Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Journal of Economic Structures 1/2021

Open Access 01.12.2021 | Research

The usefulness of extended input–output tables incorporating firm heterogeneity

verfasst von: Satoru Hagino, Jiyoung Kim

Erschienen in: Journal of Economic Structures | Ausgabe 1/2021

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This study examines the usefulness of an extended input–output table (EIOT) incorporating the heterogeneity of Japanese firms based on differences in ratios of imported intermediate goods to total output. Using an EIOT, the vertical specialization indicator of Japan was calculated, which corresponds to the foreign value added included in exports. In this process, differences in intermediate input ratios were measured examining different types of firms using firm-level microdata from the Basic Survey of Japanese Business Structure and Activities. The results indicate that distinguishing between exporting and non-exporting firms is relevant for assembly industries such as electronics and automobiles, as widely discussed in the literature. In contrast, for primary materials industries, such as paper, chemical, and metal industries, other distinctions appear to be more relevant. For example, for the chemical industry, wherein firms tend to have large, integrated manufacturing plants, the differences in intermediate import ratios are largest when distinguishing large firms from small and medium firms. For paper and metal industries, which rely on foreign raw materials, the difference is largest when distinguishing between firms with and without foreign affiliates. By incorporating such heterogeneity, the vertical specification indicator increases by 70%; thus, the EIOT captures the foreign value added more comprehensively.
Hinweise

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Abkürzungen
BSBSA
Basic Survey of Japanese Business Structure and Activities
EIOT
Extended input–output table
FSSCI
Financial Statement Statistics of Corporations by Industry
METI
Japan’s Ministry of Economy, Trade and Industry
OECD
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
TiVA
Trade in value added
VS
Vertical specialization

1 Introduction

In recent years, international conferences on national accounts have proposed extending input–output tables (IOTs) and supply and use tables (SUTs) to incorporate firm heterogeneity, along with active discussions on potential approaches for doing so (OECD 2014a, b, 2018). The Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) encourages the extension of IOTs or SUTs to improve the accuracy of its Trade in Value Added (TiVA) indicators by reflecting differences in the ratio of imported to total intermediate goods across heterogeneous firms in an industry.
For the calculation of TiVA, it is important to estimate the amount of imported intermediate goods as accurately as possible, as this is essential for calculating foreign value added. In the OECD’s expert group on extended input–output tables (EIOTs) established in 2014, experts from various countries have discussed which elements of firm heterogeneity should be incorporated in EIOTs (Johnson and Noguera 2012; Ito et al. 2017). Thus far, the OECD has proposed assessing heterogeneity between exporters and non-exporters, domestically and foreign-owned, and large and small firms, in addition to firms with and without foreign subsidiaries (OECD 2015), as presented in Table 1.
Table 1
Framework of extended input–output table
 
Country A
Country B
Industry 1
Industry 2
Industry 3
Industry 1
Industry 2
Industry 3
Exporting
Non-exporting
Large
Small
With foreign subsidiaries
Without foreign subsidiaries
Exporting
Non-exporting
Large
Small
With foreign subsidiaries
Without foreign subsidiaries
Country A
Industry 1
Exporting
            
Non-exporting
            
Industry 2
Large
            
Small
            
Industry 3
With foreign subsidiaries
            
Without foreign subsidiaries
            
Country B
Industry 1
Exporting
            
Non-exporting
            
Industry 2
Large
            
Small
            
Industry 3
With foreign subsidiaries
            
Without foreign subsidiaries
            
Country C
Industry 1
Exporting
            
Non-exporting
            
Industry 2
Large
            
Small
            
Industry 3
With foreign subsidiaries
            
Without foreign subsidiaries
            
Value added
            
Total output
            
 
Country C
Final demand
Industry 1
Industry 2
Industry 3
Country A
Country B
Country C
Exporting
Non-exporting
Large
Small
With foreign subsidiaries
Without foreign subsidiaries
Country A
Industry 1
Exporting
         
Non-exporting
         
Industry 2
Large
         
Small
         
Industry 3
With foreign subsidiaries
         
Without foreign subsidiaries
         
Country B
Industry 1
Exporting
         
Non-exporting
         
Industry 2
Large
         
Small
         
Industry 3
With foreign subsidiaries
         
Without foreign subsidiaries
         
Country C
Industry 1
Exporting
         
Non-exporting
         
Industry 2
Large
         
Small
         
Industry 3
With foreign subsidiaries
         
Without foreign subsidiaries
         
Value added
Total output
Source: authors’ design based on OECD (2015)
In this context, this study considers the kind of firm heterogeneity that should be incorporated in Japan’s EIOT. The research then examines the usefulness of such extension by estimating the vertical specialization (VS) indicator of Japan, which corresponds to TiVA’s foreign value added included in Japan’s exports.
The remainder of this paper is organized into three sections. Section 2 introduces methods, Subsection 3.1 discusses heterogeneity between exporters and non-exporters, and Subsection 3.2 that between large and small firms. Next, Subsection 3.3 focuses on domestically and foreign-owned firms, and Subsection 3.4 that firms with and without foreign subsidiaries. Subsection 3.5 describes the challenges of compiling Japan’s EIOT, after determining an element of firm heterogeneity that produces the largest gap of imported intermediate ratio for each industry. In Subsection 3.6, Japan’s VS indicators are calculated to examine the usefulness of the constructed EIOT. Section 4 concludes.

2 Methods

Using firm-level data from the Basic Survey of Japanese Business Structure and Activities (BSBSA) conducted by Japan’s Ministry of Economy, Trade and Industry (METI), Hagino (2017) found the ratio of imported intermediates to output to be about 10% higher for exporters than non-exporters. To calculate the ratio, the author defined exporters as firms with non-zero exports. In contrast, studies for other countries often define exporters as firms that export at least 10% of their total sales. This research applied a different approach from Hagino’s (2017), identifying exporters in terms of their export ratio (i.e., export/sales) in 10 percentage point increments, calculating the differences in intermediate import ratios between exporters and non-exporters.
The weight of distinctions between large and small firms and between exporters and non-exporters is assessed to determine differences in intermediate import ratios, using the firm-level data of the BSBSA. Two different methods are used to distinguish small and large firms. The first follows the Small and Medium-Sized Enterprise Act, which defines large firms as those with paid-in capital of more than 300 million yen. The second follows the Financial Statement Statistics of Corporations by Industry (FSSCI) of the Ministry of Finance, which defines large firms as those with paid-in capital of 1 billion yen or more.
The usefulness in distinguishing between foreign- and domestically owned firms in Japan is then examined, as in many developing and emerging economies, as well as highly internationalized developed economies, foreign-owned firms have a significant role in international trade.
The share of exports and imports accounted for by Japanese firms with foreign subsidiaries is also investigated. These shares for Japan are calculated from the BSBSA in comparison to corresponding shares for the U.K. and France from the OECD Trade by Enterprise Characteristics (TEC) database. Since the BSBSA does not cover very small firms, such firms are not included in this calculation; however, since very small firms are generally unlikely to have foreign subsidiaries, this is not considered to materially affect the results. The U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis developed an EIOT incorporating heterogeneity between firms with and without foreign subsidiaries, since many U.S. firms with foreign subsidiaries import intermediate goods from subsidiaries and such firms have an important role in international trade in general.
Based on above analyses, the EIOT developed for this research incorporates aspects of firm heterogeneity. As for the details of the compilation procedure, Japan’s IO table, which we will refer to as the Benchmark IO Table, is compiled every 5 years in joint work involving ten government ministries coordinated by the Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications. The Benchmark IO Table is non-competitive and separates the import table from the domestic table. It is based on producer prices, which include subsidies and taxes, such as consumption taxes.
A domestic table is produced by deducting the import table from the transaction table of the Benchmark IO Table and converting 108 product/activity classifications into 18 industry classifications for consistency with the TiVA classification (Table 2). This research focuses on the extension of intermediate input and demand using elements of firm heterogeneity to quantify the effectiveness of the extension; thus, final demand and value added are not separated.
Table 2
2015 domestic IO and import tables (in billion yen)
 
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
Total output
Domestic IO table
 1
1389
0
5827
0
239
3
0
0
0
0
7
0
42
1013
2
0
1
341
12,888
 2
0
1
0
0
5
261
36
1
0
0
0
159
309
0
0
0
0
1
848
 3
1367
0
5026
1
17
115
0
0
0
0
1
0
2
5532
8
0
0
807
38,341
 4
52
3
25
539
42
79
25
31
79
62
21
14
54
300
111
43
113
421
3586
 5
274
2
885
28
3615
646
98
125
351
121
182
120
460
1400
1814
687
714
2098
16,926
 6
862
32
1128
328
1062
145,37
668
1174
2027
2700
448
1371
2968
846
5314
103
1190
7463
65,493
 7
13
18
513
8
273
674
16,078
4720
2711
4197
236
19
3834
345
100
4
125
351
47,886
 8
2
4
0
0
14
63
20
4196
346
408
7
33
121
93
13
0
1113
596
34,067
 9
2
0
1
0
3
2
31
1340
6271
2084
47
1
162
53
57
6
917
252
35,055
 10
51
0
0
0
0
0
0
8
0
22,788
0
0
0
0
747
0
1682
220
55,378
 11
24
1
41
12
108
120
369
17
26
24
58
169
108
68
213
5
173
281
4614
 12
132
36
610
117
665
1918
1411
415
609
718
62
3407
218
4765
1719
333
836
5719
34,081
 13
30
3
18
8
49
167
126
53
79
34
6
504
19
320
529
87
812
787
60,837
 14
843
17
2745
263
1276
2304
1344
1446
1598
2138
318
591
1626
4772
2094
188
1484
5572
128,109
 15
771
182
1417
110
732
2121
1123
952
1084
1011
759
1765
1817
10,123
13,859
3051
7195
8295
104,984
 16
72
33
213
63
155
339
277
253
209
232
96
642
405
1863
1255
738
6717
1981
35,448
 17
269
47
1293
125
499
2285
739
1242
1443
1487
175
2503
3043
11,473
16,105
4344
14,717
12,674
155,508
 18
21
3
44
3
17
69
27
66
40
20
8
91
55
371
837
111
336
2497
177,614
Total output
12,888
848
38,341
3586
16,926
65,493
47,886
34,067
35,055
55,378
4614
34,081
34,081
60,837
128,109
35,448
155,508
177,614
1,017,818
 
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
Total Import
Import table
 1
178
0
1660
29
124
203
0
0
0
0
55
0
1
129
0
0
0
46
2808
 2
0
1
11
1
48
10,130
1275
1
3
6
4
7459
7
1
0
0
1
4
20,293
 3
118
0
1949
8
2
108
0
0
0
0
9
0
0
1626
1
0
0
101
7806
 4
24
1
13
306
40
54
5
10
18
31
10
3
26
170
32
11
37
169
5155
 5
8
0
36
2
762
41
8
6
14
6
30
42
122
126
137
21
38
86
2631
 6
132
6
240
131
101
5796
77
118
259
289
76
371
137
145
680
17
94
3582
14,882
 7
4
2
7
1
31
56
2640
307
867
600
15
5
229
23
6
0
10
27
5944
 8
2
0
0
0
0
0
6
1420
15
93
1
16
3
12
6
0
376
287
5674
 9
1
0
0
0
3
0
11
598
3898
604
32
0
77
6
54
1
352
86
15,310
 10
21
0
0
0
0
0
0
1
0
2060
0
0
0
0
69
0
104
0
4588
 11
4
0
5
31
7
7
7
21
11
13
112
1
23
35
23
3
104
257
2263
 12
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
2
4
 13
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
 14
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
190
0
0
0
0
1234
 15
5
1
18
3
17
64
24
47
60
22
4
81
18
424
3169
259
189
403
5931
 16
10
1
7
2
5
25
7
8
7
9
1
2
9
28
278
898
76
14
1399
 17
3
1
98
7
22
141
18
48
61
73
7
129
167
611
611
289
807
486
3785
 18
1
0
8
0
2
15
6
15
30
7
1
17
6
30
216
14
32
53
2410
Total
491
10
3921
510
1118
16,394
4029
2482
5085
3704
345
7898
625
2274
1008
53
1115
4645
87,354
1: agriculture, 2: mining, 3: food, 4: textiles, 5: paper, 6: chemicals, 7: metal, 8: machinery, 9: electronics, 10: transport equipment, 11: other manufacturing, 12: electric, gas and water, 13: construction, 14: wholesale and retail, 15: transportation and warehouse, 16: finance and insurance, 17: real estate and leasing, 18: community, society and individual services
Source: authors’ calculations based on the Benchmark IOT
Extending the Benchmark IO Table to incorporate firm heterogeneity requires separating the total output based on the type of firm heterogeneity considered for each industry. To do so, firm-level data from the BSBSA are used and calculate the weights, for which output shares are used. An extended import table is then constructed by incorporating the differences in intermediate import ratios.
Finally, the usefulness of the EIOT is examined by comparing VS indicators based on the EIOT with that of the non-extended Benchmark IOT. For this purpose, VS coefficients are calculated by multiplying the import coefficient matrix using the Leontief inverse matrix. The coefficients for each industry are then aggregated, referring to the aggregated figure as each industry’s total VS coefficient. Industries’ total VS is then calculated by multiplying the industry total VS coefficient by the number of exports. After aggregating each industry’s VS amount, the VS indicator is calculated by dividing the aggregate VS amount by total exports. Finally, two different VS indicators are calculated based on the extended and non-extended IOTs.
The roots of the development of TiVA indicators can be traced back to the estimation of VS indicators (Hummels et al. 2001), which are calculated as the ratio of imported intermediate goods included in exports and are estimated using OECD IOTs. The VS indicator corresponds to foreign value added included in exports in the TiVA.
VS indicators can be estimated using one country’s IOT. Defining VSId as the direct imports deriving from exports, \(X\) as the \(n\times 1\) vector of exports of each industry, \({X}_{t}\) as a scalar of total exports of a country, \({A}^{m}\) as the \(n\times n\) imported input coefficient matrix, \(U\) as a \(1\times n\) vector of 1s used for aggregating industries, and n as the number of industries, VSId is given by:
$${\rm VSI}_{\rm d}=U\times {A}^{m}\times X\times {X}_{t}^{-1}.$$
(1)
However, imports may indirectly derive from exports. For example, automobile manufacturers may import chassis to export cars, or may alternatively purchase chassis from domestic manufacturers, who may import intermediate goods for chassis. Therefore, VS indicators should cover all imports deriving from exports, including imports through increases in domestic demand spurred by exports. Domestic demand deriving from exports can be calculated using the Leontief inverse matrix. Defining \({A}^{d}\) as the \(n\times n\) input coefficient of domestic transactions matrix and \({(I-{A}^{d})}^{-1}\) as the Leontief inverse matrix, \({\mathrm{VSI}}\), which covers both direct and indirect imports from exports, is given by:
$${\mathrm{VSI}}=U\times {A}^{m}\times {\left(I-{A}^{d}\right)}^{-1}\times X\times {X}_{t}^{-1}.$$
(2)

3 Results and discussion

3.1 Heterogeneity between exporting and non-exporting firms

The results of calculating the differences in intermediate import ratios between exporters and non-exporters are presented in Table 3.
Table 3
Difference in intermediate import ratios between exporters and non-exporters, by export/sales ratios
 
Industry/scope of exporters
 > 0–100%
 ≥ 10–100%
 ≥ 20–100%
 ≥ 30–100%
 ≥ 40–100%
 ≥ 50–100%
 ≥ 60–100%
 ≥ 70–100%
 ≥ 80–100%
 ≥ 90–100%
100%
2011
Food products
0.055
0.060
0.110
0.057
0.057
0.057
0.067
0.067
0.080
0.080
0.098
Textiles
0.070
0.147
0.187
0.116
− 0.056
− 0.054
0.009
− 0.101
− 0.101
− 0.101
− 0.101
Wood and paper products
0.027
0.064
0.366
0.444
0.509
0.540
0.762
0.967
0.967
0.967
0.967
Chemicals
0.086
− 0.156
− 0.172
− 0.143
− 0.062
− 0.025
− 0.189
0.115
0.278
0.587
0.587
Metals
0.034
0.104
0.125
0.194
0.295
0.428
0.239
0.262
− 0.039
− 0.011
− 0.011
Machinery equipment
0.067
0.043
0.035
0.024
− 0.018
− 0.023
− 0.041
− 0.044
− 0.051
0.085
0.013
Electronic and optical equipment
0.103
0.108
0.101
0.097
0.143
0.127
0.249
0.282
0.378
0.605
0.069
Transport equipment
0.037
0.030
0.024
0.022
0.017
0.006
0.035
0.052
0.035
0.002
0.395
Manufacturing n.e.c and recycling
0.188
0.092
0.274
0.273
0.280
0.302
0.099
0.140
0.540
0.572
0.815
2015
Food products
0.046
0.084
0.329
0.245
0.288
0.340
0.392
0.392
0.743
0.743
0.963
Textiles
0.104
0.124
0.009
− 0.020
0.005
− 0.113
− 0.089
− 0.088
− 0.134
− 0.134
− 0.134
Wood and paper products
− 0.007
0.058
0.098
0.339
0.352
0.503
0.627
0.627
0.961
0.961
0.961
Chemicals
0.171
0.133
− 0.132
− 0.126
− 0.087
− 0.016
− 0.002
− 0.011
0.088
0.061
0.693
Metals
0.055
0.092
0.110
0.030
0.241
0.545
0.577
0.595
0.715
0.849
0.870
Machinery equipment
0.103
0.079
0.072
0.064
0.047
0.039
0.027
0.042
− 0.077
0.054
− 0.053
Electronic and optical equipment
0.178
0.168
0.142
0.152
0.229
0.230
0.142
0.153
0.201
0.141
− 0.149
Transport equipment
0.062
0.049
0.046
0.063
0.070
0.066
0.086
0.089
0.136
0.232
0.366
Manufacturing n.e.c and recycling
0.189
0.081
0.030
0.122
0.110
0.161
0.206
0.418
0.217
0.069
− 0.038
Source: authors’ calculations based on firm-level data of the Basic Survey of Japanese Business Structure and Activities, METI
The results indicate that, in the processing and assembly industries, the more a firm exports, the more it tends to import. In the electronic and optical equipment industry, the difference in the intermediate import ratio between exporters and non-exporters in 2011 was largest when focusing on exporters with an export ratio of 90%, while in 2015, it was largest for those with an export ratio of 50%. In the transport equipment industry, the difference in both years is largest for exporters with an export ratio of 100%. In the machinery equipment industry, the difference in the intermediate import ratio between exporters and non-exporters remains relatively stable as the export ratio increases. In contrast, no clear pattern between the export ratio and the difference between exporters and non-exporters can be observed in primary materials industries. For the metals industry, the difference is largest for an export ratio of 10%, both in 2011 and 2015. For the wood and paper products industry (hereafter, paper industry), the difference becomes larger as the export ratio increases. Conversely, for the textile industry, the difference is largest at an export ratio of 20% in 2011 and 10% in 2015 and then declines as the ratio increases. For the chemical industry, the difference is largest at an export ratio of 10% and then declines, even becoming negative, as the export ratio increases. These results indicate that other aspects of firm heterogeneity may be more crucial for identifying differences in the intermediate imports ratio.
The volume of transactions must be considered to determine the most appropriate export ratio to distinguish exporters from non-exporters. For example, in the transport equipment industry, a small number of export-intensive firms import, so the difference is largest for an export ratio of 100%. To take the volume of transactions into consideration and identify the magnitude of exports to the imported intermediate ratios, the gap was multiplied by the volume of total inputs to calculate indices (Fig. 1). In this figure, “\(>\) 0–100%”, “\(\ge\) 10–100%”, …, “\(\ge\) 90–100%”, 100% means the ranges of export intensities (export sales ratios). We calculated the differences of import intermediate ratios between exporters and non-exporters that belong to the certain range of export intensities, by subtracting non-exporters ratios from exporters ratios. The magnitude of “ > 0–100%” is defined to equal 100 as reference index. (However, “ > 0–100%” in 2015 of wood and paper products industry is defined as – 100 since it has a negative value.) Figure 1 demonstrates that the calculation for the export/sales ratio of “\(>\) 0–100%” for all exporters produces the largest magnitude to the gap indices in all industries, the exception being the wood and paper products with the highest magnitude at “\(\ge\) 10–100%” in 2015 (124.31), the metal industry with the largest magnitude at “\(\ge\) 30–100%” in 2011 (243.06) and at “\(\ge\) 10–100%” in 2015 (108.22). Given than such exceptions are not numerous, we regard that all exporters should be covered in distinguishing exporters from non-exporters.

3.2 Heterogeneity between small and large firms

Figures 2 and 3 present the differences in the intermediate import ratio between small and large firms by industry, with Fig. 2 showing the results based on the first definition and Fig. 3 those based on the second definition, comparing the differences between exporters and non-exporters (where exporters are defined as firms with non-zero exports). In the processing and assembly industries, the differences in intermediate import ratios between exporters and non-exporters are found to be larger than those between small and large firms. Interestingly, for the electronic and optical equipment industry, the gap is larger when using the definition of the Small and Medium-Sized Enterprises Act (Fig. 2), which uses a lower capital threshold for large firms, than when using the definition of the FSSCI (Fig. 3), which uses a higher threshold. This indicates that there are a lot of medium-sized firms in the electronic and optical equipment industry between the two thresholds that engage in export.
The pattern for primary material industries differs considerably. For the chemical and metal industries, the differences in intermediate import ratios between small and large firms are larger than those between exporters and non-exporters. For the paper industry, the difference in 2015 between small and large firms was about the same as that between exporters and non-exporters. This indicates that heterogeneity regarding aspects other than exports may have a role for these industries. Interestingly, for the chemical industry, the difference is larger when using the definition of the FSSCI than when using the definition of the Small and Medium-Sized Enterprise Act. As discussed by Hagino (2017), this indicates that a small number of very large chemical firms operating integrated production systems, such as petroleum complexes, use large amounts of imported intermediates and materials.
Table 4 examines the differences in the chemical and metal industries in more detail. For this purpose, the chemical industry is subdivided into petrochemical and non-petrochemical industries, and the latter is further subdivided into chemical, rubber, and ceramic products industries. Similarly, the metal industry is subdivided into the pig iron, forged products, nonferrous products, nonferrous processing, and other metal industries.
Table 4
Differences in intermediate import ratios in the chemical and metal industries
 
2011
2015
Industry
Paid-in capital ≥ 1 billion yen
Paid-in capital ≥ 300 million yen
Paid-in capital ≥ 1 billion yen
Paid-in capital ≥ 300 million yen
Chemicals
0.214
0.196
0.206
0.191
Petrochemical products
0.335
0.314
0.397
0.344
Nonpetrochemical products
0.058
0.048
0.023
0.024
Chemical products
0.031
0.032
− 0.027
− 0.029
Rubber products
0.126
0.084
0.088
0.072
Ceramic products
0.044
0.038
0.062
0.054
Metal
0.153
0.141
0.098
0.078
Pig iron
0.269
0.26
0.19
0.188
Forged products
− 0.012
− 0.013
− 0.006
− 0.004
Nonferrous products
0.044
0.061
0.048
0.018
Nonferrous processing
0.004
0.006
− 0.009
− 0.05
Other metal
− 0.01
− 0.012
0.003
− 0.006
Source: authors’ calculations based on firm-level data of the Basic Survey of Japanese Business Structure and Activities, METI
In the chemical industry, the difference is larger in the petrochemical industry than the non-petrochemical industry. Large petrochemical firms are equipped with capital-intensive integrated manufacturing complexes, and the use of imported intermediates and materials increases with the size of such firms, resulting in the large difference. Within the non-petrochemical industry, the differences in rubber and ceramic products industries are small but positive, while in the chemical products industry the difference is even negative. As highlighted by Hagino (2017), a likely reason for the negative difference in the chemical industry is that production in the industry tends to be divided into multiple stages, so that importers provide processed products to domestic firms and exporters process domestically produced products.
In the metal industry, the difference is larger in pig iron and nonferrous products industries than in the other sub-industries. Large iron and nonferrous products firms are equipped with capital-intensive integrated manufacturing complexes, and the use of imported intermediates and materials increases with the size of such firms, resulting in the large difference. The differences in the other metal industries (forged products, nonferrous processing, and other metal industries) are positive but small or negative. The reason, once again, seems to be that production in these sub-industries tends to be divided into multiple stages.

3.3 Heterogeneity between domestic and foreign firms

Figures 4 and 5 demonstrate that foreign-owned firms do not play a pivotal role in international trade in Japan, and that this distinction is less relevant than in other countries. Figure 4 compares the export and import shares accounted for by domestic and foreign firms in Japan and major European economies, while Fig. 5 shows the share of domestic and foreign firms in the total number of exporting and importing firms. The data for European countries are from the OECD’s Trade by Enterprise Characteristics (TEC) database, which provides trade data (exports and imports) categorized by firms’ characteristics, including ownership structure. For Japan, corresponding figures are estimated using firm-level data from the BSBSA. Although the BSBSA does not cover very small firms with less than 50 employees and 30 million yen of paid-in capital, omitting such small firms is unlikely to skew the results in a meaningful way.
Starting with Fig. 4, the results demonstrate that the share of exports and imports in Japan accounted for by foreign firms is much smaller than in European countries, especially in the case of exports, at around 5%, it is almost negligible. A similar pattern is revealed in Fig. 5, which shows that the shares of foreign firms in the total number of exporting and importing firms in Japan are less than 3%. These findings suggest that, in the case of Japan, distinguishing between domestically and foreign-owned firms is not a high priority when examining heterogeneity in intermediate imports.

3.4 Heterogeneity between firms with and without foreign subsidiaries

Figure 6 indicates that firms with foreign subsidiaries in Japan account for more than 95% of all exports and imports, which is considerably higher than in France and the UK.
Therefore, differences in the intermediate import ratio between firms with and without foreign subsidiaries are calculated. The results are presented in Fig. 7 and reveal that the difference between firms in the metal industry with and without foreign subsidiaries is larger than those between exporters and non-exporters as well as those between small and large firms. This suggests that metal corporations, which need to import materials, have established subsidiaries for the exploration and mining of raw materials abroad. Thus, distinguishing between firms with and without foreign subsidiaries in the EIOT for the metal industry appears to be appropriate.
Furthermore, in the textile industry and the paper industry, the differences between firms with and without foreign subsidiaries are as large as those between exporters and non-exporters. Wood and paper products firms, which must import wood products, have established foreign subsidiaries to grow and harvest wood abroad. Similarly, many textile firms have established subsidiaries abroad, especially for sewing processes, to take advantage of lower labor costs in developing countries and import intermediates to Japan. Since the reliance on foreign subsidiaries by firms in these industries is likely to grow in the future, distinguishing between firms with and without foreign subsidiaries in the EIOT also seems appropriate for the wood and paper products and textile industries.

3.5 Compiling Japan’s EIOT

The analyses in subsections (3.13.4) regarding the types of heterogeneity to incorporate in the Japanese EIOT have several implications. For processing and assembly industries, such as machinery, electronics, transport equipment, food, and textile industries, heterogeneity between exporters and non-exporters should be incorporated. For the chemical industry, heterogeneity between small and large firms should be incorporated, and for paper and metal industries, heterogeneity between firms with and without foreign subsidiaries should be incorporated.
As for the textile industry, the difference in intermediate import ratios between firms with and without foreign subsidiaries is as large as that between exporting and non-exporting firms; however, the share of exports accounted for by firms with foreign subsidiaries is quite small (Table 5). As for the heterogeneity between small and large firms, the intermediate import ratio of small firms is larger than that of large firms, so incorporating such heterogeneity is not consistent with theoretical assumptions; therefore, the most appropriate approach appears to be the incorporation of heterogeneity between exporting and non-exporting firms.
Table 5
Share in exports in 2015
 
Food (%)
Textiles (%)
Paper (%)
Chemicals (%)
Metal (%)
Machinery (%)
Electronics (%)
Transport equipment (%)
Other manufacturing (%)
Export share of exporting firms
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
100.0
Export share of large firms
 
94.3
 
90.5
     
Export share of firms with foreign subsidiaries
 
22.5
77.1
 
63.2
    
Source: authors’ calculations based on firm-level data of the Basic Survey of Japanese Business Structure and Activities, METI
An extended domestic table was constructed by applying the weights to the total output of each manufacturing industry (Table 4) in the domestic table. Total output was separated into the output of exporters and non-exporters for the food, textile, machinery, electronics, transport equipment, and other manufacturing industries; of small and large firms for the chemical industry; and of firms with and without foreign subsidiaries for the paper and metal industries. For the textile industry, the output weight of firms with foreign subsidiaries is relatively small (bold text in Table 6), justifying the use of exporting and non-exporting as the heterogeneity consideration for the textile industry.
Table 6
Output shares in 2015
 
Food (%)
Textiles (%)
Paper (%)
Chemicals (%)
Metal (%)
Machinery (%)
Electronics (%)
Transport equipment (%)
Other manufacturing (%)
Output share of exporting firms
33.7
63.6
39.6
74.5
61.9
71.2
76.2
80.7
71.7
Output share of large firms
 
82.5
 
80.2
     
Output share of firms with foreign subsidiaries
 
29.4
29.1
 
42.2
    
Source: authors’ calculations based on firm-level data of the Basic Survey of Japanese Business Structure and Activities, METI
Table 6 is the extended import table incorporating the differences in intermediate import ratios (only manufacturing industries are shown). Based on Hagino’s (2017) analysis demonstrating that differences in industries’ intermediate import ratios are mainly due to the import of goods that an industry needs to produce, such differences are assumed to derive from differences in within-industry imports. For example, exporting automobile firms in the transport equipment industry import a large number of automobile parts, whereas non-exporting automobile firms mainly procure such parts from domestic firms. As a result, the transport equipment industry’s difference in import intermediate ratio becomes largest in the import of transport equipment. Such a result is assumed to be reasonable, and therefore, reflect differences in intermediate import ratios in the diagonal cells (bold text in Table 7).
Table 7
2015 Extended domestic IO and import tables (in billion yen)
 
3
4
5
6
7
Exporting
Non-exporting
Exporting
Non-exporting
With foreign subsidiaries
Without foreign subsidiaries
Large firms
Small firms
With foreign subsidiaries
Without foreign subsidiaries
Extended domestic table
          
 1
1964
3864
0
0
69
169
3
1
0
0
 2
0
0
0
0
2
4
210
52
15
21
 3
1694
3332
0
0
5
12
92
23
0
0
 4
8
17
159
380
12
30
63
16
11
15
 5
298
587
18
10
1052
2563
518
128
41
57
 6
380
748
209
119
309
753
11,666
2872
282
387
 7
173
340
5
3
80
194
541
133
6781
9297
 8
0
0
0
0
4
10
51
12
9
12
 9
0
0
0
0
1
2
1
0
13
18
 10
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
 11
14
27
8
4
32
77
96
24
156
213
Total output
12,920
25,421
2281
1305
4926
12,001
52,557
12,937
20,197
27,690
Extended import table
          
 1
559
1101
18
11
36
88
163
40
0
0
 2
4
7
1
0
14
34
8129
2001
538
737
 3
1065
884
5
3
1
2
87
21
0
0
 4
4
9
175
131
12
28
43
11
2
3
 5
12
24
1
1
390
372
33
8
3
5
 6
81
159
84
48
29
71
4582
1213
32
44
 7
2
4
1
0
9
22
45
11
1598
1042
 8
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
3
4
 9
0
0
0
0
1
2
0
0
5
7
 10
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
 11
2
4
20
11
2
5
5
1
3
4
Total
1730
2191
305
205
494
624
13,087
3307
2184
1845
 
8
9
10
11
Exporting
Non-exporting
Exporting
Non-exporting
Exporting
Non-exporting
Exporting
Non-exporting
Extended domestic table
        
 1
0
0
0
0
0
0
5
2
 2
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
 3
0
0
0
0
0
0
1
0
 4
22
9
61
19
50
12
15
6
 5
89
36
267
84
97
23
130
52
 6
836
339
1544
483
2178
522
321
127
 7
3359
1361
2065
646
3385
812
169
67
 8
2986
1210
264
82
329
79
5
2
 9
954
387
4777
1494
1681
403
33
13
 10
6
2
0
0
18,379
4409
0
0
 11
12
5
20
6
20
5
42
16
Total output
24,244
9823
26,705
8350
44,663
10,715
3307
1307
Extended import table
        
 1
0
0
0
0
0
0
40
16
 2
1
0
2
1
5
1
3
1
 3
0
0
0
0
0
0
7
3
 4
7
3
14
4
25
6
7
3
 5
4
2
10
3
5
1
21
8
 6
84
34
197
62
233
56
55
22
 7
218
88
661
207
484
116
11
4
 8
838
582
11
3
75
18
1
0
 9
426
173
2403
1495
487
117
23
9
 10
0
0
0
0
1145
915
0
0
 11
15
6
8
3
10
2
89
23
Total
1593
889
3307
1778
2471
1233
255
89
3: food, 4: textiles, 5: paper, 6: chemicals, 7: metal, 8: machinery, 9: electronics, 10: transport equipment, 11: other manufacturing
Source: authors’ calculations based on the Benchmark IOT and firm-level data of the Basic Survey of Japanese Business Structure and Activities, METI

3.6 Usefulness of the EIOT

Table 8 presents the VS coefficients for the non-extended IOT and Table 9 those for the EIOT.
Table 8
VS coefficients of the 2015 Benchmark IOT
 
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
1
0.02
0.00
0.06
0.01
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
2
0.03
0.03
0.02
0.04
0.04
0.21
0.06
0.03
0.03
0.04
0.04
0.26
0.03
0.03
0.02
0.01
0.01
0.02
3
0.02
0.00
0.07
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.04
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
4
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.10
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
5
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.06
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.01
0.00
0.01
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
6
0.03
0.02
0.02
0.06
0.02
0.12
0.01
0.01
0.02
0.02
0.03
0.02
0.02
0.01
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.03
7
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.08
0.03
0.04
0.03
0.01
0.00
0.02
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
8
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.05
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
9
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.03
0.14
0.03
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
10
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.06
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
11
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.02
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
12
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
13
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
14
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
15
0.00
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.01
0.00
0.01
0.01
0.00
0.02
0.03
0.01
0.00
0.01
16
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.03
0.00
0.00
17
0.00
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.02
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.00
18
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
Total
0.12
0.07
0.18
0.24
0.16
0.36
0.16
0.16
0.25
0.21
0.16
0.30
0.10
0.15
0.08
0.06
0.04
0.07
1: agriculture, 2: mining, 3: food, 4: textiles, 5: paper, 6: chemicals, 7: metal, 8: machinery, 9: electronics, 10: transport equipment, 11: other manufacturing, 12: electric, gas and water, 13: construction, 14: wholesale and retail, 15: transportation and warehouse, 16: finance and insurance, 17: real estate and leasing, 18: community, society and individual services
Source: authors’ calculations based on the Benchmark IOT
Table 9
VS coefficients of the 2015 extended IOT
 
1
2
3–1
3–2
4–1
4–2
5–1
5–2
6–1
6–2
7–1
7–2
8–1
1
0.02
0.00
0.05
0.05
0.02
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
2
0.03
0.03
0.02
0.02
0.07
0.03
0.04
0.04
0.21
0.21
0.06
0.06
0.02
3–1
0.01
0.00
0.05
0.03
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
3–2
0.01
0.00
0.04
0.02
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
4–1
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.10
0.04
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
4–2
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.08
0.03
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
5–1
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.05
0.02
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
5–2
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.05
0.02
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
6–1
0.02
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.08
0.02
0.01
0.01
0.09
0.10
0.00
0.00
0.01
6–2
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.04
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.02
0.03
0.00
0.00
0.00
7–1
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.07
0.04
0.02
7–2
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.04
0.03
0.01
8–1
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.02
8–2
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.02
9–1
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.02
9–2
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.01
10–1
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
10–2
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
11–1
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
11–2
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
12
0.01
0.00
0.02
0.02
0.09
0.04
0.06
0.06
0.04
0.04
0.05
0.05
0.02
13
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
14
0.02
0.01
0.09
0.09
0.19
0.10
0.10
0.10
0.05
0.05
0.05
0.05
0.06
15
0.02
0.02
0.05
0.05
0.09
0.05
0.07
0.07
0.05
0.05
0.04
0.04
0.05
16
0.00
0.00
0.01
0.01
0.05
0.02
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.01
17
0.01
0.01
0.05
0.05
0.10
0.05
0.05
0.05
0.05
0.05
0.03
0.03
0.05
18
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
Total
0.17
0.10
0.43
0.38
0.96
0.41
0.47
0.42
0.54
0.55
0.35
0.31
0.34
 
8–2
9–1
9–2
10–1
10–2
11–1
11–2
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
1
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.01
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
2
0.02
0.03
0.03
0.04
0.04
0.04
0.04
0.26
0.02
0.02
0.02
0.01
0.01
0.02
3–1
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
3–2
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
4–1
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
4–2
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
5–1
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.01
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
5–2
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
6–1
0.01
0.02
0.02
0.02
0.02
0.02
0.02
0.01
0.01
0.00
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.02
6–2
0.00
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.01
7–1
0.02
0.03
0.03
0.02
0.02
0.01
0.01
0.00
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
7–2
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
8–1
0.04
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
8–2
0.03
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
9–1
0.02
0.07
0.13
0.02
0.02
0.01
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
9–2
0.01
0.04
0.08
0.01
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
10–1
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.03
0.06
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
10–2
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.02
0.05
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
11–1
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.02
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
11–2
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
12
0.02
0.03
0.03
0.03
0.03
0.02
0.02
0.00
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
13
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
14
0.06
0.07
0.07
0.08
0.08
0.08
0.08
0.00
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.00
0.00
0.01
15
0.05
0.05
0.05
0.05
0.05
0.19
0.19
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.04
0.01
0.01
0.01
16
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.02
0.02
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.03
0.00
0.00
17
0.05
0.06
0.06
0.06
0.06
0.05
0.05
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.01
0.01
18
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
Total
0.36
0.43
0.52
0.42
0.48
0.52
0.51
0.31
0.08
0.09
0.12
0.08
0.05
0.09
1: agriculture, 2: mining, 3: food, 4: textiles, 5: paper, 6: chemicals, 7: metal, 8: machinery, 9: electronics, 10: transport equipment, 11: other manufacturing, 12: electric, gas and water, 13: construction, 14: wholesale and retail, 15: transportation and warehouse, 16: finance and insurance, 17: real estate and leasing, 18: community, society and individual services
For industries 3–11, the subnumbers (e.g., 3–1 and 3–2) denote elements of the extension
Source: authors’ calculations based on the Benchmark IOT and firm-level data of the Basic Survey of Japanese Business Structure and Activities, METI
Table 10 reveals the VS indicator based on the EIOT (34.3%) is 70% larger than that based on the non-extended IOT (20.5%). This implies that the extension of IOTs incorporating differences in intermediate import ratios makes it possible to more comprehensively capture VS, and potentially, foreign value added.
Table 10
VS indicators calculated from the extended and non-extended IOTs
Industry
Extension elements
Calculation based on extended IOT
Calculation based on non-extended IOT
Industry total of VS coefficient
Exports (billion of yen)
Amount of VS (billion of yen)
VS indicator
Industry total of VS coefficient
Exports (billion of yen)
Amount of VS (billion of yen)
VS indicator
Domestic value added included in imported intermediates (%)
Amount of VS after deducting domestic value added (billion of yen)
VS indicator after deducting domestic value added
Agriculture
0.17
0
0
 
0.12
0
0
 
0.6
0.0
 
Mining
0.10
33
3
0.07
33
2
0.5
2
Food
Exporting
0.43
155
66
0.18
155
29
1.2
28
Non-exporting
0.38
0
0
Textile
Exporting
0.96
131
126
0.24
131
32
1.6
31
Non-exporting
0.41
0
0
Paper
With foreign subsidiaries
0.47
289
135
0.16
375
60
0.9
59
Without foreign subsidiaries
0.42
86
36
Chemical
Large
0.54
6811
3673
0.36
7521
2679
1.8
2630
Small
0.55
711
388
Metal
With foreign subsidiaries
0.35
2866
1014
0.16
4535
739
1.9
725
Without foreign subsidiaries
0.31
1669
521
Machinery
Exporting
0.34
8685
2943
0.16
8685
1348
7.1
1253
Non-exporting
0.36
0
0
Electronics
Exporting
0.43
14,294
6200
0.25
14,294
3536
8.2
3245
Non-exporting
0.52
0
0
Transport equipment
Exporting
0.42
22,919
9644
0.21
22,919
4756
4.3
4552
Non-exporting
0.48
0
0
Other manufacturing
Exporting
0.52
526
275
0.16
526
86
7.9
79
Non-exporting
0.51
0
0
Electric, gas and water
0.31
23
7
0.30
23
7
0.8
7
Construction
0.08
23
2
0.10
23
2
1.5
2
Wholesale and retail
0.09
18,051
1602
0.15
18,051
2650
1.2
2618
Transportation and warehouse
0.12
158
20
0.08
158
13
2.7
13
Finance and insurance
0.08
0
0
0.06
0
0
1.1
0
Real estate and leasing
0.05
16
1
0.04
16
1
1.0
1
Community, society and individual services
0.09
278
25
0.07
278
21
2.4
20
Total
9.50
77,725
26,680
34.3%
2.87
77,725
15,961
20.5%
2.1
15,632
20.1%
Source: authors’ calculations based on the Benchmark IOT, firm-level data of the Basic Survey of Japanese Business Structure and Activities, METI, and OECD TiVA indicator
OECD TiVA indicators show that Japan’s foreign value added included in exports is about 15%. Despite the similarity of the underlying concept of the VS indicator and foreign value added, the former is 30% larger than the latter. This gap may be caused by the fact that the VS indicator calculated in this research is based on one country’s IOT and does not exclude the domestic value added included in imported intermediate goods (APEC 2019, De Becker and Yamano 2012), which is not negligible in machinery industries. If the domestic value added included in imported intermediate goods is deducted using corresponding data from the OECD TiVA indicators, the VS indicator is reduced slightly to 20.1%. To calculate the foreign value added included in imported intermediate goods in this way, data from Japan’s trade partners must be considered and made endogenous in the analysis, which requires an international EIOT.

