Skip to main content

Open Access 07.12.2023 | Case Study

A COVID-19 stress test for life insurance: insights into the effectiveness of different risk mitigation strategies

verfasst von: Moritz Hanika

Erschienen in: European Actuarial Journal

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

COVID-19 has affected mortality rates and financial markets worldwide. Against this background, we perform a COVID-19 stress test for life insurance, considering a joint financial and mortality shock, to evaluate the effectiveness of different risk mitigation strategies. Specifically, we conduct a model-based simulation analysis of a life insurer selling annuities and term life insurances. The analysis includes stress scenarios that are calibrated to observations during the first year of the COVID-19 pandemic. We also consider new business and study the risk situation under three different risk mitigation strategies observed in practice as an immediate response to the pandemic: stopping sales, increasing premiums, or adjusting investment strategies. Results show that a life insurer’s risk situation is mainly affected in the short term, selling annuities (in addition to term life insurance) immunizes against the mortality shock, and the immediate use of risk mitigation strategies can help reduce the negative impact.
Hinweise

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

1 Introduction

COVID-19 had and will continue to have a major impact on society worldwide. Under the backdrop of globalization, the virus spread quickly across countries, thereby increasing mortality rates and causing many economic problems, such as business interruptions and supply chain issues. The COVID-19 pandemic is thus notable not only for its impact on human health and mortality [29, 36] but also for its economic effects on financial markets [1, 43]. This makes it particularly relevant for the life insurance industry, whose core business is to adequately price mortality risks and ensure stable returns on assets under management.
Research by a U.S. company that uses data science to predict disease outbreaks indicates an increasing frequency of pandemics, revealing a 47–57% chance of a COVID-19-like event happening within the next 25 years [30]. Hence, managing pandemic shocks is highly relevant for life insurers. Although the previous literature has examined the general impact of COVID-19 on the insurance industry [34], particularly with respect to mortality risk [10, 33, 37] or insurance investing [27], academic research that analyzes the impact of the joint financial and mortality shock caused by COVID-19 on a life insurer’s risk situation in an asset–liability-based simulation analysis is still missing. Further, Harris et al. [22] showed that U.S. life insurers only sparingly responded to COVID-19 by removing specific policies or increasing premiums for newly sold policies for older people. However, the effectiveness of these immediate measures has not been analyzed in academic research so far. Against this background, we examine the impact of a joint financial and mortality shock on a life insurer’s risk situation in a COVID-19 stress test. Furthermore, we evaluate the effectiveness of different risk mitigation strategies observed in practice that can be applied on short notice to draw conclusions for potential future pandemics. We find that a temporary pandemic event such as COVID-19 affects a life insurer’s risk situation, especially in the short run, and that the immediate use of risk mitigation strategies can reduce the negative impact.
COVID-19 has increased mortality rates differently across population groups, with older individuals or those with comorbidities being the most affected [11, 29]. Spiegelhalter [38] and Sasson [36] proposed that COVID-19 caused an upward log-linear shift in mortality rates, affecting older individuals more. Schnürch et al. [37] described how to embed this shift in the popular Lee–Carter (LC) mortality model. Furthermore, they studied the impact of a COVID-19-like mortality shock on the valuation of life insurance products, similar to Carannante et al. [10] who conversely used an accelerated mortality model. Carannante et al. [9] examined the profitability of variable annuity contracts under a COVID-19-induced mortality shock, similar to Cheng [13] who focused on participating life insurance and considered changes in policyholders’ surrender behavior. While these existing studies observed only a limited impact of mortality shocks on life insurance, they did not consider joint financial and mortality shocks. Even before COVID-19, empirical research indicated that mortality and financial risks could be correlated [16] and some studies have explicitly investigated the consequences for the risk-neutral valuation of life insurance products [2, 17, 23, 28]. In the context of COVID-19, Li et al. [26] used excess mortality and interest rate data from the COVID-19 pandemic in the U.S. to calibrate a bivariate jump diffusion model for the risk-neutral pricing of mortality bonds and observed a high correlation between mortality and interest rates during the pandemic. Furthermore, Arık et al. [3] found only a small relevance of simultaneous financial and mortality shocks for the risk-neutral pricing of annuities and buyout premiums. In contrast to previous studies, we focus on a life insurer’s risk situation and the effectiveness of risk mitigation strategies rather than risk-neutral valuation.
Regarding the observed risk mitigation strategies of life insurers as an immediate response to COVID-19, Harris et al. [22] observed only a few adjustments to product pricing and offerings in the U.S.; these adjustments include slightly increased premiums by low-price leaders, increased prices for high-risk groups (e.g., smokers), and removal of specific policies offered to older people from the market. Similarly, U.S. life insurers during the Spanish flu of 1918 charged higher prices for new policies and gave up business in states with greater exposure to the disease [14]. Regarding investment strategies, Berry-Stölzle et al. [5] observed that U.S. life insurers created cash buffers by raising external capital and cutting dividends in response to the 2008–2009 financial crisis; the same approach was also observed during the COVID-19 pandemic [19]. Another common strategy is to shift assets into low-risk investments (e.g., government bonds) to avoid higher volatility caused by financial crises [24]. However, investments in bonds are exposed to credit risk, which is highly relevant for insurance investments, as downgrades by rating agencies increased during the COVID-19 pandemic [27]. In line with the academic literature, regulatory stress tests by the European and Occupational Pension Authority (EIOPA) and the Australian Prudential Authority (APRA) showed that reactive management actions, such as de-risking of assets or raising capital, can help reduce the negative impact of a COVID-19-like stress scenario [18]; the common management actions used by insurers are capital raising, reduction of new business volumes, and repricing [4].1 Building on these observations, we consider three risk mitigation strategies in our stress test: premium increases for new business, age-specific adjustments of product offerings during the pandemic, and changes in the life insurer’s investment strategy at the beginning of the pandemic.
For the model framework of our stress test, we build on previous research that used asset–liability models to study the effectiveness of natural hedging2 [20, 42] or mortality bonds [12, 21] as risk mitigation strategies. In contrast to these studies, we consider a joint financial and mortality shock calibrated to COVID-19 and analyze the effectiveness of immediate measures rather than risk mitigation strategies that had to be initialized in the past. For the mortality model of our simulation analysis, we follow Gatzert and Wesker [20] and use an extension of the LC model proposed by Brouhns et al. [8]. To embed the mortality shock, we employ the approach of Schnürch et al. [37] using mortality data from the first year of the COVID-19 pandemic. For the asset model, we differentiate between high- and low-risk investments. Both evolve according to a geometric Brownian motion, and the life insurer specifies the portfolio composition (as in Bohnert et al. [7]) making adjustments in response to the pandemic outbreak possible. To include financial shocks depending on the risk levels of investment types, we use financial data from the first year of the COVID-19 pandemic and consider market and credit risks. The life insurer’s asset–liability model accounts for regular dividend payments to shareholders and new business (term life and annuity). Policies are actuarially calculated with additional loadings sold to different age groups, allowing the assessment of the effectiveness of premium increases or age-specific adjustments in product offerings during the pandemic.
We run Monte Carlo simulations to analyze the long- and short-term effects of individual and joint financial and mortality shocks on a life insurer’s risk situation under different product portfolios (term life vs. annuity). Furthermore, we evaluate the effectiveness of the three risk mitigation strategies to reduce the negative impact of the joint financial and mortality shock for a life insurer particularly focusing on term life insurance. Our results show that financial and mortality shocks reinforce each other. The stress scenario increases the life insurer’s one-year default probabilities during the pandemic but exerts only a small long-term impact on the life insurer’s risk situation. A sufficiently large portion of annuities in the product portfolio immunizes against the mortality shock but only partially immunizes against the financial shock. Furthermore, the risk mitigation strategies reduce the negative short-term impacts, with the effectiveness depending on the respective strategies.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows: Sect. 2 introduces the mortality and asset models with embedded shock mechanisms along with the life insurer’s asset–liability model. Section 3 explains the calibration of the financial and mortality shock based on COVID-19 and the parameters used in the simulation analyses. The numerical results are presented by first examining the long- and short-term effects of the (joint) shocks and then analyzing the effectiveness of different risk mitigation strategies. Finally, Sect. 4 summarizes the main findings.

2 Model framework

In this section, we describe the model framework used in our simulation analysis to study the impact of a joint financial and mortality shock, as exemplified by COVID-19, on life insurance. We first describe the mortality model with a mortality shock, followed by the asset model with a financial shock, and finally, the life insurer’s asset–liability model.

2.1 Mortality model with shock

The mortality model describes the development of mortality rates for a given population. The mortality rate \(m\left( {x,t} \right)\) of an x-year-old person in year t is defined as
$$m\left( {x,t} \right) = \frac{{D\left( {x,t} \right)}}{{E\left( {x,t} \right)}},$$
(1)
where \(D\left( {x,t} \right)\) is the death count and \(E\left( {x,t} \right)\) is the exposure at risk. Given the mortality rates in Eq. (1), the corresponding one-year survival probability of an x-year-old person in year t can be computed using \(p_{x} \left( t \right) = \exp \left( { - m\left( {x,t} \right)} \right)\), and the one-year death probability is \(q_{x} \left( t \right) = 1 - p_{x} \left( t \right)\) [8]. The probability \({}_{n}p_{x} \left( t \right)\) that an x-year-old person in year t will survive for the next n years can be computed using \({}_{n}p_{x} \left( t \right) = \prod\nolimits_{i = 0}^{n - 1} {p_{x + i} \left( {t + i} \right)}\).
Building on Gatzert and Wesker [20], we assume that mortality rates follow the LC model [25], i.e.,
$$m\left( {x,t} \right) = \exp \left( {a_{x} + b_{x} \cdot k_{t} + \varepsilon_{x,t}^{m} } \right),$$
(2)
with age-specific constants \(a_{x}\) and \(b_{x}\), time-varying trend \(k_{t}\), and homoscedastic error terms \(\varepsilon_{x,t}^{m}\) with a mean of zero. Although the model in Eq. (2) is underdetermined, adding the two constraints
$$\sum\limits_{x} {b_{x} = 1\,\,\,\,{\text{and}}\,\,\,\,\sum\limits_{t} {k_{t} = 0} }$$
(3)
ensures identifiability [25]. Furthermore, we use an extension of the LC model proposed by Brouhns et al. [8], where the death counts \(D\left( {x,t} \right)\) are given by a Poisson distribution, i.e.,
$$D\left( {x,t} \right) \sim Poisson\left( {E\left( {x,t} \right) \cdot \hat{m}\left( {x,t} \right)} \right)\,\,\,\,{\text{with}}\,\,\,\,\hat{m}\left( {x,t} \right) = \exp \left( {a_{x} + b_{x} \cdot k_{t} } \right).$$
The unknown parameters \(a_{x}\), \(b_{x}\), and \(k_{t}\) are estimated by maximizing the corresponding log-likelihood function
$$L\left( {a_{x} ,b_{x} ,k_{t} } \right) = \sum\limits_{x,t} {\left( {D\left( {x,t} \right) \cdot \left( {a_{x} + b_{x} \cdot k_{t} } \right) - E\left( {x,t} \right) \cdot \exp \left( {a_{x} + b_{x} \cdot k_{t} } \right)} \right)}$$
using Newton’s method, where the constraints in Eq. (3) are applied after each update step [8]. To forecast mortality rates beyond the time of observation, the estimated parameters \(k_{t}\) are used to fit a time series model. Lee and Carter [25] employed a simple random walk with drift, i.e.,
$$k_{t + 1} = \phi + k_{t} + \varepsilon_{t} ,$$
(4)
where \(\phi\) is a constant drift and \(\varepsilon_{t}\) denotes independent normally distributed random variables with a mean of zero and constant volatility \(\sigma\).3
In year \(t = \tilde{t}\), a pandemic event occurs and increases mortality in this specific year. To model the mortality shock in year \(\tilde{t}\), we build on the empirical observations during COVID-19, showing that the increase is age-specific and can be approximated by an upward log-linear shift for the 25–84 age group [36, 37]. Therefore, following Schnürch et al. [37] we consider the adjusted mortality rate
$$m_{shock} \left( {x,t} \right) = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\left( {1 + c} \right) \cdot m\left( {x,t} \right)\,\,\,\,{\text{if}}\,\,\,\,t = \tilde{t}} \\ {m\left( {x,t} \right)\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,{\text{else }}\,\,\,\,\, \, } \\ \end{array} } \right.$$
(5)
for a strictly positive constant c. Assuming that \(m\left( {x,t} \right)\) and \(m_{shock} \left( {x,t} \right)\) follow an LC model, Schnürch et al. [37] mathematically proved that the only difference between the two LC models is approximately given by an increase in \(k_{{\tilde{t}}}\) without affecting \(k_{t}\) in other years \(t \ne \tilde{t}\) or the parameters \(a_{x}\) and \(b_{x}\). Therefore, we employ a single LC model in our stress test, where parameter \(k_{t}\) is increased by a strictly positive constant \(k_{shock}\) in the year of the pandemic event \(\tilde{t}\), i.e.,
$$k_{t}^{shock} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {k_{t} + k_{shock} \,\,\,\,{\text{if}}\,\,\,\,t = \tilde{t}} \\ {k_{t} \,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,{\text{else}}\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,} \\ \end{array} } \right.,\,\,\,\,a_{x}^{shock} = a_{x} \,\,\,\,{\text{and}}\,\,\,\,\,b_{x}^{shock} = b_{x} .$$

2.2 Asset model with financial shock

The asset model accounts for two types of investments. A high-risk investment S represents stocks while a low-risk investment B represents bonds. As in Bohnert et al. [7], the asset prices \(I_{t}^{i}\) of both investments \(i \in \left\{ {S,B} \right\}\) evolve over time t according to the geometric Brownian motion, i.e.,
$$dI_{t}^{i} = \mu_{i} \cdot I_{t}^{i} \cdot dt + \sigma_{i} \cdot I_{t}^{i} \cdot dW_{t}^{i}$$
with drifts \(\mu_{i}\), volatilities \(\sigma_{i}\), and Brownian motions \(W_{t}^{i}\). The solutions for the stochastic differential equations are given by
$$I_{t}^{i} = I_{t - 1}^{i} \cdot \exp \left( {\mu_{i} - \frac{{\sigma_{i}^{2} }}{2} + \sigma_{i} \cdot \varepsilon_{t}^{i} } \right)\,$$
(6)
with independent standard normally distributed random variables \(\varepsilon_{t}^{i}\). Therefore, investments \(i \in \left\{ {S,B} \right\}\) yield a continuous one-year return of
$$r_{t}^{i} = \mu_{i} - \sigma_{i}^{2} /2 + \sigma_{i} \cdot \varepsilon_{t}^{i} .$$
(7)
To account for credit risk, the investments in bonds are reduced by the portfolio loss
$$L_{t} = EAD_{t} \cdot LGD_{t} \cdot \tilde{L}_{t}$$
(8)
with exposure at default \(EAD_{t}\), loss given default \(LGD_{t}\), and normalized portfolio loss \(\tilde{L}_{t}\).4 The normalized portfolio loss is Vasicek distributed, i.e.,
$$\tilde{L}_{t} = \Phi \left( {\frac{{\sqrt {1 - \rho } \cdot \varepsilon_{t}^{L} - \Phi^{ - 1} \left( {PD_{t} } \right)}}{\sqrt \rho }} \right),$$
where \(\Phi\) denotes the standard normal distribution, \(PD_{t}\) denotes the default parameters, \(\rho\) denotes the correlation parameter, and \(\varepsilon_{t}^{L}\) denote independent standard normally distributed random variables.5 The correlations between \(\varepsilon_{t}^{S}\), \(\varepsilon_{t}^{B}\), and \(\varepsilon_{t}^{L}\) are denoted as \(\rho_{SB}\), \(\rho_{SL}\), and \(\rho_{BL}\), respectively.
To model a financial shock in year \(\tilde{t}\), we consider a price drop in combination with increased volatility for both investments \(i \in \left\{ {S,B} \right\}\), i.e.,
$$\varepsilon_{t}^{i} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} { - \left| {\varepsilon_{t}^{i} } \right|\,\,\,{\text{if}}\,\,\,\,t = \tilde{t}} \\ {\,\varepsilon_{t}^{i} \,\,\,\,\,\,\,{\text{else}}\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,} \\ \end{array} } \right.\,\,\,\,{\text{and}}\,\,\,\,\sigma_{i} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\sigma_{i} + \sigma_{i}^{shock} \,\,\,{\text{if}}\,\,\,\,t = \tilde{t}} \\ {\sigma_{i} \,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,{\text{else}}\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,} \\ \end{array} } \right.$$
(9)
for strictly positive constants \(\sigma_{i}^{shock}\). Consequently, the asset prices in Eq. (6) become
$$I_{t}^{i} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {I_{t - 1}^{i} \cdot \exp \left( {\mu_{i} - \frac{{\left( {\sigma_{i} + \sigma_{i}^{shock} } \right)^{2} }}{2} - \left( {\sigma_{i} + \sigma_{i}^{shock} } \right) \cdot \left| {\varepsilon_{t}^{i} } \right|\,} \right)\,\,\,\,\,\,\,{\text{if}}\,\,\,\,t = \tilde{t}} \\ {I_{t - 1}^{i} \cdot \exp \left( {\mu_{i} - \frac{{\sigma_{i}^{2} }}{2}} \right) + \sigma_{i} \cdot \varepsilon_{t}^{i} \,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,{\text{else}}\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,} \\ \end{array} } \right.$$
and the returns in Eq. (7) become
$$r_{t}^{i} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\mu_{i} - {{\left( {\sigma_{i} + \sigma_{i}^{shock} } \right)^{2} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\left( {\sigma_{i} + \sigma_{i}^{shock} } \right)^{2} } {\,2}}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\,2}} - \left( {\sigma_{i} + \sigma_{i}^{shock} } \right) \cdot \left| {\varepsilon_{t}^{i} } \right|\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,{\text{if}}\,\,\,\,t = \tilde{t}} \\ {\mu_{i} - \sigma_{i}^{2} /2 + \sigma_{i} \cdot \varepsilon_{t}^{i} \,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,{\text{else}}{.}\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,} \\ \end{array} } \right.$$
To account for an increased credit risk in year \(\tilde{t}\), we use two different default parameters, i.e.,
$$PD_{t} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {PD^{shock} \,\,\,\,{\text{if}}\,\,\,\,t = \tilde{t}} \\ {PD\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,{\text{else}}{.}\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,} \\ \end{array} } \right.$$
(10)

2.3 Asset–liability model

The asset–liability model of our stress test describes the situation of a life insurer who frequently writes new business over a time horizon of T years. Cash flows only arise at the beginning of year t denoted by \(t^{ + }\) or at the end of the year denoted by \(t^{ - }\). The life insurer is founded in year \(1^{ + }\) and sells term life insurance contracts with death benefit D as well as temporary annuities with annual payments R. Both types of contracts have a term of T years. The age x of the purchasing policyholders varies, and the number of contracts sold in year t to policyholders with age x is denoted by \(n_{D} \left( {x,t} \right)\) for term life insurances and \(n_{R} \left( {x,t} \right)\) for annuities.
Term life insurance contracts are sold against annual premiums while annuities are sold against single premiums. The premiums are actuarially fair with an additional loading \(\lambda\) and depend on the year of sale and the age of the purchaser, i.e.,
$$P_{D} \left( {x,t} \right) = \left( {1 + \lambda } \right) \cdot D \cdot \frac{{{}_{T|}A_{x}^{(t)} }}{{\ddot{a}_{{x:\left. {\overline {\, T \,}}\! \right| }}^{(t)} }}\,\,\,\,{\text{and}}\,\,\,\,P_{R} \left( {x,t} \right) = \left( {1 + \lambda } \right) \cdot R \cdot a_{{x:\left. {\overline {\, T \,}}\! \right| }}^{(t)} .$$
(11)
The corresponding actuarial present values are given by
$$\begin{gathered} {}_{T|}A_{x}^{(t)} = \sum\limits_{k = 0}^{T - 1} {v^{k + 1} } \cdot {}_{k}p_{x} \left( t \right) \cdot q_{x + k} \left( {t + k} \right),\,\,\,\,\,\ddot{a}_{{x:\left. {\overline {\, T \,}}\! \right| }}^{(t)} = \sum\limits_{k = 0}^{T - 1} {v^{k} } \cdot {}_{k}p_{x} \left( t \right)\,\,\,\, \\ {\text{and}}\,\,\,\,a_{{x:\left. {\overline {\, T \,}}\! \right| }}^{(t)} = \sum\limits_{k = 1}^{T} {v^{k} } \cdot {}_{k}p_{x} \left( t \right), \\ \end{gathered}$$
(12)
where \(v = 1/\left( {1 + r^{G} } \right)\) denotes the discount factor for some actuarial interest rate \(r^{G}\).
When the life insurer is founded in year \(1^{ + }\), shareholders make an initial contribution \(E_{0}\), and the first contracts are sold, resulting in the insurer’s initial asset volume of
$$A_{{1^{ + } }} = E_{0} + \sum\limits_{x} {n_{D} \left( {x,1} \right) \cdot P_{D} \left( {x,1} \right)} + \sum\limits_{x} {n_{R} \left( {x,1} \right) \cdot P_{R} \left( {x,1} \right)} .$$
For the transition from \(t^{ + }\) to \(t^{ - }\), the fraction \(\alpha\) of assets \(A_{{t^{ + } }}\) is invested in stocks, and the fraction \(\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\) is invested in bonds. Accounting for the continuous interest rates for the stock investments \(r_{t}^{S}\) and bond investments \(r_{t}^{B}\) (see Eq. (7)), as well as the portfolio loss \(L_{t}\) (see Eq. (8)), the adjusted assets are given by
$$A_{{t^{ - } }}^{adj} = \alpha \cdot A_{{t^{ + } }} \cdot \exp \left( {r_{t}^{S} } \right) + \left( {\left( {1 - \alpha } \right) \cdot A_{{t^{ + } }} - L_{t} } \right) \cdot \exp \left( {r_{t}^{B} } \right).$$
(13)
To define contractual payments at the end of the year, let \(d_{D} \left( {x,\tau ,t} \right)\) and \(d_{R} \left( {x,\tau ,t} \right)\) respectively denote the number of deaths in year t of the policyholders who bought a term life insurance contract or an annuity at the beginning of year \(\tau\) at age x. Furthermore, let
$$\vec{n}_{i} \left( {x,\tau ,t} \right) = n_{i} \left( {x,\tau } \right) - \sum\limits_{k = \tau }^{t} {d_{i} \left( {x,\tau ,k} \right)} \,\,\,\,\,:\,\,\,\,\,i \in \left\{ {D,R} \right\}$$
denote the number of contracts bought in year \(\tau\) by policyholders with age x who are still active in \(t^{ - }\).6 Given this notation, the adjusted assets in Eq. (13) are reduced by contractual payments, and some dividend div7 is paid to shareholders, i.e.,
$$A_{{t^{ - } }} = A_{{t^{ - } }}^{adj} - D \cdot \sum\limits_{\tau = 1}^{t} {\sum\limits_{x} {d_{D} \left( {x,\tau ,t} \right)} } - R \cdot \sum\limits_{\tau = 1}^{t} {\sum\limits_{x} {\vec{n}_{R} \left( {x,\tau ,t} \right)} } - div.$$
The assets at the beginning of all years \(t > 1\) are given by
$$A_{{t^{ + } }} = A_{{\left( {t - 1} \right)^{ - } }} + \sum\limits_{\tau = t - T}^{t - 1} {\sum\limits_{x} {P_{D} \left( {x,\tau } \right) \cdot \vec{n}_{D} \left( {x,\tau ,t - 1} \right) + \sum\limits_{x} {P_{D} \left( {x,t} \right) \cdot n_{D} \left( {x,t} \right)} + \sum\limits_{x} {P_{R} \left( {x,t} \right) \cdot n_{R} \left( {x,t} \right)} } } .$$
Using the actuarial notation from Eq. (12), the value of liabilities in year t for a single term life insurance policy bought in year \(\tau\) by an x-year-old person is
$$V_{D} \left( {x,\tau ,t} \right) = D \cdot {}_{{T - \vec{\tau }|}}A_{{x + \vec{\tau }}}^{(t)} - P_{D} \left( {x,\tau } \right) \cdot \ddot{a}_{{x + \vec{\tau }:\left. {\overline {\, {T - \vec{\tau }} \,}}\! \right| }}^{(t)} ,$$
where \(\vec{\tau } = t - \tau\) denotes the time since the contract was concluded. Similarly, the value of liabilities in year t for a single annuity contract bought in year \(\tau\) by an x-year-old person is given by
$$V_{R} \left( {x,\tau ,t} \right) = R \cdot a_{{x + \vec{\tau }:\left. {\overline {\, {T - \vec{\tau }} \,}}\! \right| }}^{(t)} .$$
Accounting for all active contracts at the end of year t, the life insurer’s required policy reserves can be computed as
$$PR_{{t^{ - } }} = \sum\limits_{\tau = 1}^{t} {\sum\limits_{x} {\vec{n}_{D} \left( {x,\tau ,t} \right) \cdot V_{D} \left( {x,\tau ,t + 1} \right)} } + \sum\limits_{\tau = 1}^{t} {\sum\limits_{x} {\vec{n}_{R} \left( {x,\tau ,t} \right) \cdot V_{R} \left( {x,\tau ,t + 1} \right)} } .$$
To investigate the life insurer’s risk situation, the one-year default probabilities \(DP_{t}\) and the overall default probability DP over the entire time horizon are considered. Accordingly, let \(T_{s} = \inf \left\{ {t = 1,...\,,T:A_{{t^{ - } }} < PR_{{t^{ - } }} } \right\}\) denote the stopping time when the life insurer’s assets drop below the policy reserves for the first time. Then, the overall default probability is given by
$$DP = P\left( {T_{s} \le T} \right),$$
and the one-year default probabilities are
$$DP_{t} = P\left( {A_{{t^{ - } }} < PR_{{t^{ - } }} |A_{{\tau^{ - } }} \ge PR_{{\tau^{ - } }} {\mkern 1mu} {\mkern 1mu} \forall \tau < t} \right) = \frac{{P\left( {T_{s} = t} \right)}}{{P\left( {T_{s} > t - 1} \right)}}.$$

3 Numerical analysis

This section describes the calibration of the mortality and financial shocks based on observations from the first year of the COVID-19 pandemic, along with the parameters used in our simulation analysis. Subsequently, the numerical results of the simulation analysis are presented by first showing the impact of the joint financial and mortality shock on the life insurer’s risk situation and then examining the effectiveness of the different risk mitigation strategies.

3.1 Calibration of mortality and financial shocks

COVID-19 affected mortality rates differently in geographic regions such as the EU because of differences in various aspects, such as political decision making or healthcare systems [41]. Therefore, we use Germany and Spain, two of the five largest EU countries by population, to calibrate two different and representative mortality shocks in our stress test. Germany has a particularly low crude mortality rate while Spain has a particularly high crude mortality rate caused by COVID-19 [41]. For both countries, the parameters of the LC model given in Eq. (2) are estimated using mortality data from 1990 to 2019 provided by the Human Mortality Database. Age x is restricted to 25–85 years to ensure the adequacy of an upward log-parallel shift in mortality, as observed during the COVID-19 pandemic [36, 37].
To forecast mortality rates beyond the year 2019 with the two LC models, we use the estimated parameters \(k_{t}\) to fit a random walk with drift (see Eq. (4)). Similar values are obtained for both countries: \(\phi^{Ger} = - 1.37\) for Germany and \(\phi^{Spa} = - 1.72\) for Spain, with standard deviations \(\sigma^{Ger} = 1.57\) and \(\sigma^{Spa} = 2.90\), respectively, for the error terms \(\varepsilon_{t}\). Figure 1 shows the estimated parameters \(k_{t}\) for both countries along with a specific forecast until the year 2060, with the general trend shifting to higher longevity. The estimated parameters \(a_{x}\) and \(b_{x}\) are shown in the Appendix (see Fig. 9). For both countries, \(a_{x}\) steadily increases for age x while \(b_{x}\) indicates a higher sensitivity toward the time trend parameter \(k_{t}\) for ages around 30 and 75 years. Only for \(x < 35\) years is parameter \(a_{x}\) lower for Germany than for Spain; for these ages, parameter \(b_{x}\) is clearly higher for Spain than for Germany. As a result, we observe higher mortality rates for Germany than for Spain in our model owing to the longevity trend (see also Eq. (2)).8
To include the pandemic shock in year 2020, we replace the parameters \(k_{2020}\) with estimates of two additional LC models fitted on mortality data including the year 2020 [37]. For both countries, a jump in the pandemic year 2020 runs counter to the general demographic trend (see Fig. 1). In line with the observations by Villani et al. [41], the jump from − 18.23 to − 15.24 \(\left( {k_{shock} = 2.99} \right)\) for Germany is less pronounced (see Fig. 1a) while the jump from − 27.11 to − 13.63 \(\left( {k_{shock} = 13.48} \right)\) for Spain is more pronounced (see Fig. 1b).
As exemplified by COVID-19, a pandemic event can also influence financial markets [1, 43]. To calibrate a realistic stress scenario in the stress test, we exemplarily analyze the impact of COVID-19 on the European stock performance index “S&P Europe 350” and “S&P Eurozone Sovereign Bond Index”.9 While Fig. 2a shows that COVID-19 had a strong impact on the stock market index, with a sharp decline in 2020, only a small impact can be observed on the bond market index; this result is in line with the general observations during financial crises [24]. Furthermore, Fig. 2b, c show that COVID-19 increased the stock and bond markets’ volatility at an annual level, with the effect being particularly more pronounced for the stock market. Building on these empirical observations, we set \(\sigma_{S}^{shock} = 0.10\) and \(\sigma_{B}^{shock} = 0.01\) in Eq. (9) to represent the observed increase in volatility in 2020 (see Fig. 2b, c).
Although investments in bonds are often assumed to be safe havens during financial crises [24], as supported by the results in Fig. 2, they are exposed to credit risk. The large number of downgrades made by financial rating agencies during the COVID-19 pandemic suggests that credit risk increased during this period [27]. As shown in Fig. 3, the highest number of sovereign bond defaults rated by Moody’s occurred in the first year of COVID-19 in 2020. The annual default rate in 2020 was 4.2% while the average annual default rate between 1983 and 2021 was 0.8%. Building on this observation, we assume increased portfolio loss \(L_{{\tilde{t}}}\) in the pandemic year by setting \(PD^{shock} = 4.2\%\) and \(PD = 0.8\%\) in Eq. (10).

3.2 Input parameters

For the asset–liability model of the life insurer, we use a time horizon of \(T = 20\) years and a death benefit of \(D =\) €100,000, representing the default values for term life insurance on Germany’s largest aggregator, www.​check24.​de. In this study, we assume that starting with year 1 every year, 9000 new term life insurance contracts are sold, split into three batches of size 3000 for the different age groups of \(x = 30\), \(x = 40\), and \(x = 50\) years,10 i.e.,
$$n_{D} \left( {x,t} \right) = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {3000\,\,\,\,{\text{if}}\,\,\,\,\,x \in \left\{ {30,\,\,40,\,\,50} \right\}} \\ {0\,\,\,\,{\text{else}}{.}\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,\,} \\ \end{array} } \right.\,$$
We also accept that every year \(n_{R}\) temporary annuities with an annual annuity payment of \(R =\) €6000 are sold to a single age group of \(x = 65\) years. The number of annually sold annuities \(n_{R}\) is subject to a sensitivity analysis in Sect. 3.3 and then hold constant at \(n_{R} = 50\) for the remaining analyses. For the actuarial present values in Eq. (12), the mortality forecasts of the two fitted LC models (Germany and Spain) are utilized. The actuarial interest rate \(r^{G}\) is set to 0.25%, representing the legal requirement for German life insurers in 2023. We present the results under actuarially fair premiums using the premium loading \(\lambda = 0\). The shareholders’ initial contribution \(E_{0}\) is accepted to be 3% of the initially sold contracts’ present value.
To estimate the drift, volatility, and correlation of the stock and bond investment, we employ the monthly data of the stock market index “S&P Europe 350” and “S&P Eurozone Sovereign Bond Index” from February 2013 to December 2021 and obtain \(\mu_{S} = 0.095\), \(\sigma_{S} = 0.142\), \(\mu_{B} = 0.033,\) \(\sigma_{B} = 0.037\), and \(\rho_{SB} = 0.143\). The stock ratio \(\alpha\) is set to 15%.11 For the market rate of return \(r_{M}\), which is used only to calculate dividends in this simulation analysis, we use the same value of 5% as in Gatzert and Wesker [20]. For the portfolio loss \(L_{t}\) in Eq. (8), the exposure at default is set as the fraction of assets invested in bonds, i.e., \(EAD_{t} = \left( {1 - \alpha } \right) \cdot A_{t^{ + }}\). The loss given default is set to \(LGD_{t} = 47\%\) while the correlation parameter is set to \(\rho = 0.20\).12 Furthermore, we assume no correlation between portfolio loss and investment returns in this simulation, i.e., \(\rho_{SL} = \rho_{BL} = 0\).
In the following analyses, all numerical results are obtained using Monte Carlo simulations with 500,000 sample paths. Depending on the section, calibrated financial and/or mortality shocks are applied (see Sect. 3.1), where the year of the pandemic event is set to the 10th year after the life insurer’s founding, i.e., \(\tilde{t} = 10\). Table 1 summarizes the parameters used in the simulation analysis.
Table 1
Parameters for analysis
Description
Notation
Value
Time horizon
T
20
Time of the pandemic event
\(\tilde{t}\)
10
Number of annually sold term life policies
\(n_{D}\)
9000
Policyholders’ age groups (term life insurance)
\(x_{D}\)
30, 40, 50
Death benefit
D
100,000
Number of annually sold annuities
\(n_{R}\)
50
Policyholders’ age groups (annuity)
\(x_{R}\)
65
Annual annuity
R
6000
Premium loading
\(\lambda\)
0.000
Drift of high-risk investment (stocks)
\(\mu_{S}\)
0.095
Volatility of high-risk investment (stocks)
\(\sigma_{S}\)
0.142
Drift of low-risk investment (bonds)
\(\mu_{B}\)
0.033
Volatility of low-risk investment (bonds)
\(\sigma_{B}\)
0.037
Correlation between high- and low-risk investment
\(\rho_{SB}\)
0.143
Correlation between portfolio loss and investment return
\(\rho_{SL}\); \(\rho_{BL}\)
0.000
Stock ratio
\(\alpha\)
0.150
Loss given default
LGD
0.470
Default probability parameter of the Vasicek distribution
PD
0.008
Correlation parameter of the Vasicek distribution
\(\rho\)
0.200
Market rate on return
\(r_{M}\)
0.050

3.3 Impact of COVID-19 shock on life insurer’s risk situation

The COVID-19 stress test consists of two parts: the financial shock, which is equal for Germany and Spain; and the mortality shock, which is more pronounced for Spain than for Germany (see Sect. 3.1). Figure 4a shows the overall default probability DP over the entire time horizon of \(T = 20\) years when no shock is applied depending on the number of annually sold annuities \(n_{R}\) for Germany and Spain. As separate mortality models are calibrated for both countries, the results differ between Germany and Spain even in the absence of the mortality shock. If the life insurer sells only term life insurance \(\left( {n_{R} = 0} \right)\), the overall default probabilities DP for Germany and Spain are 12.18 and 14.83%, respectively. Germany’s lower default probability can be explained by its higher mortality rates (see Sect. 3.1), which result in shorter durations until death and thus less volatile cash flows (see also [42]). For both countries, the lowest default probability DP can be observed when a small amount of \(n_{R} = 100\) annuities is sold every year, in addition to the term life insurance; it then steadily increases for higher numbers of annually sold annuities \(n_{R}\). This finding is in line with Gatzert and Wesker [20] and can be explained by the smoother and, therefore, less volatile cash flow structures of mixed portfolios consisting of annuities and term life insurances.
Figure 4b shows the absolute increase in DP caused by the mortality and/or financial shocks in \(t = 10\). In comparison with that in Germany, the more pronounced mortality shock in Spain leads to a higher increase in DP. Meanwhile, the financial shock increases DP approximately equally for Germany and Spain. For both countries, the increase in DP caused by the pure financial shock is greater than that caused by the pure mortality shock. Higher numbers of annually sold annuities reduce the negative impact of the financial shock until a saturation point of approximately 3.5 percentage points. However, the mortality shock can be completely absorbed by natural hedging [20, 42]. If both shocks are applied simultaneously, the increase in DP exceeds the sum of the individual shocks through an additional reinforcement effect (see Fig. 4b). The extent of the reinforcement effect decreases as the number of annually sold annuities increases, further emphasizing the benefits of natural hedging.
These results show that a diversified life insurer is relatively well immunized against the pure mortality shock caused by COVID-19 but that natural hedging cannot mitigate the risks caused by the simultaneous financial shock. As a life insurer’s product mix cannot be adjusted at short notice and doing so might not even be possible because of a specific market orientation, the following analyses focus on a life insurer with a high share of term life insurance, i.e., we set \(n_{R} = 50\).13 The default probabilities for this scenario are listed in Table 2.
Table 2
Default probabilities DP in case of \(n_{R} = 50\) for Germany and Spain caused by the financial and/or mortality shock in \(t = 10\)
 
Germany
Spain
DP
Absolute increase
DP
Absolute increase
No shock
9.29%
 
10.12%
 
Financial shock
15.13%
+ 5.84 p.p
15.59%
+ 5.47 p.p
Mortality shock
9.47%
+ 0.18 p.p
10.88%
+ 0.76 p.p
Both shocks
16.11%
+ 6.82 p.p
19.42%
+ 9.30 p.p
Notes: The absolute increase is expressed in percentage points (p.p.)
To investigate the short- and long-term effects of a COVID-19-like event, we present in Fig. 5 the absolute increase of the one-year default probabilities \(DP_{t}\) caused by the joint financial and mortality shock in \(t = 10\) (filled bars). The years before the pandemic outbreak \(\left( {t < 10} \right)\) are not displayed as the one-year default probabilities are not affected until that point of time. For Germany (Fig. 5a) and Spain (Fig. 5b), the highest increase in the one-year default probabilities can be seen right at the end of that year. For later years, the increase exponentially decreases and converges against zero. The long-term effects result from the life insurer’s reduced equity leading to higher default probabilities in the subsequent years as reserves must first be rebuilt. Although the increase for Spain starts at a higher level (7.90 percentage points) than that for Germany (5.44 percentage points), the convergence toward zero is similarly fast for both countries, falling below 0.2 percentage points four years after the end of the pandemic. As mortality rates are only increased in \(t = 10\), higher payments for term life insurance are limited to this period too, as is the reduction of the life insurer’s assets caused by the temporary financial shock. Therefore, the long-term impact is comparatively small. This result is in line with the findings of Carannante et al. [10], who showed that a temporary mortality shock would have a minor impact on life insurance, whereby the required premium increase to compensate an accelerated mortality decreases for longer contract terms.
Motivated by previous events such as the 1918 Spanish flu or the 2004 earthquake, mortality shocks are usually assumed to be short-term catastrophes that do not extend over several years [12, 15]. However, the case of COVID-19 indicates that a large-scale pandemic can increase mortality rates in the span of more than one year. Therefore, Fig. 5 also shows the impact of a two-year pandemic event in our stress test (unfilled bars), where the financial and mortality shocks are applied in years \(t = 10\) and \(t = 11\). In this case the one-year default probabilities first increase until the end of \(t = 11\) and then again converge against zero. The higher increase in \(t = 11\) may be explained by the life insurer’s already reduced reserves caused by the shocks in \(t = 10\), resulting in a worse financial starting point for the life insurer to enter the second year of the pandemic. As the decrease after the end of the two-year shock is exponential, as in the case of the one-year shock, the long-term impact for life insurance seems negligible even if the pandemic extends over several years.

3.4 Risk mitigation in the event of shocks

In this section, we investigate the effectiveness of different risk mitigation strategies to reduce the impact of the joint financial and mortality shock. We restrict our analysis to observed practices that can be applied on short notice, namely, stopping new business, increasing premiums, and adjusting investment strategies. Furthermore, we build on the results described in the previous section, showing that the impact of the shocks is short term regardless of the duration of the pandemic. Thus, we focus on the joint shock only applied in year \(t = 10\), with the different risk mitigation strategies applied directly at the beginning of that year in \(t = 10^{ + }\). Although this approach would mean that the life insurer anticipates the pandemic before it starts and responds immediately, this point in time serves as a threshold, i.e., a lower bound, owing to the used time steps of one year.14

3.4.1 Stopping new business

For the first risk mitigation strategy, we analyze the effectiveness of stopping new business for specific age groups during the pandemic. This strategy is motivated by the empirical findings of Harris et al. [22], who showed that some U.S. life insurers stopped selling specific policies for the oldest age groups in response to COVID-19.
Figure 6 shows the absolute increase in the one-year default probabilities \(DP_{t}\) caused by the joint financial and mortality shock in \(t = 10\), when in \(t = 10^{ + }\), the term life insurance contracts are sold to all age groups, or only to the age groups \(x = 30\) and \(x = 40\) years, or only to the age group \(x = 30\) years, or no term life insurance contracts are sold. The number of sold contracts is 3000 for all age groups and remains unchanged for all years before and after \(t = 10\). The more age groups are excluded, the higher the risk reduction as the height of the four consecutive bars decreases. The largest risk reduction can be observed at the end of the pandemic year \(t = 10\), and it then exponentially decreases over time, analogous to the general decline in risk reduction potential. Therefore, the analyzed strategy indeed mitigates the increase in the one-year default probabilities caused by the pandemic shock. Stopping new business during the pandemic reduces the number of sold contracts and, therefore, reduces exposure toward the mortality shock. However, as most contracts are sold before the pandemic and the strategy does not address the financial shock, the effectiveness of this strategy is relatively small and offsets only approximately 14% of the increased one-year default probability in \(t = 10\).
Furthermore, solely excluding the oldest age group, in anticipation of the greater increase in mortality for this group, is not optimal. Stopping new business for all the three age groups (unfilled bars with dashed lines) is more than three times as effective as solely excluding the oldest age group \(x = 50\) (unfilled bars with solid lines). Table 3 in the Appendix shows the overall default probability under all possible combinations of age-specific exclusions for the new term life business in year \(t = 10\). Some benefits are observed with the exclusion of older over younger individuals. However, a robustness test revealed that these benefits stem from the higher premium volumes for the contracts sold to older age groups due to their higher death probabilities rather than the greater increase in their mortality rates given the mortality shock in Eq. (5). When using age-specific death benefits in our simulation analysis to ensure that the premium volumes depend only on the number of sold contracts, we observe a higher risk reduction for excluding the younger age groups than for excluding the older age groups. Specifically, the risk for term life insurance decreases with age as the liability value becomes less volatile owing to the shorter duration until death at older ages [42]. Consequently, the general riskiness of a life insurance product can play a more important role and should not be neglected even if the mortality shock is more pronounced for older people (as in the case of COVID-19).

3.4.2 Increasing premiums

For the second risk mitigation strategy, we analyze the effectiveness of increasing actuarial fair premiums for contracts sold during the pandemic event by an additional loading. Therefore, different loadings \(\lambda\) for the contracts sold in \(t = 10^{ + }\) are used in Eq. (11) in the simulation analysis. The premiums before and after \(t = 10\) are unchanged, i.e., actuarial fair premiums with \(\lambda = 0\%\).
Figure 7 shows the absolute increase in the one-year default probabilities \(DP_{t}\) caused by the joint financial and mortality shock in \(t = 10\) for different loadings \(\lambda\). The loading \(\lambda = 0\%\) (filled bars) serves as a reference point, where actuarial fair premiums are used during the pandemic. For the loadings \(\lambda > 0\%\), the increase in the one-year default probabilities is reduced with the largest risk reduction at the end of the pandemic year in \(t = 10\). As higher loadings increase the life insurer’s equity and thus help to avoid liquidity shortage, this strategy addresses the negative impact of the financial and mortality shocks; by contrast, stopping new business during the pandemic only addresses the negative impact of the mortality shock on newly sold contracts. Hence, using a comparatively small loading of \(\lambda = 2\%\) for the contracts sold in year \(t = 10^{ + }\) reduces the one-year default probabilities more than stopping the sale of all term life insurance contracts during the pandemic (see Figs. 6 and 7). Moreover, a sufficiently large loading can fully offset the increase in the one-year default probabilities \(DP_{t}\). For Germany, the loading of \(\lambda = 23\%\) completely negates the increase in \(DP_{t}\) caused by the joint financial and mortality shock in \(t = 10\) for all \(t \ge 10\) (see Fig. 7a).15
This mechanism makes premium increases a hypothetically attractive short-term strategy. However, in practice, this strategy carries the risk of losing a leading market position to competitors, which can result in a decline in demand in subsequent years. This assumption is also supported by Harris et al. [22], who observed that the premium response of U.S. life insurers to COVID-19 was minimal and limited to life insurers with a certain price gap toward competitors. Meanwhile, policyholders might even accept premium increases during a pandemic event because of the stronger sensitization toward death and, therefore, a higher willingness to pay for term life insurance [35]. Assuming that the premium increase only leads to a decline in demand during the period when premiums increase, this condition would technically result in a combined strategy of stopping new business and increasing premiums, which would (in our simulation) be superior to the sole strategy of stopping new business.

3.4.3 Adjusting investment strategies

For the third risk mitigation strategy, we analyze the effectiveness of changing the investment strategy at the beginning of the pandemic year. We assume that the stock ratio \(\alpha\) in Eq. (13) is reduced at \(t = 10^{ + }\) and remains constant for the remaining time horizon to account for the long-term nature of bonds. Higher shares in bonds generally reduce asset volatility and the exposure toward the volatility shock; this effect is less pronounced for bonds than for stocks in our stress test (see Fig. 2b, c). However, in our stress test, bond investments are exposed to credit risk, which is increased by the financial shock (see Sect. 3.1). Figure 8 shows the absolute increase in the one-year default probabilities \(DP_{t}\) caused by the joint financial and mortality shock in year \(t = 10\) for different adjustments of the stock ratio \(\alpha\) in \(t = 10^{ + }\). The stock ratio \(\alpha = 15\%\) (filled bars) serves as a reference point, where the investment strategy remains unchanged.
Reducing the stock ratio \(\alpha\) at the beginning of the pandemic decreases the absolute increase in \(DP_{t}\) in \(t = 10\) to a minimum of 3.67 (5.63) percentage points for Germany (Spain) if all assets are reallocated to bonds, i.e., \(\alpha = 0\%\) (see Fig. 8). Thereby, the largest step-wise reduction effect of 0.80 (0.96) percentage points for Germany (Spain) is obtained with the reduction of \(\alpha\) from 15 to 10% while the smallest step-wise risk reduction of 0.39 (0.55) percentage points is obtained with the reduction of \(\alpha\) from 5 to 0%. In later years, the one-year default probabilities \(DP_{t}\) start to increase again at some point \(t \ge 11\), which happens earlier and is more pronounced for lower stock ratios \(\alpha\). This observation is consistent for both countries, showing that a reduction in the stock ratio can have a more pronounced long-term effect than the other two strategies. Therefore, adjusting the investment strategy might be less suitable for mitigating the negative impact of a short-term pandemic event such as COVID-19. Overall, the strategy seems more effective than stopping new business (see Fig. 6) but is more limited than the strategy of increasing premiums (see Fig. 7).16 Furthermore, reallocating all assets to bonds may not be worthwhile for shareholder value maximization because of the comparably small further risk reduction at the cost of a lower profit potential.

4 Summary

In this study, we examine the effectiveness of different risk mitigation strategies that can be applied on short notice during a pandemic on the basis of a COVID-19 stress test for life insurance. To the best of our knowledge, this study is the first to use an asset–liability model to examine the impact of a joint financial and mortality shock caused by COVID-19 on a life insurer offering annuities and term life insurances. Mortality rates are modeled by an extension of the LC model, where we use mortality data from the first year of the COVID-19 pandemic in Germany (smaller shock) and Spain (larger shock) to embed realistic mortality shocks. Financial shock differs between high- and low-risk investments, increases market and credit risks, and is calibrated to financial data from the first year of the COVID-19 pandemic. The life insurer’s asset–liability model accounts for new business (annuity and term life) sold to policyholders of different age groups, actuarial fair premiums, and dividend payments to shareholders. First, we use Monte Carlo simulation to analyze the long- and short-term effects of the individual and joint shocks on the life insurer’s risk situation under different product portfolios (annuity vs. term life). Second, we investigate the effectiveness of three risk mitigation strategies observed in practice, focusing on a life insurer with a high share of term life insurance. We consider stopping new business for certain age groups, increasing premiums during the pandemic, and adjusting the investment portfolio at the beginning of the pandemic.
The numerical results of our simulation analysis show that financial and mortality shocks can reinforce each other and, therefore, should not be analyzed separately. Product diversification, i.e., selling annuities next to term life insurances, can completely negate the negative impact of the mortality shock but not that of the financial shock. Furthermore, our results indicate that a temporary pandemic event such as COVID-19 might have only a limited impact on the long-term risk situation of life insurers as the increase in one-year default probabilities exponentially decreases immediately after the end of the pandemic in our simulation analysis. Stopping new business during the pandemic reduces the negative impact of the stress scenario; however, its effectiveness is low. Furthermore, we observe that solely excluding policies for older age groups (in anticipation of a larger mortality shock at older ages) is not necessarily beneficial as older policyholders generally carry lower risks due to their shorter duration until death. Premium increases during a pandemic turn out to be a very effective risk mitigation strategy in our stress test as it increases the life insurer’s equity, helping to deal with the financial and mortality shocks. However, in practice, this strategy bears the risk of losing market position. Adjusting the investment portfolio at the beginning of the pandemic is more effective than stopping sales but leads to more pronounced negative long-term effects owing to the long-term nature of bond investments and might be less suitable for mitigating the risks of a short-term pandemic event such as COVID-19.
In conclusion, our simulation analysis shows that either the applicability in practice or the effectiveness of such immediate measures is limited. Therefore, more sophisticated risk mitigation strategies, such as reinsurance or alternative risk transfer seem unavoidable for life insurers next to product portfolio diversification. While investigating these strategies is beyond the scope of the current study, further research could analyze their effectiveness under a COVID-19 stress test. Additionally, our findings are limited to the impact of COVID-19 on mortality and insurer investment; hence, other aspects such as demand or contract cancellation could also be addressed in future research. Our results also rely on the specific impact of COVID-19 on mortality and financial markets, and such effect may differ in future pandemics. Furthermore, the study does not examine the effectiveness of combining different strategies, which might also be interesting to analyze. Although the greatest impact of COVID-19 appears to be over, the next pandemic will likely occur sooner than expected, and life insurers should be prepared for this situation. Even when specific characteristics differ between pandemics, this study provides some general insights into what to expect and how to respond as a life insurer.

Acknowledgements

The author would like to thank Cassandra Cole, Nadine Gatzert, the participants at the Annual Meeting of the American Risk and Insurance Association 2023 in Washington D.C., and two anonymous reviewers for valuable comments on an earlier version of this paper.
Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://​creativecommons.​org/​licenses/​by/​4.​0/​.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Anhänge

Appendix

See Fig. 9, Tables 3, 4 and 5.
Table 3
Overall default probability DP when in year \(t = 10\), the joint financial and mortality shock is applied for Germany and Spain under different numbers of sold contracts in \(t = 10^{ + }\)
Number of sold term life contracts in \(t = 10^{ + }\)
Age groups
Germany
Absolute decrease
Spain
Absolute decrease
9000
30/40/50
16.11%
19.42%
6000
40/50
16.07%
− 0.04 p.p.
19.40%
− 0.02 p.p.
6000
30/50
16.04%
− 0.07 p.p.
19.25%
− 0.17 p.p.
6000
30/40
15.86%
− 0.25 p.p.
19.10%
− 0.32 p.p.
3000
50
15.97%
− 0.14 p.p.
19.15%
− 0.27 p.p.
3000
40
15,81%
− 0.30 p.p.
18.98%
− 0.44 p.p.
3000
30
15.77%
− 0.34 p.p.
18.89%
− 0.53 p.p.
0
 
15.16%
− 0.95 p.p.
18.12%
− 1.30 p.p.
Notes: The number of sold contracts is 3000 for all age groups, and the absolute decrease is expressed in percentage points (p.p.)
Table 4
Overall default probability DP when in year \(t = 10\), the joint financial and mortality shock is applied for Germany and Spain under different loadings \(\lambda\) in \(t = 10^{ + }\)
 
Germany
Absolute decrease
Spain
Absolute decrease
\(\lambda = 0\%\)
16.11%
19.42%
\(\lambda = 1\%\)
15.45%
− 0.66 p.p.
18.69%
− 0.73 p.p.
\(\lambda = 2\%\)
14.83%
− 1.28 p.p.
17.99%
− 1.43 p.p.
\(\lambda = 23\%\)
9.04%
− 7.07 p.p.
10.38%
− 9.04 p.p.
Notes: The absolute decrease is expressed in percentage points (p.p.)
Table 5
Overall default probability DP when in year \(t = 10\), the joint financial and mortality shock is applied for Germany and Spain under different adjusted stock ratios \(\alpha\) in \(t = 10^{ + }\)
 
Germany
Absolute decrease
Spain
Absolute decrease
\(\alpha = 15\%\)
16.11%
19.42%
\(\alpha = 10\%\)
15.29%
− 0.82 p.p.
18.49%
− 0.93 p.p.
\(\alpha = 5\%\)
15.03%
− 1.08 p.p.
18.11%
− 1.31 p.p.
\(\alpha = 0\%\)
15.48%
− 0.63 p.p.
18.48%
− 0.94 p.p.
Notes: The absolute decrease is expressed in percentage points (p.p.)
Fußnoten
1
Note that regulatory stress tests consider joint financial and mortality shocks but apply many simultaneous shocks to complex balance sheets relying on standard formulas, rarely consider multi-timestep internal models, and most often present results in an accumulated way.
 
2
The literature on natural hedging shows that selling annuities next to term life insurance is an effective tool to hedge against mortality risks and to smooth cash flow structures in general [20, 42].
 
3
Note that more sophisticated time series models (e.g., ARIMA models) can be considered too [20, 25] and that the random walk with drift could be replaced by a Brownian motion with drift in a continuous time model [6].
 
4
The normalized portfolio loss \(\tilde{L}_{t}\) represents the loss of a large homogeneous portfolio consisting of N non-recoverable loans with equal values \(1/N\) and equal default probabilities \(PD_{t}\). Assuming that the assets of the borrowing companies are modeled by geometric Brownian motions with equal correlation parameters \(\rho\), the normalized portfolio loss \(\tilde{L}_{t}\) converges for \(N \to \infty\) against the Vasicek distribution [40].
 
5
Note that this approach is motivated in the Capital Requirement Regulation of Basel III (see Regulation (EU) No 575/2013, article 153).
 
6
For \(\tau < 1\) and \(t < \tau\), we set \(\vec{n}_{i} \left( {x,\tau ,t} \right) = 0\).
 
7
The dividend is calculated by \(r_{M} \cdot E_{0} = \left( {1 - 0.005} \right) \cdot div + 0.005 \cdot \left( { - E_{0} } \right)\) based on the assumption that the shareholders assume a constant one-year default probability of 0.5%, with \(r_{M}\) denoting the market rate of return [20].
 
8
Note that this observation is in line with the higher life expectancy in Spain than Germany [32].
 
9
In contrast to our approach for the mortality shock, we do not differentiate between Germany and Spain for the financial shock as the sales area is most often geographically restricted to the country of origin; the same does not hold true for financial markets.
 
10
While the number of contracts is chosen to be equal for the different age groups to increase the interpretability of the results, the selection of the 30-, 40-, or 50-year-old purchasers is motivated by the research showing that the probability of owning term life insurance is highest for the age group of 50–59 years [39].
 
11
According to the German Insurance Association, 83.4% of the assets of German life insurers consisted of bonds and real estate while shares and participating interest accounted for 14.0% in 2022 (see www.​gdv.​de).
 
12
The loss given default of 47% derives from an average recovery rate on defaulted sovereign bonds over the 1983–2021 period of 53% [31]. Furthermore, inserting the average annual default rate of 0.8% over the same period in the standard formula of the Capital Requirement Regulation of Basel III yields the correlation parameter of 20% (see Regulation (EU) No 575/2013, article 153).
 
13
Note that in this case, the premium volume of annuities is approximately 8.7% (11.2%) of the total premium volume in the case of Germany (Spain).
 
14
Note that similar results regarding the effectiveness of the different risk mitigation strategies are obtained when the shocks extend over two consecutive years and the strategies are applied at the beginning of the second year.
 
15
For further information, Table 4 in the Appendix contains values for the overall default probability DP under the different loadings used in \(t^{ + } = 10\).
 
16
This is also supported by the values of the overall default probabilities given in Table 5 in the Appendix.
 
Literatur
1.
Zurück zum Zitat Albulescu CT (2021) COVID-19 and the United States financial markets’ volatility. Financ Res Lett 38:1–5CrossRef Albulescu CT (2021) COVID-19 and the United States financial markets’ volatility. Financ Res Lett 38:1–5CrossRef
2.
Zurück zum Zitat Arık A, Yolcu-Okur Y, Şahin Ş, Uğur Ö (2018) Pricing pension buy-outs under stochastic interest and mortality rates. Scand Actuar J 2018(3):173–190MathSciNetCrossRefMATH Arık A, Yolcu-Okur Y, Şahin Ş, Uğur Ö (2018) Pricing pension buy-outs under stochastic interest and mortality rates. Scand Actuar J 2018(3):173–190MathSciNetCrossRefMATH
3.
Zurück zum Zitat Arık A, Uğur Ö, Kleinow T (2023) The impact of simultaneous shocks to financial markets and mortality on pension buy-out prices. ASTIN Bull 53(2):392–417MathSciNetCrossRefMATH Arık A, Uğur Ö, Kleinow T (2023) The impact of simultaneous shocks to financial markets and mortality on pension buy-out prices. ASTIN Bull 53(2):392–417MathSciNetCrossRefMATH
5.
Zurück zum Zitat Berry-Stölzle TR, Nini GP, Wende S (2014) External financing in the life insurance industry: evidence from the financial crisis. J Risk Insur 81(3):529–562CrossRef Berry-Stölzle TR, Nini GP, Wende S (2014) External financing in the life insurance industry: evidence from the financial crisis. J Risk Insur 81(3):529–562CrossRef
6.
Zurück zum Zitat Biffis E, Denuit M (2006) Lee-Carter goes risk-neutral: an application to the Italian Annuity Market. G Ist Ital Attuar 69:33–53 Biffis E, Denuit M (2006) Lee-Carter goes risk-neutral: an application to the Italian Annuity Market. G Ist Ital Attuar 69:33–53
7.
Zurück zum Zitat Bohnert A, Gatzert N, Jørgensen PL (2015) On the management of life insurance company risk by strategic choice of product mix, investment strategy and surplus appropriation schemes. Insur Math Econ 60:83–97MathSciNetCrossRefMATH Bohnert A, Gatzert N, Jørgensen PL (2015) On the management of life insurance company risk by strategic choice of product mix, investment strategy and surplus appropriation schemes. Insur Math Econ 60:83–97MathSciNetCrossRefMATH
8.
Zurück zum Zitat Brouhns N, Denuit M, Vermunt JK (2002) A Poisson log-bilinear regression approach to the construction of projected lifetables. Insur Math Econ 31(3):373–393MathSciNetCrossRefMATH Brouhns N, Denuit M, Vermunt JK (2002) A Poisson log-bilinear regression approach to the construction of projected lifetables. Insur Math Econ 31(3):373–393MathSciNetCrossRefMATH
9.
Zurück zum Zitat Carannante M, D’Amato V, Fersini P, Forte S, Melisi G (2022) Disruption of life insurance profitability in the aftermath of the COVID-19 pandemic. Risks 10(2):1–16CrossRef Carannante M, D’Amato V, Fersini P, Forte S, Melisi G (2022) Disruption of life insurance profitability in the aftermath of the COVID-19 pandemic. Risks 10(2):1–16CrossRef
10.
Zurück zum Zitat Carannante M, D’Amato V, Haberman S (2022) COVID-19 accelerated mortality shocks and the impact on life insurance: the Italian situation. Ann Actuar Sci 16(3):478–497CrossRef Carannante M, D’Amato V, Haberman S (2022) COVID-19 accelerated mortality shocks and the impact on life insurance: the Italian situation. Ann Actuar Sci 16(3):478–497CrossRef
11.
Zurück zum Zitat Cairns AJG, Blake D, Kessler AR, Kessler M (2020) The impact of COVID-19 on future higher-age mortality. Working Paper University of London Cairns AJG, Blake D, Kessler AR, Kessler M (2020) The impact of COVID-19 on future higher-age mortality. Working Paper University of London
12.
Zurück zum Zitat Chen H, Cox SH (2009) Modeling mortality with jumps: applications to mortality securitization. J Risk Insur 76(3):727–751CrossRef Chen H, Cox SH (2009) Modeling mortality with jumps: applications to mortality securitization. J Risk Insur 76(3):727–751CrossRef
13.
Zurück zum Zitat Cheng C (2022) Beyond death: the impact of a population-wide health shock on life insurance. North Am J Econ Financ 63:1–10CrossRef Cheng C (2022) Beyond death: the impact of a population-wide health shock on life insurance. North Am J Econ Financ 63:1–10CrossRef
14.
Zurück zum Zitat Cortes G, Verdickt G (2023) Did the 1918–19 influenza pandemic kill the U.S. life insurance industry? Working Paper University of Florida Cortes G, Verdickt G (2023) Did the 1918–19 influenza pandemic kill the U.S. life insurance industry? Working Paper University of Florida
16.
Zurück zum Zitat Dacorogna MM, Cadena M (2015) Exploring the dependence between mortality and market risks. SCOR Papers 4:1–31 Dacorogna MM, Cadena M (2015) Exploring the dependence between mortality and market risks. SCOR Papers 4:1–31
17.
Zurück zum Zitat Deelstra G, Grasselli M, Van Weverberg C (2016) the role of the dependence between mortality and interest rates when pricing guaranteed annuity options. Insur Math Econ 71:205–219MathSciNetCrossRefMATH Deelstra G, Grasselli M, Van Weverberg C (2016) the role of the dependence between mortality and interest rates when pricing guaranteed annuity options. Insur Math Econ 71:205–219MathSciNetCrossRefMATH
20.
Zurück zum Zitat Gatzert N, Wesker H (2012) The impact of natural hedging on a life insurer’s risk situation. J Risk Fin 13(5):396–423CrossRef Gatzert N, Wesker H (2012) The impact of natural hedging on a life insurer’s risk situation. J Risk Fin 13(5):396–423CrossRef
21.
Zurück zum Zitat Gatzert N, Wesker H (2014) Mortality risk and its effect on shortfall and risk management in life insurance. J Risk Insur 81(1):57–90CrossRef Gatzert N, Wesker H (2014) Mortality risk and its effect on shortfall and risk management in life insurance. J Risk Insur 81(1):57–90CrossRef
22.
Zurück zum Zitat Harris TF, Yelowitz A, Courtemanche C (2021) Did COVID-19 change life insurance offerings? J Risk Insur 88(4):831–861CrossRef Harris TF, Yelowitz A, Courtemanche C (2021) Did COVID-19 change life insurance offerings? J Risk Insur 88(4):831–861CrossRef
23.
Zurück zum Zitat Jalen L, Mamon R (2009) Valuation of contingent claims with mortality and interest rate risks. Math Comput Model 49(9–10):1893–1904MathSciNetCrossRefMATH Jalen L, Mamon R (2009) Valuation of contingent claims with mortality and interest rate risks. Math Comput Model 49(9–10):1893–1904MathSciNetCrossRefMATH
24.
Zurück zum Zitat Kopyl KA, Lee JB-T (2016) How safe are the safe haven assets? Financ Mark Portfol Manag 30(4):453–482CrossRef Kopyl KA, Lee JB-T (2016) How safe are the safe haven assets? Financ Mark Portfol Manag 30(4):453–482CrossRef
25.
Zurück zum Zitat Lee RD, Carter LR (1992) Modeling and forecasting U.S. mortality. J Am Stat Assoc 87(419):659–671MATH Lee RD, Carter LR (1992) Modeling and forecasting U.S. mortality. J Am Stat Assoc 87(419):659–671MATH
26.
Zurück zum Zitat Li H, Liu H, Tang Q, Yuan Z (2023) Pricing extreme mortality risk in the wake of the COVID-19 pandemic. Insur Math Econ 108:84–106MathSciNetCrossRefMATH Li H, Liu H, Tang Q, Yuan Z (2023) Pricing extreme mortality risk in the wake of the COVID-19 pandemic. Insur Math Econ 108:84–106MathSciNetCrossRefMATH
27.
Zurück zum Zitat Liedtke PM (2021) Vulnerabilities and resilience in insurance investing: studying the COVID-19 pandemic. Geneva Pap Risk Insur Issues Pract 46(2):266–280CrossRef Liedtke PM (2021) Vulnerabilities and resilience in insurance investing: studying the COVID-19 pandemic. Geneva Pap Risk Insur Issues Pract 46(2):266–280CrossRef
28.
Zurück zum Zitat Liu X, Mamon R, Gao H (2014) A generalized pricing framework addressing correlated mortality and interest risks: a change of probability measure approach. Stochastics 86(4):594–608MathSciNetCrossRefMATH Liu X, Mamon R, Gao H (2014) A generalized pricing framework addressing correlated mortality and interest risks: a change of probability measure approach. Stochastics 86(4):594–608MathSciNetCrossRefMATH
29.
Zurück zum Zitat Liu J, Zhang L, Yan Y, Zhou Y, Yin P, Qi J, Wang L, Pan J, You J, Yang J, Zhao Z, Wang W, Liu Y, Lin L, Wu J, Li X, Chen Z, Zhou M (2021) Excess mortality in Wuhan City and other parts of China during the three months of the COVID-19 outbreak: findings from Nationwide Mortality Registries. BMJ 372:1–10 Liu J, Zhang L, Yan Y, Zhou Y, Yin P, Qi J, Wang L, Pan J, You J, Yang J, Zhao Z, Wang W, Liu Y, Lin L, Wu J, Li X, Chen Z, Zhou M (2021) Excess mortality in Wuhan City and other parts of China during the three months of the COVID-19 outbreak: findings from Nationwide Mortality Registries. BMJ 372:1–10
33.
Zurück zum Zitat Richards SJ (2022) Real-time measurement of portfolio mortality levels in the presence of shocks and reporting delays. Ann Actuar Sci 16(3):430–452CrossRef Richards SJ (2022) Real-time measurement of portfolio mortality levels in the presence of shocks and reporting delays. Ann Actuar Sci 16(3):430–452CrossRef
34.
Zurück zum Zitat Richter A, Wilson TC (2020) Covid-19: implications for insurer risk management and the insurability of pandemic risk. Geneva Risk Insur Rev 45(2):171–199CrossRef Richter A, Wilson TC (2020) Covid-19: implications for insurer risk management and the insurability of pandemic risk. Geneva Risk Insur Rev 45(2):171–199CrossRef
35.
Zurück zum Zitat Qian X (2021) The impact of COVID-19 pandemic on insurance demand: the case of China. Eur J Health Econ 22(7):1017–1024CrossRef Qian X (2021) The impact of COVID-19 pandemic on insurance demand: the case of China. Eur J Health Econ 22(7):1017–1024CrossRef
36.
Zurück zum Zitat Sasson I (2021) Age and COVID-19 mortality: a comparison of Gompertz doubling time across countries and causes of death. Demogr Res 44:379–396CrossRef Sasson I (2021) Age and COVID-19 mortality: a comparison of Gompertz doubling time across countries and causes of death. Demogr Res 44:379–396CrossRef
37.
Zurück zum Zitat Schnürch S, Kleinow T, Korn R, Wagner A (2022) The impact of mortality shocks on modelling and insurance valuation as exemplified by COVID-19. Ann Actuar Sci 16(3):498–526CrossRef Schnürch S, Kleinow T, Korn R, Wagner A (2022) The impact of mortality shocks on modelling and insurance valuation as exemplified by COVID-19. Ann Actuar Sci 16(3):498–526CrossRef
38.
Zurück zum Zitat Spiegelhalter D (2020) Use of “Normal” risk to improve understanding of dangers of COVID-19. BMJ 370:1–7 Spiegelhalter D (2020) Use of “Normal” risk to improve understanding of dangers of COVID-19. BMJ 370:1–7
39.
Zurück zum Zitat Swiss Re (2013) Life insurance: focusing on the consumer. Swiss Re Sigma 2013(6):1–40 Swiss Re (2013) Life insurance: focusing on the consumer. Swiss Re Sigma 2013(6):1–40
40.
Zurück zum Zitat Vasicek OA (2015) Limiting loan loss probability distribution. In: Vasicek OA (ed) Finance, economics and mathematics. Wiley, New YorkCrossRef Vasicek OA (2015) Limiting loan loss probability distribution. In: Vasicek OA (ed) Finance, economics and mathematics. Wiley, New YorkCrossRef
41.
Zurück zum Zitat Villani L, McKee M, Cascini F, Ricciardi W, Boccia S (2020) Comparison of deaths rates for COVID-19 across European during the first wave of the COVID-19 pandemic. Front Public Health 8:1–5CrossRef Villani L, McKee M, Cascini F, Ricciardi W, Boccia S (2020) Comparison of deaths rates for COVID-19 across European during the first wave of the COVID-19 pandemic. Front Public Health 8:1–5CrossRef
42.
Zurück zum Zitat Wong A, Sherris M, Stevens R (2017) Natural hedging strategies for life insurers: impact of product design and risk measure. J Risk Insur 84(1):153–175CrossRef Wong A, Sherris M, Stevens R (2017) Natural hedging strategies for life insurers: impact of product design and risk measure. J Risk Insur 84(1):153–175CrossRef
43.
Zurück zum Zitat Zhang D, Hu M, Ji Q (2020) Financial markets under the global pandemic of COVID-19. Financ Res Lett 36:1–6CrossRef Zhang D, Hu M, Ji Q (2020) Financial markets under the global pandemic of COVID-19. Financ Res Lett 36:1–6CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
A COVID-19 stress test for life insurance: insights into the effectiveness of different risk mitigation strategies
verfasst von
Moritz Hanika
Publikationsdatum
07.12.2023
Verlag
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Erschienen in
European Actuarial Journal
Print ISSN: 2190-9733
Elektronische ISSN: 2190-9741
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s13385-023-00371-3