Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Logistics Research 1/2014

Open Access 01.12.2014 | Review

A review of competitive facility location in the plane

verfasst von: Tammy Drezner

Erschienen in: Logistics Research | Ausgabe 1/2014

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

In this paper, we review competitive location models. Retail facilities operate in a competitive environment with an objective of profit and market share maximization. These facilities are different from each other in their overall attractiveness to consumers. The basic problem is the optimal location of one or more new facilities in a market where competition already exists or will exist in the future. Extensions to the models include an analysis of the optimal allocation of a budget among new facilities and their best locations, modeling location under conditions of uncertainty and future competition, incorporating the concept of a threshold in competitive location, modeling lost demand, and minimizing cannibalization.

1 Introduction

Facility location models deal, for the most part, with the location of plants, warehouses, distribution centers, and other industrial facilities. These location models do not account for competition or for differences among facilities and therefore allocate consumers to facilities by proximity. In reality, retail facilities operate in a competitive environment with an objective of profit and market share maximization. These facilities are different from each other in their overall attractiveness to consumers. One branch of location analysis focuses on the location of retail and other commercial facilities which operate in a competitive environment, namely, competitive facility location. The basic problem is the optimal location of one or more new facilities in a market where competition already exists or will exist in the future. When the budget invested in expanding market share is fixed, profit increases when market share increases; thus, maximizing profit is equivalent to maximizing market share (for a discussion, see [14, 63, 88]. It follows, then, that the location objective is to locate the retail outlet at the location that maximizes its market share.
A unique feature of competitive facility location models is facility attractiveness (its appeal to consumers). Facilities differ in the total “bundle of benefits” they offer consumers. They vary in one or more of the attributes which make up their total attractiveness to consumers.
Also unique to competitive facility location is the modeling of demand in terms of buying power. Income levels and discretionary spending become a measure of demand. For a review of competitive models, see Eiselt et al. [46], Berman et al. [11], Drezner [18], Serra and ReVelle [80], Plastria [70, 71], Drezner and Eiselt [40].
The underlying theme running through all competitive models is the existence of an interrelationship between four variables: buying power (demand), distance, facility attractiveness, and market share, with the first three variables being independent variables and the last the dependent variable. Most location papers assume a certain approach to estimating market share and then find the location for new competing facilities based on such approach. Once buying power, distance, and attractiveness are known, market share can be calculated by approaches rooted in consumer behavior theory (for a review of consumer behavior theory, see Anderson et al. [6] and also see Ben-Akiva et al. [8], McFadden [65], Rusmevichientong et al. [78] ). For a review of store choice models, the reader is referred to Fotheringham [48], Timmermans et al. [84], Fotheringham and Trew [49], Volle [86].
Competitive location models are investigated in planar continuous space and in discrete space, in particular in a network environment. Continuous models seek the location of facilities anywhere in the plane; thus, there is an infinite number of potential locations for the facilities. Discrete models restrict the location of facilities to a pre-specified set of potential locations, typically the nodes of a network.
Bell et al. [7], Nakanishi and Cooper [66], and Jain and Mahajan [62] applied the competitive models to the location of grocery stores. Huff [61] applied them to grocery stores, furniture stores, and clothing stores. Drezner and Drezner [27] and Drezner [20] applied the competitive models to the location of shopping malls. Goodchild and Noronha [55] applied them to the location of gas stations, and Drezner [22] applied them to the hotel industry.
In this paper, we review competitive location models in the plane, focusing on two approaches to estimating market share: (1) the proximity approach [59] and (2) the gravity rule [60, 61, 76] discussed in Sect. 2.5. Many of the models discussed in this manuscript apply also to discrete models.
The location discussion according to the two approaches to estimating market share is followed by additional modeling considerations and implementation issues. In the last section, conclusions are drawn and suggestions for future research are proposed.

2 Estimating market share

Various approaches were proposed to modeling the interrelationship between buying power (demand), distance, facility attractiveness, and market share and obtaining a reasonable estimate of the market share captured by each competing facility.

2.1 The proximity approach to estimating market share

The first modern paper on competitive facility location is generally agreed to be Hotelling’s [59] paper on duopoly in a linear market. Hotelling considered the location of two competing facilities on a segment (for example, vendors on Main Street). The distribution of buying power along the segment is assumed uniform, there is no price differential, and therefore consumers patronize the closest facility. When one facility is located and there is no competition, all consumers patronize the existing facility. However, when a competing facility is introduced and is located at a different point on the segment, the consumers on one side of the midpoint between the two facilities patronize one facility and the customers on the other side of the midpoint patronize the second facility. If one facility is held fixed in place, the best location for the second is either immediately left or right of the fixed one, depending on which segment—left or right of the existing facility—is longer. Drezner [41] analyzed the proximity model in the plane.
Hotelling [59] showed that when the two competitors charge the same price (they do not compete on prices), an equilibrium exists. However, when competitors can compete on price, no equilibrium exists. The existence of an equilibrium is discussed in the literature. For a discussion of the equilibrium issue, the reader is referred to the seminal paper by d’Aspremont et al. [15] and [89, 90].
The assumption that consumers patronize the facility closest to them implies that the competing facilities are equally attractive or that consumers consider only distance in their selection. For equally attractive facilities, the plane is partitioned by a Voronoi diagram [4, 67, 68] and the demand points in each polygon are attracted to the same facility. This, in turn, implies an “all or nothing” property. The combined buying power at a demand point is assigned entirely to one facility and none is assigned to other facilities, unless two or more facilities are equidistant. A solution procedure for solving the multiple competitive facility location in the plane is proposed in Suzuki et al. [83].
The proximity assumption is appropriate either for central planning where planners allocate demand to facilities, or for public facilities, or when consumers are highly price sensitive and will always select the cheapest option. However, when consumers select facilities to patronize on their own, they do not necessarily select by proximity. There are several reasons why not to use the proximity approach:
Deficiencies of the proximity approach
1.
A small change in the location of the facilities may discontinuously shift the entire demand at a demand point from one facility to another. This is because a tenet of the proximity approach is that a facility attracts “all or nothing” of the buying power at a demand point. This property remains in deterministic utility models discussed in Sect. 2.2 where all consumers residing at a demand point patronize the facility which provides the maximum utility.
 
2.
Using distance as the sole criterion for facility patronage, choice ignores the different attractiveness levels of different facilities. Different facilities have different levels of appeal (attractiveness) to consumers, and consumers are willing to travel an extra distance to a farther but more attractive facility. This issue is rectified in the deterministic utility approach discussed in Sect. 2.2.
 
3.
Consumers do not necessarily measure the exact distance when deciding which facility to patronize. They select the facility that they perceive to be the closest to them. Distances are likely perceived differently by different consumers.
 

2.2 The deterministic utility approach to estimating market share

When the facilities are not equally attractive, the proximity premise for allocating consumers to facilities is no longer valid. To account for variations in facility attractiveness, a deterministic utility approach was introduced by Drezner [16]. Hodgson [57] also suggested to incorporate attractiveness in the competitive location model. In the deterministic utility approach, we assume that all consumers residing at the same demand point apply the same utility. This assumption can be relaxed by stratifying the consumers residing at a demand point by categories, such as income, and defining these subgroups as different demand points located at the same location. Hotelling’s approach is extended by relaxing the proximity assumption. The proximity approach is a special case of the discrete utility approach when the utility function consists of distance only (in negative sign or a reciprocal of the distance). This generalization rectifies only deficiency #2 of the proximity approach in Sect. 2.1. Consumers are known to make their choice of a facility based on factors other than distance alone. This utility function is a composite index of facility attributes and the distance to the facility, representing the expected satisfaction from that facility (either an additive or a multiplicative utility function). It is generally agreed that consumers, through a decision-making process, choose the facility with the highest utility, the facility which is expected to maximize their satisfaction. This choice is determined by some formula according to which consumers evaluate alternative facilities’ attributes weighted by their personal salience to arrive at an overall facility attractiveness.
A trade-off between distance and attractiveness takes place. Based on this premise, the degree of expected satisfaction with each alternative as a function of the relevant characteristics of that facility is measured. It is suggested that a consumer will patronize a better and farther facility as long as the extra distance to it does not exceed its attractiveness advantage because of the value of travel time. For example, factory outlet centers at the fringe of the city which offer price discounts, or, in another context, paramedics transporting a motor vehicle accident victim will bypass a nearby hospital in favor of a farther, better equipped trauma center as long as the difference in quality of care exceeds the adverse effect to the patient caused by the extra distance and time delay. The attractiveness of a facility can be transformed into a distance markup. A break-even distance is defined. At the break-even distance, the attractiveness of two competing facilities is equal. This break-even distance, therefore, is the maximum distance that a consumer will be willing to travel to a farther facility (new or existing) based on his perception of its attractiveness and advantage relative to other facilities. All consumers at a demand point will patronize the new facility if it is located within the break-even distance. While consumers are no longer assumed to patronize the closest facility, consumers at a certain demand point are assumed to apply the same utility function; therefore, they all patronize the same facility. The “all or nothing” property is maintained in this extension.

2.3 The random utility approach to estimating market share

To address the three deficiencies of the proximity assumption listed in Sect. 2.1, a random utility model was introduced by Leonardi and Tadei [64] and Drezner and Drezner [23]. The deterministic utility model is extended by assuming that each consumer draws his utility from a random distribution of utility functions. The probability that a consumer will prefer a certain facility over all other facilities is calculated by applying the multivariate normal distribution. Once the probabilities are calculated, the market share captured by a certain facility (new or existing) can be calculated as a weighted sum of the buying power at all demand points. This formulation eliminates the “all or nothing” property since a probability that a consumer will patronize a particular facility can be established and is no longer either 0 or 100 %. To circumvent the mathematically complicated formulation of the random utility model, Drezner et al. [36] suggested using a simple S-shaped function. The utility declines very slowly for small distances, declines sharply for intermediate distances, and remains around zero for large distances.

2.4 The cover-based approach to estimating market share

Drezner et al. [38, 39] introduced the cover-based approach to estimating market share. Each competing facility has a “sphere of influence” [77] represented by a radius of influence which depends on the attractiveness of the facility. A consumer at a distance within the radius of influence is attracted to the facility. Consumers’ demand within the sphere of influence of no facility is lost. In Drezner et al. [38], adding additional facilities of a given radius of influence is considered as an expansion strategy. In Drezner et al. [39], three models are analyzed: (1) increasing the radius of influence of existing facilities thereby increasing their attractiveness, (2) adding new facilities (and determining the radius of influence of each), and (3) a combination of both. All these expansions have a defined cost and the best expansion strategy for a given budget is found. All three models are investigated in a unified approach. The authors are currently investigating the leader–follower model premised on the cover-based competitive location model.