4 Conclusion

This paper discussed the various aspects of firm heterogeneity that should be incorporated into Japan’s EIOT. Based on the analysis using firm-level data, it was concluded that processing and assembly industries, such as the machinery, electronics, transport equipment industries, food, and textile industries, heterogeneity between exporters and non-exporters should be incorporated. For the chemical industry, heterogeneity between small and large firms should be incorporated, while for paper and metal industries, heterogeneity between firms with and without foreign subsidiaries should be incorporated. Based on these results, an EIOT was constructed for Japan. To examine the usefulness of this table, Japan’s VS indicator was estimated, finding the VS indicator based on the EIOT to be 70% larger than that based on the non-extended IOT. This implies that the foreign value added could be more comprehensively captured by the extension of an IOT. For more precise calculation of the foreign value added, however, Japan’s EIOT should be incorporated into an international IOT. For this purpose, we would like to work with the OECD. Doing so may enable verification of the reliability of the input structure method proposed in this study.
A future research challenge is the construction of an EIOT incorporating different elements of heterogeneity. Specifically, capturing the impact of firms’ globalization on the SNA, identifying multinational corporations could be useful. For this purpose, the OECD has proposed to incorporate the distinction between domestically owned firms without foreign subsidiaries, domestically owned firms with foreign subsidiaries, and foreign-owned firms in the EIOT. Following this proposal will present an opportunity to extend the work in this paper and present a potential research task for next research stage.

Acknowledgements

Not applicable.

Declarations

Not applicable.
Not applicable.

Competing interests

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.
Open AccessThis article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://​creativecommons.​org/​licenses/​by/​4.​0/​.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat APEC Committee on Trade and Investment, 2019. Methodologies of Constructing the APEC TiVA Database for Better Understanding Global Value Chains in the APEC Region. APEC Committee on Trade and Investment, 2019. Methodologies of Constructing the APEC TiVA Database for Better Understanding Global Value Chains in the APEC Region.
Zurück zum Zitat De Becker K, Yamano N (2012) ‘International Comparative Evidence on Global Value Chains, OECD Science,’ Technology and Industry Working Papers 2012/03. De Becker K, Yamano N (2012) ‘International Comparative Evidence on Global Value Chains, OECD Science,’ Technology and Industry Working Papers 2012/03.
Zurück zum Zitat Hagino S (2017) Identifying Firm Heterogeneity in Japan by Developing TEC and TEC Plus Data. Fukuyama University Journal of Economics Hagino S (2017) Identifying Firm Heterogeneity in Japan by Developing TEC and TEC Plus Data. Fukuyama University Journal of Economics
Zurück zum Zitat Hummels D, Ishii J, Yi K-M (2001) The nature and growth of vertical specialization in world trade. Journal of International Economics 54:75–96CrossRef Hummels D, Ishii J, Yi K-M (2001) The nature and growth of vertical specialization in world trade. Journal of International Economics 54:75–96CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ito K, Deseatnicov I, Fukao K (2017) ‘Japanese Plants’ heterogeneity in sales, factor inputs, and participation in global value chains. RIETI Discussion Paper Series, 17-E-117 Ito K, Deseatnicov I, Fukao K (2017) ‘Japanese Plants’ heterogeneity in sales, factor inputs, and participation in global value chains. RIETI Discussion Paper Series, 17-E-117
Zurück zum Zitat Johnson RC, Noguera G (2012) Accounting for intermediates: production sharing and trade in value added. Journal of International Economics 86(2):224–236CrossRef Johnson RC, Noguera G (2012) Accounting for intermediates: production sharing and trade in value added. Journal of International Economics 86(2):224–236CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat OECD Expert Group on Extended Supply-Use Tables (2014a) Draft: Terms of Reference OECD Expert Group on Extended Supply-Use Tables (2014a) Draft: Terms of Reference
Zurück zum Zitat OECD (2014b) Extending OECD’s Work on Measuring Trade in Value-Added, STD/CSSP(2014)7 OECD (2014b) Extending OECD’s Work on Measuring Trade in Value-Added, STD/CSSP(2014)7
Zurück zum Zitat OECD (2015) Firm Heterogeneity and Trade in Value-Added, STD/CSSP/WPTGS(2015)23 OECD (2015) Firm Heterogeneity and Trade in Value-Added, STD/CSSP/WPTGS(2015)23
Zurück zum Zitat OECD (2018) Addressing the Challenges of Globalisation in National Accounts, COM/SDD/DAF(2018)6 OECD (2018) Addressing the Challenges of Globalisation in National Accounts, COM/SDD/DAF(2018)6
Metadaten
Titel
The usefulness of extended input–output tables incorporating firm heterogeneity
verfasst von
Satoru Hagino
Jiyoung Kim
Publikationsdatum
01.12.2021
Verlag
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Erschienen in
Journal of Economic Structures / Ausgabe 1/2021
Elektronische ISSN: 2193-2409
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1186/s40008-021-00255-3

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 1/2021

Journal of Economic Structures 1/2021 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner