18, 1–22.CrossRef McKelvey, R. D., & Niemi, R. G. (1978). A multi-stage game representation of sophisticated voting for binary procedures. Journal of Economic Theory, 18, 1–22.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Moulin, H. (1979). Dominance solvable voting schemes. Econometrica, 47, 1337–1351.CrossRef Moulin, H. (1979). Dominance solvable voting schemes. Econometrica, 47, 1337–1351.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ordeshook, P. C., & Palfrey, T. R. (1988). Agendas, strategic voting, and signaling with incomplete information. American Journal of Political Science, 32(2), 441–463.CrossRef Ordeshook, P. C., & Palfrey, T. R. (1988). Agendas, strategic voting, and signaling with incomplete information. American Journal of Political Science, 32(2), 441–463.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pedersen, M. N. (2014). A Danish killer amendment—when judicial review was banned from the 1849 Constitution. Public Choice, 158, 513–523.CrossRef Pedersen, M. N. (2014). A Danish killer amendment—when judicial review was banned from the 1849 Constitution. Public Choice, 158, 513–523.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Poole, K. T., & Rosenthal, H. (1997). Congress: A political and economic history of roll call voting. New York: Oxford University Press. Poole, K. T., & Rosenthal, H. (1997). Congress: A political and economic history of roll call voting. New York: Oxford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Riker, W. (1986). The art of political manipulation. New Haven: Yale University Press. Riker, W. (1986). The art of political manipulation. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Tecklenburg, A. (1914). Die parlamentarische Beschlussfassung. Jahrbuch für öffentliches Recht, 8, 75–99. Tecklenburg, A. (1914). Die parlamentarische Beschlussfassung. Jahrbuch für öffentliches Recht, 8, 75–99.
Zurück zum Zitat Trendelenburg, A. (1850). Über die Methode bei Abstimmungen. Berlin: Gustav Bethge. Trendelenburg, A. (1850). Über die Methode bei Abstimmungen. Berlin: Gustav Bethge.
Zurück zum Zitat Thiele, C. (2008). Abstimmungsverfahren. In: Regeln und Verfahren der Entscheidungsfindung innerhalb von Staaten und Staatenverbindungen. Berlin: Springer. Thiele, C. (2008). Abstimmungsverfahren. In: Regeln und Verfahren der Entscheidungsfindung innerhalb von Staaten und Staatenverbindungen. Berlin: Springer.
Zurück zum Zitat Wilkerson, J. D. (1990). Killer amendments in congress. American Political Science Review, 93, 535–552.CrossRef Wilkerson, J. D. (1990). Killer amendments in congress. American Political Science Review, 93, 535–552.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Winkler, H. A. (1993). Weimar 1918–1933. München: C. H. Beck. Winkler, H. A. (1993). Weimar 1918–1933. München: C. H. Beck.
Metadaten
Titel
The failure of a Nazi “killer” amendment
verfasst von
Andreas Kleiner
Benny Moldovanu
Publikationsdatum
19.07.2019
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Public Choice / Ausgabe 1-2/2020
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00691-7

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 1-2/2020

Public Choice 1-2/2020 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner