Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Empirical Economics 2/2022

14.03.2021

The structure of risk-sharing networks

verfasst von: Heath Henderson, Arnob Alam

Erschienen in: Empirical Economics | Ausgabe 2/2022

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

We examine the structure of risk-sharing networks in developing countries using data from the Tanzanian village of Nyakatoke. We first show that the Nyakatoke network exhibits: (1) the “small-world” phenomenon, where two households who are not themselves risk-sharing partners are separated only by a short chain of intermediaries; (2) preferential attachment, which is a network formation process where the probability of a household receiving a partner is proportional to that household’s existing number of partners; and (3) assortative mixing, as similarly connected households tend to link to each other. We then examine the implications of these features for network performance by comparing the Nyakatoke network to simulated networks with alternative structural traits. Our simulations show that the Nyakatoke network displays optimal or near-optimal performance along multiple dimensions. In particular, the Nyakatoke network has a notable ability to withstand perturbations of multiple types, a property that none of the counterfactual networks possess.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
Section 5 provides a discussion of the implications of our results for the theoretical network formation literature. Here we only comment on those studies with direct relevance to our research question. See Wahhaj (2010), Ambrus et al. (2014, 2015), Grandjean (2014), Milán (2016), or Ambrus et al. (2017) for other theoretical work in this area.
 
2
In a similar model, Bramoullé and Kranton (2007b) studied risk-sharing networks across communities. While they found that the formation of cross-community links reduces risk sharing within a village, the net welfare effect can be positive.
 
3
Caudell et al. (2015) also considered some network formation-oriented questions. In particular, the authors examined the relationship between individual attributes and the number of times a person was named as a lender. They found that males are more likely to be cited as a lender and the probability of them being so increases with their herd size.
 
4
A couple of other studies do explicitly recognize the role of structure in risk-sharing networks, but this is typically in the context of examining network formation. For example, Comola (2010) examined whether agents choose risk-sharing partners based on their location in the network. Using data from Tanzania, the author found that location matters, as agents prefer wealthy contacts with few additional risk-sharing partners. For an example of a similar finding in the context of labor-sharing networks in Ethiopia, see Krishnan and Sciubba (2009).
 
5
See Jackson and Rogers (2007) for a discussion of structural features commonly observed in social networks.
 
6
Using only internal links is common with these data. See, for example, De Weerdt (2004) or Comola and Fafchamps (2014).
 
7
The authors report that of all \(119 \times 118 = 14\),042 dyads, 700 are discordant. See their Table 2 for more information.
 
8
Comola and Fafchamps (2014) assume that discordant responses are the result of underreporting and test whether the data are best interpreted as representing existing links or desired links. As mentioned above, they further distinguish between two interpretations of existing links: bilateral and unilateral. Bilateral links are existing links formed in mutual self-interest, whereas unilateral links are formed at the request of either party. In the Nyakatoke data, the desire-to-link model outperforms both the bilateral and unilateral models in a likelihood ratio-based framework for testing non-nested models.
 
9
See Bloch et al. (2008) for an example of how the flow of information is central to the behavior of risk-sharing networks.
 
10
Reciprocated links are counted twice under the desire-to-link assumption because the network is directed. The underreporting and overreporting scenarios result in undirected networks, so each link is only counted once. Multiplying the number of links for the underreporting and overreporting scenarios by two allows one to see how many links are added or deleted (relative to the desire-to-link scenario) when imposing these assumptions. For example, the desire-to-link scenario has 630 links, 350 of which are discordant. When imposing the underreporting assumption, we add the “missing” links until all relationships are reciprocated. This yields a total of \(630 + 350 = 980\) links, which is twice that reported for the number of links associated with underreporting.
 
11
As a result, the average degree cannot vary across simulations for the random network, which is why we do not report a standard deviation.
 
12
Note that there is a natural ordering of these statistics: as we go from underreporting, to desire-to-link, and then to overreporting, we are progressively deleting links, which serves to increase average distance.
 
13
The CCDF is simply one minus the cumulative distribution function.
 
14
See Table 1 for information on the average degree for each case.
 
15
Preferential attachment is embodied in this case as nodes with higher degrees are more likely to be found through the network-based meeting process.
 
16
The Jackson–Rogers model is a growing random network, so the degree distribution for this case differs from the static Erdös–Rényi network.
 
17
The authors put forth the following two-step procedure for estimating r: first, set \(\eta _0=0\) and m to the average degree observed in the Nyakatoke data. For undirected cases, m should be set to half of the average degree. Second, estimate r through an iterative least squares procedure. Starting with some initial value \(r_0\), regress \(\ln [1 - F(\eta )]\) on \(\ln (\eta + r_0 m)\) to estimate \(-(1 + r)\) and get an estimate \(r_1\). Repeat this process until a fixed point \(r^*\) is located. Note that we estimated each of our models with different starting values, and the results do not change.
 
18
Recall that assortative mixing occurs when high-degree nodes tend to link to other high-degree nodes, and disassortative mixing occurs when high-degree nodes link to low-degree nodes. See Appendix for further discussion and a definition of the degree correlation coefficient.
 
19
Perfect assortativity results when all nodes of a particular degree only connect to other nodes with that same degree. That is, perfect assortativity is associated with a group-like network structure.
 
20
Recall that a node’s excess degree is the node’s degree minus one.
 
21
This statistical significance also occurs for the in-degree correlation coefficient for that network (p-value = 0.02), for which we find \(\rho = 0.09\).
 
22
Note that a full consideration of diffusion processes (i.e., how shocks propagate through the network) is beyond the scope of this paper. See Newman (2010) for detailed discussion.
 
23
For the process to be well defined, the network must be initialized properly. The reader is referred to Jackson and Rogers (2007) for details regarding initialization.
 
24
These results are averages across 10,000 simulations of the corresponding network. By corresponding network, we mean a network with the same number of nodes and links. For example, to simulate the counterfactual processes for the desire-to-link network, we generate growing random networks with 119 nodes and 630 links. Further, as the desire-to-link network is directed, the counterfactual networks are also generated as directed.
 
25
Note that our results are affected by the fact that our network is of a finite size, while theoretical results are based on networks of an arbitrary (infinite) size. See Newman (2010) or Boguñá et al. (2004) for a detailed discussion.
 
26
For the counterfactual processes, we generate a new network for each iteration. That is, for each iteration, we generate a network and then progressively remove nodes from that network at random.
 
27
The simple explanation for this result is that the variance of the overreporting network’s degree distribution is sufficiently close to that of the corresponding PA network.
 
28
The PA network lacks robustness to targeted attack because its structural integrity relies heavily on high-degree hubs, and so is quickly decimated by targeted attack. Purely random networks lack hubs, which implies that the effect of targeted attack is similar to random node removal (Barabási 2016).
 
29
We consider as valid any pixel that is even partially inside that region.
 
30
The rewiring performed once inside the target pixel is to ensure more uniform sampling. It is important that this rewiring does not lead the network to leave the pixel and, as such, any rewiring that does so is discarded.
 
31
Note that the white space in each panel represents invalid pixels. As such, we see that the shape of the valid region is consistent with the notion of a positive relationship between assortativity and clustering coefficients in social networks (Newman and Park 2003).
 
32
That component size tends to be smaller for assortative networks is consistent with Newman (2002, 2003).
 
33
It is also possible that assortativity is simply an unintentional by-product of a dynamic network formation process. In the Jackson and Rogers (2007) model, for example, assortativity results from the fact that older nodes are more likely to have higher degrees and be linked to each other.
 
34
For example, consider a star network, which is a tree that is perfectly disassortative.
 
35
Regular networks have undefined assortativity coefficients because the denominator in Eq. (A.3) is zero. While it is possible to have a well-defined assortativity coefficient for almost 2-regular networks, the coefficient will generally be close to one because nearly all nodes are connected to nodes with the same degree.
 
36
The data are publicly available at Banerjee et al. (2013b).
 
37
Specifically, the survey gathered network information along multiple dimensions, including friendship, family, religious affiliation, credit relationships, etc. We approximate the risk-sharing network in each village by taking the union of two different types of networks: borrowing/lending small amounts of cash and borrowing/lending kerosene or rice. We believe that these networks capture risk sharing, as the related survey questions specifically reference times of need. For example, the question related to borrowing small amounts of cash asks “If you suddenly needed to borrow Rs. 50 for a day, who would you ask?” See Sect. 2 for the comparable question from the Nyakatoke survey.
 
38
That is, for each village we simulated 10,000 random networks with the same number of nodes and links. We then calculated the actual clustering coefficient for each village and subtract from that number the average clustering coefficient across all associated random networks.
 
39
See Figure 1 in Huisman (2009). Note that Huisman did not find similar levels of bias for clustering coefficients. See Lee et al. (2006) for additional analysis of the bias associated with sampled networks.
 
40
For example, when randomly removing 54% of nodes in our overreporting network, we find an average clustering coefficient of 0.07 across 10,000 replications. This is comparable to the true clustering coefficient of 0.08.
 
41
Other studies examining the interaction between formal and informal insurance include Cox and Jakubson (1995), Cox and Jimenez (1995), Maitra and Ray (2003), Fan (2010), Janssens and Kramer (2016), and Strupat and Klohn (2018). Also see Chih (2016) for a related paper regarding the role of social networks in influencing the extent to which the government provision of public goods crowds out voluntary contributions.
 
42
For example, consider a situation where household 1 reports a link with household 2, but household 2 does not report household 1. In this case, we impute \(g^u_{12}=g^u_{21}=1\), \(g^o_{12}=g^o_{21}=0\), but let \(g^d_{12}=1 \ne 0 = g^d_{21}\).
 
43
See Jackson and Rogers (2007) for details and a discussion of alternative clustering coefficients. Here we have adopted what is known as a “global” clustering coefficient. An alternative “local” clustering coefficient calculates the proportion of transitive triples on a node-by-node basis and then averages across nodes.
 
44
A node’s excess degree is the node’s degree minus one.
 
45
Where \(p_j\) is the probability that a randomly chosen node has a degree of j, we have \(q_j = (j + 1)p_{j+1}/\sum _k k p_k\). It must also be the case that \(\sum _i e_{ij} = q_j\).
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Albert R, Jeong H, Barabási A (1999) Diameter of the world-wide web. Nature 401(6749):130–131 Albert R, Jeong H, Barabási A (1999) Diameter of the world-wide web. Nature 401(6749):130–131
Zurück zum Zitat Albert R, Jeong H, Barabási A (2000) Error and attack tolerance of complex networks. Nature 406(6794):378–382 Albert R, Jeong H, Barabási A (2000) Error and attack tolerance of complex networks. Nature 406(6794):378–382
Zurück zum Zitat Ambrus A, Mobius M, Szeidl A (2014) Consumption risk-sharing in social networks. Am Econ Rev 104(1):149–182 Ambrus A, Mobius M, Szeidl A (2014) Consumption risk-sharing in social networks. Am Econ Rev 104(1):149–182
Zurück zum Zitat Ambrus A, Chandrasekhar A, Elliott M (2015) Social investments, informal risk sharing, and inequality. eRID Working Paper No. 179 Ambrus A, Chandrasekhar A, Elliott M (2015) Social investments, informal risk sharing, and inequality. eRID Working Paper No. 179
Zurück zum Zitat Attanasio O, Barr A, Cardenas J, Genicot G, Meghir C (2012) Risk pooling, risk preferences, and social networks. Am Econ J Appl Econ 4(2):134–167 Attanasio O, Barr A, Cardenas J, Genicot G, Meghir C (2012) Risk pooling, risk preferences, and social networks. Am Econ J Appl Econ 4(2):134–167
Zurück zum Zitat Bakshi RK, Mallick D, Ulubaşoğlu MA (2019) Social capital as a coping mechanism for seasonal deprivation: the case of the Monga in Bangladesh. Empir Econ 57(1):239–262 Bakshi RK, Mallick D, Ulubaşoğlu MA (2019) Social capital as a coping mechanism for seasonal deprivation: the case of the Monga in Bangladesh. Empir Econ 57(1):239–262
Zurück zum Zitat Baltagi BH, Deng Y, Ma X (2018) Network effects on labor contracts of internal migrants in China: a spatial autoregressive model. Empir Econ 55(1):265–296 Baltagi BH, Deng Y, Ma X (2018) Network effects on labor contracts of internal migrants in China: a spatial autoregressive model. Empir Econ 55(1):265–296
Zurück zum Zitat Banerjee A, Chandrasekhar AG, Duflo E, Jackson MO (2013a) The diffusion of microfinance. Science 341(6144):1236498 Banerjee A, Chandrasekhar AG, Duflo E, Jackson MO (2013a) The diffusion of microfinance. Science 341(6144):1236498
Zurück zum Zitat Barabási A (2016) Network science. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge Barabási A (2016) Network science. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
Zurück zum Zitat Barabási A, Albert R (1999) Emergence of scaling in random networks. Science 286(5439):509–512 Barabási A, Albert R (1999) Emergence of scaling in random networks. Science 286(5439):509–512
Zurück zum Zitat Barabási A, Albert R, Jeong H (1999) Mean-field theory for scale-free random networks. Physica A Stat Mech Appl 272(1):173–187 Barabási A, Albert R, Jeong H (1999) Mean-field theory for scale-free random networks. Physica A Stat Mech Appl 272(1):173–187
Zurück zum Zitat Barr A, Genicot G (2008) Risk sharing, commitment, and information: an experimental analysis. J Eur Econ Assoc 6(6):1151–1185 Barr A, Genicot G (2008) Risk sharing, commitment, and information: an experimental analysis. J Eur Econ Assoc 6(6):1151–1185
Zurück zum Zitat Barr A, Dekker M, Fafchamps M (2012) Who shares risk with whom under different enforcement mechanisms? Econ Dev Cult Change 60(4):677–706 Barr A, Dekker M, Fafchamps M (2012) Who shares risk with whom under different enforcement mechanisms? Econ Dev Cult Change 60(4):677–706
Zurück zum Zitat Bloch F, Genicot G, Ray D (2008) Informal insurance in social networks. J Econ Theory 143(1):36–58 Bloch F, Genicot G, Ray D (2008) Informal insurance in social networks. J Econ Theory 143(1):36–58
Zurück zum Zitat Boguñá M, Pastor-Satorras R, Vespignani A (2004) Cut-offs and finite size effects in scale-free networks. Eur Phys J B 38(2):205–209 Boguñá M, Pastor-Satorras R, Vespignani A (2004) Cut-offs and finite size effects in scale-free networks. Eur Phys J B 38(2):205–209
Zurück zum Zitat Boorman S (1975) A combinatorial optimization model for transmission of job information through contact networks. Bell J Econ 6(1):216–249 Boorman S (1975) A combinatorial optimization model for transmission of job information through contact networks. Bell J Econ 6(1):216–249
Zurück zum Zitat Bramoullé Y, Kranton R (2007a) Risk-sharing networks. J Econ Behav Organ 64(3):275–294 Bramoullé Y, Kranton R (2007a) Risk-sharing networks. J Econ Behav Organ 64(3):275–294
Zurück zum Zitat Bramoullé Y, Kranton R (2007b) Risk sharing across communities. Am Econ Rev 97(2):70–74 Bramoullé Y, Kranton R (2007b) Risk sharing across communities. Am Econ Rev 97(2):70–74
Zurück zum Zitat Callaway D, Newman M, Strogatz S, Watts D (2000) Network robustness and fragility: percolation on random graphs. Phys Rev Lett 85(25):5468–5471 Callaway D, Newman M, Strogatz S, Watts D (2000) Network robustness and fragility: percolation on random graphs. Phys Rev Lett 85(25):5468–5471
Zurück zum Zitat Caudell M, Rotolo T, Grima M (2015) Informal lending networks in rural Ethiopia. Soc Netw 40:34–42 Caudell M, Rotolo T, Grima M (2015) Informal lending networks in rural Ethiopia. Soc Netw 40:34–42
Zurück zum Zitat Chih Y (2016) Social network structure and government provision crowding-out on voluntary contributions. J Behav Exp Econ 63:83–90 Chih Y (2016) Social network structure and government provision crowding-out on voluntary contributions. J Behav Exp Econ 63:83–90
Zurück zum Zitat Cohen R, Erez K, Ben-Avraham D, Havlin S (2000) Resilience of the internet to random breakdowns. Phys Rev Lett 85(21):4626–4628 Cohen R, Erez K, Ben-Avraham D, Havlin S (2000) Resilience of the internet to random breakdowns. Phys Rev Lett 85(21):4626–4628
Zurück zum Zitat Comola M (2010) The network structure of mutual support links: evidence from rural Tanzania. pSE Working papers no. 2008-74 Comola M (2010) The network structure of mutual support links: evidence from rural Tanzania. pSE Working papers no. 2008-74
Zurück zum Zitat Comola M, Fafchamps M (2014) Testing unilateral and bilateral link formation. Econ J 124(579):954–976 Comola M, Fafchamps M (2014) Testing unilateral and bilateral link formation. Econ J 124(579):954–976
Zurück zum Zitat Comola M, Fafchamps M (2017) The missing transfers: estimating misreporting in dyadic data. Econ Dev Cult Change 65(3):549–582 Comola M, Fafchamps M (2017) The missing transfers: estimating misreporting in dyadic data. Econ Dev Cult Change 65(3):549–582
Zurück zum Zitat Cox D, Jakubson G (1995) The connection between public transfers and private interfamily transfers. J Publ Econ 57(1):129–167 Cox D, Jakubson G (1995) The connection between public transfers and private interfamily transfers. J Publ Econ 57(1):129–167
Zurück zum Zitat Cox D, Jimenez E (1995) Private transfers and the effectiveness of public income redistribution in the Philippines. In: van de Walle D, Nead K (eds) Public spending and the poor: theory and evidence. Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore Cox D, Jimenez E (1995) Private transfers and the effectiveness of public income redistribution in the Philippines. In: van de Walle D, Nead K (eds) Public spending and the poor: theory and evidence. Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore
Zurück zum Zitat De Weerdt J (2004) Risk-sharing and endogenous network formation. In: Dercon S (ed) Insurance against poverty. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 197–216 De Weerdt J (2004) Risk-sharing and endogenous network formation. In: Dercon S (ed) Insurance against poverty. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 197–216
Zurück zum Zitat De Weerdt J, Dercon S (2006) Risk-sharing networks and insurance against illness. J Dev Econ 81(2):337–356 De Weerdt J, Dercon S (2006) Risk-sharing networks and insurance against illness. J Dev Econ 81(2):337–356
Zurück zum Zitat De Weerdt J, Fafchamps M (2011) Social identity and the formation of health insurance networks. J Dev Stud 47(8):1152–1177 De Weerdt J, Fafchamps M (2011) Social identity and the formation of health insurance networks. J Dev Stud 47(8):1152–1177
Zurück zum Zitat Dercon S, De Weerdt J, Bold T, Pankhurst A (2006) Group-based funeral insurance in Ethiopia and Tanzania. World Dev 34(4):685–703 Dercon S, De Weerdt J, Bold T, Pankhurst A (2006) Group-based funeral insurance in Ethiopia and Tanzania. World Dev 34(4):685–703
Zurück zum Zitat Erdös P, Rényi A (1959) On random graphs. Publ Math Debr 6:290–297 Erdös P, Rényi A (1959) On random graphs. Publ Math Debr 6:290–297
Zurück zum Zitat Erdös P, Rényi A (1960) On the evolution of random graphs. Publ Math Inst Hung Acad Sci 5:17–61 Erdös P, Rényi A (1960) On the evolution of random graphs. Publ Math Inst Hung Acad Sci 5:17–61
Zurück zum Zitat Fafchamps M, Gubert F (2007) The formation of risk sharing networks. J Dev Econ 83(2):326–350 Fafchamps M, Gubert F (2007) The formation of risk sharing networks. J Dev Econ 83(2):326–350
Zurück zum Zitat Fafchamps M, Lund S (2003) Risk-sharing networks in rural Philippines. J Dev Econ 71(2):261–287 Fafchamps M, Lund S (2003) Risk-sharing networks in rural Philippines. J Dev Econ 71(2):261–287
Zurück zum Zitat Fan E (2010) Who benefits from public old age pensions? Evidence from a targeted program. Econ Dev Cult Change 58(2):297–322 Fan E (2010) Who benefits from public old age pensions? Evidence from a targeted program. Econ Dev Cult Change 58(2):297–322
Zurück zum Zitat Furusawa T, Konishi H (2007) Free trade networks. J Int Econ 72(2):310–335 Furusawa T, Konishi H (2007) Free trade networks. J Int Econ 72(2):310–335
Zurück zum Zitat Gao W, Moon E (2016) Informal insurance networks. BE J Theor Econ 16(2):455–484 Gao W, Moon E (2016) Informal insurance networks. BE J Theor Econ 16(2):455–484
Zurück zum Zitat Goyal S, Van Der Leij M, Moraga-González J (2006) Economics: an emerging small world. J Polit Econ 114(2):403–412 Goyal S, Van Der Leij M, Moraga-González J (2006) Economics: an emerging small world. J Polit Econ 114(2):403–412
Zurück zum Zitat Grandjean G (2014) Risk-sharing networks and farsighted stability. Rev Econ Des 18(3):191–218 Grandjean G (2014) Risk-sharing networks and farsighted stability. Rev Econ Des 18(3):191–218
Zurück zum Zitat Granovetter M (2005) The impact of social structure on economic outcomes. J Econ Perspect 19(1):33–50 Granovetter M (2005) The impact of social structure on economic outcomes. J Econ Perspect 19(1):33–50
Zurück zum Zitat Holme P, Zhao J (2007) Exploring the assortativity-clustering space of a network’s degree sequence. Phys Rev E 75(4):046111 Holme P, Zhao J (2007) Exploring the assortativity-clustering space of a network’s degree sequence. Phys Rev E 75(4):046111
Zurück zum Zitat Huisman M (2009) Imputation of missing network data: some simple procedures. J Soc Struct 10(1):1–29 Huisman M (2009) Imputation of missing network data: some simple procedures. J Soc Struct 10(1):1–29
Zurück zum Zitat Jackson M (2005) The economics of social networks. California Institute of Technology Social Science working paper 1237 Jackson M (2005) The economics of social networks. California Institute of Technology Social Science working paper 1237
Zurück zum Zitat Jackson M (2008) Social and economic networks. Princeton University Press, Princeton Jackson M (2008) Social and economic networks. Princeton University Press, Princeton
Zurück zum Zitat Jackson M (2011) An overview of social networks and economic applications. In: Benhabib J, Bisin A, Jackson M (eds) Handbook of social economics, vol 1. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 511–585 Jackson M (2011) An overview of social networks and economic applications. In: Benhabib J, Bisin A, Jackson M (eds) Handbook of social economics, vol 1. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 511–585
Zurück zum Zitat Jackson M (2014) Networks in the understanding of economic behaviors. J Econ Perspect 28(4):3–22 Jackson M (2014) Networks in the understanding of economic behaviors. J Econ Perspect 28(4):3–22
Zurück zum Zitat Jackson M, Rogers B (2007) Meeting strangers and friends of friends: How random are social networks? Am Econ Rev 97(3):890–915 Jackson M, Rogers B (2007) Meeting strangers and friends of friends: How random are social networks? Am Econ Rev 97(3):890–915
Zurück zum Zitat Jackson M, Rodriguez-Barraquer T, Tan X (2012) Social capital and social quilts: network patterns of favor exchange. Am Econ Rev 102(5):1857–1897 Jackson M, Rodriguez-Barraquer T, Tan X (2012) Social capital and social quilts: network patterns of favor exchange. Am Econ Rev 102(5):1857–1897
Zurück zum Zitat Jackson M, Rogers B, Zenou Y (2017) The economic consequences of social-network structure. J Econ Lit 55(1):49–95 Jackson M, Rogers B, Zenou Y (2017) The economic consequences of social-network structure. J Econ Lit 55(1):49–95
Zurück zum Zitat Jacoby H, Skoufias E (1997) Risk, financial markets, and human capital in a developing country. Rev Econ Stud 64(3):311–335 Jacoby H, Skoufias E (1997) Risk, financial markets, and human capital in a developing country. Rev Econ Stud 64(3):311–335
Zurück zum Zitat Janssens W, Kramer B (2016) The social dilemma of microinsurance: free-riding in a framed field experiment. J Econ Behav Organ 131:47–61 Janssens W, Kramer B (2016) The social dilemma of microinsurance: free-riding in a framed field experiment. J Econ Behav Organ 131:47–61
Zurück zum Zitat Jensen R (2004) Do private transfers ‘displace’ the benefits of public transfers? Evidence from South Africa. J Public Econ 88(1):89–112 Jensen R (2004) Do private transfers ‘displace’ the benefits of public transfers? Evidence from South Africa. J Public Econ 88(1):89–112
Zurück zum Zitat Jeong H, Tombor B, Albert R, Oltvai Z, Barabási A (2000) The large-scale organization of metabolic networks. Nature 407(6804):651–654 Jeong H, Tombor B, Albert R, Oltvai Z, Barabási A (2000) The large-scale organization of metabolic networks. Nature 407(6804):651–654
Zurück zum Zitat Kranton R, Minehart D (2001) A theory of buyer–seller networks. Am Econ Rev 91(3):485–508 Kranton R, Minehart D (2001) A theory of buyer–seller networks. Am Econ Rev 91(3):485–508
Zurück zum Zitat Krishnan P, Sciubba E (2009) Links and architecture in village networks. Econ J 119(537):917–949 Krishnan P, Sciubba E (2009) Links and architecture in village networks. Econ J 119(537):917–949
Zurück zum Zitat Kurosaki T, Fafchamps M (2002) Insurance market efficiency and crop choices in Pakistan. J Dev Econ 67(2):419–453 Kurosaki T, Fafchamps M (2002) Insurance market efficiency and crop choices in Pakistan. J Dev Econ 67(2):419–453
Zurück zum Zitat Lee SH, Kim PJ, Jeong H (2006) Statistical properties of sampled networks. Phys Rev E 73(1):016102 Lee SH, Kim PJ, Jeong H (2006) Statistical properties of sampled networks. Phys Rev E 73(1):016102
Zurück zum Zitat Maitra P, Ray R (2003) The effect of transfers on household expenditure patterns and poverty in South Africa. J Dev Econ 71(1):23–49 Maitra P, Ray R (2003) The effect of transfers on household expenditure patterns and poverty in South Africa. J Dev Econ 71(1):23–49
Zurück zum Zitat Milán P (2016) Network-constrained risk sharing in village economies. Barcelona GSE working paper no. 912 Milán P (2016) Network-constrained risk sharing in village economies. Barcelona GSE working paper no. 912
Zurück zum Zitat Morduch J (1999) Between the state and the market: Can informal insurance patch the safety net? World Bank Res Obs 14(2):187–207 Morduch J (1999) Between the state and the market: Can informal insurance patch the safety net? World Bank Res Obs 14(2):187–207
Zurück zum Zitat Murgai R, Winters P, Sadoulet E, De Janvry A (2002) Localized and incomplete mutual insurance. J Dev Econ 67(2):245–274 Murgai R, Winters P, Sadoulet E, De Janvry A (2002) Localized and incomplete mutual insurance. J Dev Econ 67(2):245–274
Zurück zum Zitat Newman M (2002) Assortative mixing in networks. Phys Rev Lett 89(20):1–5 Newman M (2002) Assortative mixing in networks. Phys Rev Lett 89(20):1–5
Zurück zum Zitat Newman M (2003) Mixing patterns in networks. Phys Rev E 67(2):1–14 Newman M (2003) Mixing patterns in networks. Phys Rev E 67(2):1–14
Zurück zum Zitat Newman M (2010) Networks: an introduction. Oxford University Press, New York Newman M (2010) Networks: an introduction. Oxford University Press, New York
Zurück zum Zitat Newman M, Park J (2003) Why social networks are different from other types of networks. Phys Rev E 68(3):036122 Newman M, Park J (2003) Why social networks are different from other types of networks. Phys Rev E 68(3):036122
Zurück zum Zitat Noldus R, Van Mieghem P (2015) Assortativity in complex networks. J Complex Netw 3(4):507–542 Noldus R, Van Mieghem P (2015) Assortativity in complex networks. J Complex Netw 3(4):507–542
Zurück zum Zitat Paxson C (1992) Using weather variability to estimate the response of savings to transitory income in Thailand. Am Econ Rev 82(1):15–33 Paxson C (1992) Using weather variability to estimate the response of savings to transitory income in Thailand. Am Econ Rev 82(1):15–33
Zurück zum Zitat Pennock D, Flake G, Lawrence S, Glover E, Giles C (2002) Winners don’t take all: characterizing the competition for links on the web. Proc Natl Acad Sci 99(8):5207–5211 Pennock D, Flake G, Lawrence S, Glover E, Giles C (2002) Winners don’t take all: characterizing the competition for links on the web. Proc Natl Acad Sci 99(8):5207–5211
Zurück zum Zitat Price D (1965) Networks of scientific papers. Science 149(3683):510–515 Price D (1965) Networks of scientific papers. Science 149(3683):510–515
Zurück zum Zitat Ryan B, Gross N (1943) The diffusion of hybrid seed corn in two Iowa communities. Rural Sociol 8(1):15–24 Ryan B, Gross N (1943) The diffusion of hybrid seed corn in two Iowa communities. Rural Sociol 8(1):15–24
Zurück zum Zitat Strupat C, Klohn F (2018) Crowding out of solidarity? Public health insurance versus informal transfer networks in Ghana. World Dev 104:212–221 Strupat C, Klohn F (2018) Crowding out of solidarity? Public health insurance versus informal transfer networks in Ghana. World Dev 104:212–221
Zurück zum Zitat Townsend R (1994) Risk and insurance in village India. Econometrica 62(3):539–91 Townsend R (1994) Risk and insurance in village India. Econometrica 62(3):539–91
Zurück zum Zitat Van den Broeck K, Dercon S (2011) Information flows and social externalities in a Tanzanian banana growing village. J Dev Stud 47(2):231–252 Van den Broeck K, Dercon S (2011) Information flows and social externalities in a Tanzanian banana growing village. J Dev Stud 47(2):231–252
Zurück zum Zitat Wahhaj Z (2010) Social norms and individual savings in the context of informal insurance. J Econ Behav Organ 76(3):511–530 Wahhaj Z (2010) Social norms and individual savings in the context of informal insurance. J Econ Behav Organ 76(3):511–530
Zurück zum Zitat Watts D (1999) Networks, dynamics, and the small-world phenomenon. Am J Sociol 105(2):493–527 Watts D (1999) Networks, dynamics, and the small-world phenomenon. Am J Sociol 105(2):493–527
Zurück zum Zitat Watts D, Strogatz S (1998) Collective dynamics of ‘small-world’ networks. Nature 393(6684):440–442 Watts D, Strogatz S (1998) Collective dynamics of ‘small-world’ networks. Nature 393(6684):440–442
Metadaten
Titel
The structure of risk-sharing networks
verfasst von
Heath Henderson
Arnob Alam
Publikationsdatum
14.03.2021
Verlag
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Erschienen in
Empirical Economics / Ausgabe 2/2022
Print ISSN: 0377-7332
Elektronische ISSN: 1435-8921
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-021-02037-z

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 2/2022

Empirical Economics 2/2022 Zur Ausgabe