2.5 The gravity-based approach to estimating market share

The gravity approach also addresses the three deficiencies of the proximity approach listed in Sect. 2.1 and is more commonly used. Most competitive location problems in the plane have recently used gravity-based models. According to the gravity rule [76], two cities attract retail trade from an intermediate town in direct proportion to the populations of the two cities and in inverse proportion to the square of the distances from them to the intermediate town. Evaluating market share based on the gravity approach was introduced by Huff [60, 61] and is used by marketers. Drezner [17, 18] was the first to introduce the gravity model to location analysis. Huff proposed that the probability that a consumer patronizes a retail facility (a mall) is proportional to its size (floor area) and inversely proportional to a power of the distance to it. Huff depicted equi-probability lines. A consumer located on such a line between two facilities patronizes the two facilities with equal probability. These equi-probability lines divide the region into catchment areas, each dominated by a facility, in a manner similar to the Voronoi diagram [68]. These lines do not define an “all or nothing” assignment of consumers to facilities, rather, at any demand point; the proportion of consumers attracted to each facility is a function of the facility’s square footage (attractiveness) and distance. The model finds the market share captured at each potential site, and thus, the best location for new facilities whose individual measures of attractiveness is known.
Suppose, there are k existing facilities and n demand points. The attractiveness of facility j is A j for i = 1,…,k, and the distance between demand point i and facility j is d ij . The buying power at demand point i is b i . Therefore, the proportion of the buying power (market share) M j attracted by facility j is: \( M_{j} = \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 1}^{n} b_{i} \frac{{{\raise0.7ex\hbox{${A_{j} }$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{A_{j} } {d_{ij}^{\lambda } }}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{${d_{ij}^{\lambda } }$}}}}{{\mathop \sum \nolimits_{m = 1}^{k} \left( {{\raise0.7ex\hbox{${A_{m} }$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{A_{m} } {d_{im}^{\lambda } }}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{${d_{im}^{\lambda } }$}}} \right)}} \) where λ is the power to which distances are raised. The gravity approach can be classified as a special case of the random utility approach as was done by Benati and Hansen [9] on the network. The utility is \( ln\left( {\frac{{A_{j} }}{{d_{ij}^{\lambda } }}} \right) + \varepsilon_{j} \) where ɛ j is an iid distribution. The issue is also discussed in Anas [5]. The original gravity approach lacks theoretical underpinnings but estimates market share quite well in practice. The issue of existing substitutable alternatives is addressed in lost demand and market expansion models discussed in Sect. 4.6.
In the original Huff formulation, facility floor area serves as a surrogate for attractiveness. An improvement on Huff’s approach was suggested by Nakanishi and Cooper [66] who introduced the multiplicative competitive interaction (MCI) model. The MCI coefficient replaces the floor area with a product of factors, each a component of attractiveness. Each factor in the product is raised to a power. Thus, the attractiveness of a facility is a composite index of a set of attributes rather than the floor area alone. Nakanishi and Cooper’s idea was elaborated on and applied by Jain and Mahajan [62] to food retailing using specific attractiveness attributes. Gravity-based models suggest the evaluation of market share for a user-provided discrete set of potential sites for the location of a new facility.
The general model can be formulated as maximizing the market share captured using a distance decay function. The two most common distance decay functions are: \( \frac{1}{{ d^{\lambda } }} \) (the original decay function suggested by Huff) or eλd. Exponential decay [58, 87] was found by Drezner [20] to be empirically superior and has been recently used extensively (for example, Aboolian et al. [1, 2], Berman and Krass [10], Bozkaya et al. [13]).

3 Implementation

In this section, we discuss how to operationalize and implement competitive location models.

3.1 Determining the parameters

Once buying power, distance, and attractiveness are known, market share can be calculated by the approaches discussed in Sect. 2.
Data about the following parameters are required in order to operationalize the models and evaluate the market share attracted by each facility:
  • The buying power
  • Facility attractiveness
  • The distance
Buying power: Buying power (demand), sometimes called purchasing power, is available in secondary data sources. Geographic information systems data bases, such as those provided by ESRI, also have data about buying power.
Attractiveness levels: Facility attractiveness is assessed using one of a variety of methods. The attractiveness of a facility is a composite index of a set of attributes. Varying importance assigned to each of these attributes by different consumers will result in a selective set of consumers patronizing each facility. Assessing attractiveness levels is addressed in many marketing studies. Huff [60, 61] used floor area as a surrogate for attractiveness of shopping malls. Nakanishi and Cooper [66] proposed the MCI coefficient which is a product of attractiveness attributes. Commonly used attractiveness components of shopping malls are: (1) variety of stores, (2) appearance, (3) favorite brand names. Other techniques for inferring or deriving attractiveness levels were also proposed [20, 27].
Distance: The distance between two points can be easily measured. However, since demand points represent areas, the distance correction for an area A and distance d are: where α = 0.24 is recommended [24]. Plastria and Vanhaverbeke [72] addressed the issue of aggregation (see also [50] and its effect on the optimality of the location solution. Demand points often have to be aggregated due to computational intractability. However, this spatial aggregation typically introduces a bias to the value of the objective function; thus, the optimality of the solution cannot be guaranteed. A preprocessing aggregation method is presented to reduce the number of demand points which prevents this loss of information and therefore avoids the possible loss of optimality. This issue is related to the modifiable areal unit problem [69] which investigates the effect of the scale of the unit area on the optimal solution.

3.2 Solution methods

In this section, we briefly describe solution methods used for solving planar location problems based on the gravity model. Finding the best location for a new facility (or multiple facilities) in a continuous space using the gravity model objective is discussed in Drezner [17] and Drezner and Drezner [28] for the single-facility case, and in Drezner [19], Drezner et al. [34] and Toth et al. [85] for the location of multiple facilities.

3.2.1 Locating a single facility

3.2.1.1 Generalized Weiszfeld
The generalized Weiszfeld algorithm was suggested in Drezner and Drezner [44]. Consider a minimization or maximization problem with Euclidean distances and an objective function:
$$F(X)=\sum_{i=1}^n F_i(d_i(X))$$
Equating the derivative to zero leads to a recursive formula. The recursive formula is:
$$ X = \frac{{\mathop \sum \nolimits_{i = 1}^{n} \frac{1}{{d_{i} (X)}}\frac{{\partial F_{i} (d_{i} (X))}}{{\partial d_{i} (X)}}X_{i} }}{{\mathop \sum \nolimits_{i = 1}^{n} \frac{1}{{d_{i} (X)}}\frac{{\partial F_{i} (d_{i} (X))}}{{\partial d_{i} (X)}}}} $$
A location X is selected and the right hand side is calculated; the left hand side is the next iterate. Drezner [42] proved sufficient conditions for convergence.
3.2.1.2 The big triangle small triangle
In order to optimally locate one facility the Big Triangle Small Triangle [43] can be used. It is a branch and bound algorithm based on the “Big Square Small Square” global optimization technique [56]. The feasible area is triangulated and bounds in each triangle found. Branching is done by partitioning a triangle into four small triangles.

3.2.2 Locating multiple facilities

An algorithm for locating one facility can be used in an iterative procedure for locating several facilities. Single-facility gravity models were extended to the location of multiple facilities by Achabel et al. (1982) and Ghosh and Craig [52]. Achabal et al. [3] extended the MCI model to the location of multiple facilities which belong to the same chain. The problem was modeled as a nonlinear integer programming problem, and a random search procedure combined with an interchange heuristic was employed to identify optimal and near-optimal sets of locations. Ghosh and Craig [52] proposed a franchise distribution model where an expanding franchise seeks to maximize sales. This model was also formulated as a nonlinear integer programming problem but included additional factors such as advertising. These two models select the best locations from a user-provided set of alternative sites as well.
For the location of multiple facilities in the plane, Drezner et al. [34] suggested a hybrid between the generalized Weiszfeld algorithm and simulated annealing. Toth et al. [85] used an interval branch and bound algorithm to solve the design and location of two facilities.

4 Extensions and refinements of the basic models

4.1 The location-allocation model

An extension to Hotelling’s approach to the selection of sites for facilities that serve a spatially dispersed population is the location-allocation model Ghosh and Rushton [53]. Both the facilities’ locations and the allocation of consumers to them are determined simultaneously. The allocation of consumers to facilities is made using Hotelling’s proximity assumption—each facility attracts the consumers closest to it. The market share attracted by each facility is calculated, and the best locations for the new facilities are then found. Multi-facility location-allocation models analyze the system-wide interactions among all facilities.
Revelle [77] introduced location-allocation models to competitive location. Goodchild [54] suggested the location-allocation market share model. A retail firm is planning to open a chain of outlets in a market in which a competing chain already exists. The entering firm’s goal is to maximize the total market share captured by the entire chain. Most location-allocation solution methods rely on heuristic approaches that do not guarantee an optimal solution. Rather, they provide good solutions for implementation. The best locations are selected from a user-provided, pre-specified set of potential sites. Typically, these problems are formulated on a network and the location solution is on a node. A book edited by Ghosh and Rushton [53] provides a collection of papers on the subject. A comprehensive review of location-allocation models can be found in Ghosh and Harche [51].

4.2 Limited budget (location and design models)

Drezner [19] investigated the location of multiple competing facilities in an area where other facilities already exist. The budget for constructing new facilities is given and it is up to the planner’s discretion to allocate that budget among them. Both the optimal allocation of the budget among the new facilities and the best locations for them are found.
The optimal budget allocation among the new facilities depends on the functional relationship between the investment in a new facility and its attractiveness. It is assumed that an increase in the budget invested in a facility results in an increase in the attractiveness of that facility. This relationship is referred to as the investment-attractiveness curve. Such a curve can exhibit an increasing marginal return relationship (when the attractiveness as a function of investment increases in a faster than linear rate, which means that the curve is convex), a fixed marginal return (or in other words, a linear curve), or a decreasing marginal return one (when the curve is concave). As discussed in Quirk [75], in the first phases of a new firm, the return on investment typically exhibits an increasing marginal return. New entrants to a market dominated by large, mature competitors exhibit an increasing marginal return on attractiveness with an increase in budget. This means that with any additional funds invested in a facility, the increase in its attractiveness exceeds a linear rate. Mature, well established firms typically experience decreasing marginal returns on investment, that is, the rate of increase in attractiveness is slower than linear. Moderately established firms experience a linear relationship, or close to it. It is implicitly assumed that a positive relationship exists between facility attractiveness and market share, that is, an increase in attractiveness yields an increase in the market share captured. This provides an incentive to invest in a facility in order to increase its attractiveness.
Drezner [19] concludes with the following interesting and useful findings:
1.
For mature firms with a decreasing marginal return on investment curve, the fixed budget allocation solution with equally divided budget among several new facilities is very close to optimality.
 
2.
For firms with a fixed (constant) marginal return on investment, the fixed budget allocation solution with equally divided budget is quite good and can be used if the computational effort required to obtain the flexible budget allocation solution is prohibitive.
 
3.
For start-up entrants with a rapidly increasing marginal return, one should consider opening only one new, large facility investing the entire budget in it.
 
4.
Middle of the road firms with mildly increasing marginal return should adopt a middle-ground solution, none of the extreme budget allocation strategies is appropriate. In this case, it is recommended to find the best budget allocation by using the solution methods introduced in the paper [19].
 
Constructing facilities on a network when facility attractiveness is a variable with a cost function depending on the attractiveness is termed “design”, leading to location models with design. Such a model was first proposed by Plastria and Carrizosa [72] suggesting a multitude of approaches for calculating the market share attracted by the facilities. Location of facilities on the nodes of a network was investigated in Aboolian et al. [2]. Such a model in the plane was analyzed in Fernandez et al. [47] and extended to sequential location of two facilities in Toth et al. [85].
Fernandez et al. [47] considered locating a single new facility in a planar market using the gravity model. Both the location and the attractiveness of the new facility are to be found so as to maximize the profit obtained by the chain. Several types of constraints and costs are considered. Two solution methods are developed and tested: The first is a repeated local optimization heuristic with locational constraints. The second is an exact global optimization technique using interval analysis, incorporating several novel features.
Toth et al. [85] analyzed the improvement in the quality of the solution when two facilities are located sequentially rather than simultaneously. They compare three different strategies: simultaneous location and independent design of two facilities in the plane, simultaneous location with equal designs, and the sequential approach of determining each facility in turn. The basic model is chain’s profit maximization, taking market share, location costs and design costs into account. The market share captured by each facility is calculated by the gravity model. Toth et al. [85] proposed an exact algorithm that finds optimal solutions for more than one facility. They developed an exact interval branch and bound algorithm to solve both simultaneous location and design two-facility problems.

4.3 Modeling uncertain future market conditions

Drezner [21] found the location of a new facility when future market conditions are unclear using the minimax regret objective. There are several defined scenarios concerning future market conditions:
1.
The purchase potential across communities varies during the time horizon.
 
2.
A new competitor enters the market at some point in the future.
 
3.
A competitor exits the area at some point in the future.
 
4.
A competitor renovates his facility at some point in the future thereby changing its overall attractiveness.
 
5.
One’s own facility is being remodeled and changes its attractiveness at some point in the future.
 
6.
A scenario can incorporate more than one change in market conditions by combining any number of the five scenarios above.
 
The minimax regret objective is formulated and solved in two phases:
1) The best solution for each scenario is found,
2) The location problem with an objective of minimizing the maximum deviation from the best objective value is then solved.

4.4 Minimizing the probability that the market share falls short of a target threshold

Drezner et al. [35] discussed the location of a new retail facility. They propose a different objective function observing that there is a market share threshold to be captured, below which a firm will not survive. The appropriate objective function, then, is to minimize the probability that the firm will not achieve the threshold and thus will not survive. It follows that rather than locating a facility to maximize market share, a firm should locate so as to minimize the probability of falling short of obtaining this minimum threshold.
The problem is solved in the plane using the gravity model. The threshold optimal location tends to be different from the location at which the expected market share is maximized. For a set of test problems, it was found that the location is different especially when the probability of failure to obtain the threshold is relatively low (<50 %). When the probability of failure is low, the firm should concentrate on minimizing the variance thus reducing the uncertainty. This may yield a location in a different region of the market area. When the probability of failure is high (50 % or more), the company should concentrate on maximizing the expected market share and locate close to the location at which the market share is maximized.
Blanquero et al. [12] considered the objective of robustness that is defined as the extent to which the system is able to carry out its functions despite some damage done to it, such as the removal of some of the nodes and/or links in a network. The robustness objective is to minimize the probability of not meeting a threshold. The best location for a facility is found by applying the Big Triangle Small Triangle technique proposed in Drezner and Suzuki [43].

4.5 Future competition: leader–follower

Most competitive facility location models discussed above (with the exception of location under conditions of uncertainty) attempt to find the optimal location for a new facility (facilities) by maximizing current market share against existing competition without considering future changes in the competitive environment. A different approach to competitive location focuses on anticipating and preempting future competition. It is assumed that a new competing facility (the follower) will enter the market at some point in the future. The competitor will establish his facility at the location which maximizes his market share. Therefore, one’s (the leader’s) present location decision will affect the competitor’s location decision. Conversely, a future competitive entry has implications for one’s (the leader’s) present location decision. The objective is to find the location that maximizes the market share captured by one’s own facility (the leader’s) following the competitor’s entry. This problem is known in the economic literature as the Stackelberg equilibrium problem or the leader–follower problem and as the Simpson’s problem in voting theory [79, 81, 82]. Drezner [41] analyzed the problem in the plane. Drezner and Zemel [45] showed that the solution for uniform continuous demand in the whole plane is to arrange the leader’s facilities in an hexagonal pattern. Drezner and Drezner [25] solved this problem in the plane heuristically applying the gravity model.
Such models are usually very difficult to solve. The value of the leader’s objective function can be calculated for a given location if the follower’s best location can be calculated. If the follower’s optimal location cannot be guaranteed, the objective function is not well-defined. Drezner and Drezner [25] proposed three heuristic algorithms for the solution of the single-facility location problem (for both the leader and the follower) in the plane.
The discrete version of the problem is analyzed in Plastria and Vanhaverbeke [74]. They considered the location of facilities under a budget constraint in order to maximize the remaining market share after the competitor’s later entry. They considered three strategies: the maximin strategy when a follower’s location choice is considered the worst for the leader, the minimax regret strategy, and the Stackelberg strategy in which the competitor also optimizes his market share. They developed mixed zero–one programming formulations for the solution of these models.

4.6 Lost demand (market expansion)

All models discussed above, with the exception of the cover-based competitive model [38, 39], assume that the entire demand is distributed among the competing facilities. For non-essential services, some of the demand may not be satisfied. A model assuming that some of the demand is lost is proposed in Drezner and Drezner [31]. If there is no nearby facility to patronize, consumers may use alternative products or alternative means to obtain the product. Consumers may resort to the Internet rather than drive to a far facility, consumers may decide to eat at home rather than drive to a far restaurant or rent a movie rather than drive to a theater.
Drezner and Drezner [31] proposed that the probability of patronizing a facility declines exponentially with the distance. Therefore, the probability of not patronizing any facility is the product of the probabilities of not patronizing each facility.
Drezner and Drezner [33] suggested defining a competing dummy facility at a reasonable distance from all demand points (no physical location is assumed) that attracts all lost demand. This simple scheme can be used to model and solve any “standard” competitive model by adding one additional competitor dummy facility.
The lost demand in the network environment was addressed in Aboolian et al. [2] and Berman and Krass [10]. It is called in these papers market expansion. It views recovering lost demand as an expansion of the attracted buying power [47, 72, 85].

4.7 Consistent and inconsistent consumers’ choice

Drezner et al. [37] analyzed the consistency of consumers’ facility choice. They suggested two consistency rules:
  • Consistent rule: A consumer does not change his choice on the way to the selected facility.
  • Inconsistent rule: A consumer changes his mind if on the way another facility becomes more attractive.
In the figure below, the inferior facility B attracts all demand points inside the small circle. All consumers residing in the shaded area are originally attracted to the more attractive facility A. However, when consumers follow the inconsistent rule, they enter the small circle on the way to facility A and once inside the small circle change their mind and patronize facility B. https://static-content.springer.com/image/art%3A10.1007%2Fs12159-014-0114-z/MediaObjects/12159_2014_114_Article_Figa_HTML.gif
When consumers’ choice follows the inconsistent rule, Drezner et al. [37] conclude that:
  • When locating an inferior new facility, the best location is on the way from a major consumers’ concentration to a more attractive facility. Consider a small “Mom and Pop” shop competing with a large shopping center. Consumers who are first attracted to the large shopping center will find themselves close to the small shop on their way and may patronize the small shop rather than drive the extra distance to the large shopping center.
  • The best location should not be too close to the more attractive facility so that the distance differential remains significant.
Drezner et al. [37] analyzed the issue by applying the deterministic utility approach.

4.8 Cannibalization

The first paper on the subject is by Ghosh and Craig [52] who investigated it in discrete space. Plastria [71] and Drezner [22] solved it in the plane.
Cannibalization occurs at the retail level of chain facilities (fast food, hotels), especially in the case of franchises. In this form of cannibalization, opening a new retail outlet in close proximity to an existing outlet, the new facility cannibalizes the sales of the existing one. With the growth of franchise operations, this emerges as an important and timely issue. For as long as companies wish to grow and expand, managers will be faced with the strategic decision of optimally locating new, additional facilities such that cannibalization of existing chain members is minimized.
Plastria [71] applied the proximity approach. The market share is maximized in the intersection of circles which is usually an area. Plastria [71] found the point in the area where cannibalization is minimized. Drezner [22] analyzed maximizing market share while minimizing cannibalization using the gravity model. An efficient frontier depicting the trade-offs of these two non-compatible objectives is constructed and illustrated on an example problem.

4.9 Applying the gravity approach to other location models

Most multiple facility location models assume that each consumer patronizes the closest facility. While gravity models are prevalent in competitive facility location, it may well be appropriate to apply the gravity approach to other location models. This opens a new array of possible models that can be more realistic than models based on proximity. Several location problems were already analyzed using the gravity approach for consumer choice:
Gravity hub: Drezner and Drezner [26] suggested that consumers apply the gravity approach when deciding which airline route to select from a list of routes, each using one hub. The total distance through the hub is the basis for the gravity approach.
Gravity p-Median: Drezner and Drezner [30] analyzed the p-median model with the stipulation that consumers at each demand point do not necessarily patronize the closest facility. Planar Gravity p-Median and Minimum Variance: Drezner and Drezner [29] considered the p-median in the plane and minimized the variance of loads using the gravity approach.
Gravity Multiple Server: Drezner and Drezner [32] proposed models for locating facilities and service providers to serve a set of demand points. The number of facilities is unknown. However, there is a given number of servers (such as automatic teller machines) to be distributed among the facilities. Each facility acts as an M/M/k queuing system. The objective function is the minimization of the combined travel time and waiting time at the facility for all consumers.
There are many more non-competitive location models that can be analyzed by applying the gravity approach rather than the proximity approach yet to be formulated and analyzed.

5 Summary

In Table 1, the competitive location papers in a planar environment are summarized.
Table 1
Summary of planar competitive location models
References
Model
Facilities
Comments
Achabal et al. [3]
Location-allocation
Multiple
 
Ahn et al. [4]
Location-allocation
Multiple
 
Bell et al. [7]
Gravity
Multiple
 
Berman et al. [11]
Gravity
 
Also network models
Blanquero et al. [12]
Gravity
Single
Threshold
Dasci and Laporte [14]
Utility
Multiple
Leader–follower
d’Aspremont et al. [15]
Proximity
Multiple
 
Drezner [16]
Utility
Single
 
Drezner [17]
Gravity
Single
 
Drezner [18]
Utility and gravity
Single
 
Drezner [19]
Gravity
Multiple
Budget
Drezner [20]
Gravity
Single
 
Drezner [21]
Gravity
Single
Uncertainty
Drezner [22]
Gravity
Single
Cannibalization
Drezner and Drezner [23]
Random utility
Single
 
Drezner and Drezner [24]
Gravity
Single
Area demand
Drezner and Drezner [25]
Gravity
Multiple
Leader–follower
Drezner and Drezner [44]
Gravity
Single
 
Drezner and Drezner [27]
Gravity
Single
 
Drezner and Drezner [28]
Gravity
Single
Exact algorithm
Drezner and Drezner [31]
Gravity
Single
Lost demand
Drezner and Drezner [33]
All models
Single
Lost Demand
Drezner Z. [41]
Proximity
Single and Two
Leader–follower
Drezner et al. [37]
Utility
Single
Consistency
Drezner et al. [36]
Random utility
Single
 
Drezner et al. [34]
Gravity
Multiple
 
Drezner et al. [35]
Gravity
Single
Threshold
Drezner et al. [38]
Cover
Multiple
 
Drezner et al. [39]
Cover
Multiple
Budget
Drezner and Eiselt [40]
Review
 
Consumer behavior
Drezner and Zemel [45]
Proximity
Infinite
Leader–follower, Continuous demand
Eiselt et al. [46]
Bibliography
 
Also network models
Fernandez et al. [47]
Gravity
Single
Budget
Ghosh and Harche [51]
Location-allocation
Multiple
 
Ghosh and Craig [52]
Gravity
Multiple
Cannibalization
Ghosh and Rushton [53]
Location-allocation
Multiple
 
Goodchild [54]
Location-allocation
Multiple
 
Goodchild and Noronha [55]
Location-allocation
Multiple
 
Hodgson [58]
Gravity
Multiple
 
Hotelling [59]
Proximity
Two
 
Huff [61]
Gravity
Single
 
Huff [60]
Gravity
Single
 
Jain and Mahajan. [62]
Gravity
Multiple
 
Leonardi and Tadei [64]
Random utility
Single
 
Nakanishi and Cooper [66]
Gravity
Multiple
 
Okabe and Suzuki [67]
Proximity
Multiple
Continuous demand
Plastria [70]
Review
  
Plastria and Carrizosa [71]
Utility
Single
Budget
Plastria and Vanhaverbeke [72]
Cover
Multiple
Aggregation
Plastria and Vanhaverbeke [73]
Cover
Two
Leader–follower
Suzuki et al. [82]
Utility
Multiple
 
Toth et al. [84]
Gravity
Two
Budget
Wilson [86]
Gravity
Multiple
 
Wong and Yang [88]
Utility
Multiple
Continuous demand
Yang and Wong [89]
Utility
Multiple
Continuous demand

6 Conclusions

Competitive facility location models are very useful in many situations where locations for competing retail facilities are sought. The gravity approach to estimating market share is considered to be a very effective tool for estimating the market share attracted by facilities and is also the main approach used by location modelers.
Of particular interest are the results obtained for the location of retail facilities under budget constraints. Different budget allocation strategies are recommended for mature, well-established firms, for start-up firms, and for middle of the road firms based on their return on investment patterns (see Sect. 4.2).
Also of interest is the retail location strategy based on the risk level of not achieving a minimum target threshold market share. One location strategy is recommended when the probability of not achieving the target is higher than 50 %, and another strategy when it is under 50 % (see Sect. 4.4).
In addition, the location strategy depends on the nature of the facility. “Mom and Pop” facilities should follow one strategy and established firms should follow another one (see Sect. 4.7).
There are many more aspects of competitive facility location models yet to be formulated and analyzed.
Open AccessThis article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License which permits any use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author(s) and the source are credited.
Literatur
1.
Zurück zum Zitat Aboolian R, Berman O, Krass D (2007) Competitive facility location model with concave demand. Euro J Oper Res 181:598–619CrossRef Aboolian R, Berman O, Krass D (2007) Competitive facility location model with concave demand. Euro J Oper Res 181:598–619CrossRef
2.
Zurück zum Zitat Aboolian R, Berman O, Krass D (2007) Competitive facility location and design problem. Euro J Oper Res 182:40–62CrossRef Aboolian R, Berman O, Krass D (2007) Competitive facility location and design problem. Euro J Oper Res 182:40–62CrossRef
3.
Zurück zum Zitat Achabal D, Gorr WL, Mahajan V (1982) MULTILOC: a multiple store location decision model. J Retail 58:5–25 Achabal D, Gorr WL, Mahajan V (1982) MULTILOC: a multiple store location decision model. J Retail 58:5–25
4.
Zurück zum Zitat Ahn H-K, Cheng S-W, Cheong O, Golin M, van Oostrum R (2004) Competitive facility location: the Voronoi game. Theoret Comput Sci 310:457–467CrossRef Ahn H-K, Cheng S-W, Cheong O, Golin M, van Oostrum R (2004) Competitive facility location: the Voronoi game. Theoret Comput Sci 310:457–467CrossRef
5.
Zurück zum Zitat Anas A (1982) Residential location markets and urban transportation economic theory, econometrics and policy analysis with discrete choice models, monograph. Academic Press, Waltham Anas A (1982) Residential location markets and urban transportation economic theory, econometrics and policy analysis with discrete choice models, monograph. Academic Press, Waltham
6.
Zurück zum Zitat Anderson SP, De Palma A, Thisse JF (1992) Discrete choice theory of product differentiation. The MIT press, Cambridge Anderson SP, De Palma A, Thisse JF (1992) Discrete choice theory of product differentiation. The MIT press, Cambridge
7.
Zurück zum Zitat Bell DR, Ho T-H, Tang CS (1998) Determining where to shop: fixed and variable costs of shopping. J Mark Res 35:352–369CrossRef Bell DR, Ho T-H, Tang CS (1998) Determining where to shop: fixed and variable costs of shopping. J Mark Res 35:352–369CrossRef
8.
Zurück zum Zitat Ben-Akiva M, McFadden D, Train K, Walker J, Bhat C et al (2002) Hybrid choice models: progress and challenges. Mark Lett 13:163–175CrossRef Ben-Akiva M, McFadden D, Train K, Walker J, Bhat C et al (2002) Hybrid choice models: progress and challenges. Mark Lett 13:163–175CrossRef
9.
Zurück zum Zitat Benati S, Hansen P (2002) The maximum capture problem with random utilities: problem formulation and algorithms. Eur J Oper Res 143:518–530CrossRef Benati S, Hansen P (2002) The maximum capture problem with random utilities: problem formulation and algorithms. Eur J Oper Res 143:518–530CrossRef
10.
Zurück zum Zitat Berman O, Krass D (2002) Locating multiple competitive facilities: spatial interaction models with variable expenditures. Ann Oper Res 111:197–225CrossRef Berman O, Krass D (2002) Locating multiple competitive facilities: spatial interaction models with variable expenditures. Ann Oper Res 111:197–225CrossRef
11.
Zurück zum Zitat Berman O, Drezner T, Drezner Z, Krass D (2009). Modeling competitive facility location problems: new approaches and results. In TutORials in Operations Research, San Diego CA, 156–181 Berman O, Drezner T, Drezner Z, Krass D (2009). Modeling competitive facility location problems: new approaches and results. In TutORials in Operations Research, San Diego CA, 156–181
12.
Zurück zum Zitat Blanquero R, Carrizosa E, Hendrix EMT (2011) Locating a competitive facility in the plane with a robustness criterion. Euro J Oper Res 215:21–24CrossRef Blanquero R, Carrizosa E, Hendrix EMT (2011) Locating a competitive facility in the plane with a robustness criterion. Euro J Oper Res 215:21–24CrossRef
13.
Zurück zum Zitat Bozkaya B, Yanik S, Balcisoy S (2010) A GIS-based optimization framework for competitive multi-facility location-routing problem. Netw Spat Econ 10:297–320CrossRef Bozkaya B, Yanik S, Balcisoy S (2010) A GIS-based optimization framework for competitive multi-facility location-routing problem. Netw Spat Econ 10:297–320CrossRef
14.
Zurück zum Zitat Dasci A, Laporte G (2005) A continuous model for multistore competitive location. Oper Res 53:263–280CrossRef Dasci A, Laporte G (2005) A continuous model for multistore competitive location. Oper Res 53:263–280CrossRef
15.
Zurück zum Zitat d’Aspremont C, Gabszewicz JJ, Thisse J-F (1979) On Hotelling’s ‘stability in competition’. Econometrica 47:1145–1150CrossRef d’Aspremont C, Gabszewicz JJ, Thisse J-F (1979) On Hotelling’s ‘stability in competition’. Econometrica 47:1145–1150CrossRef
16.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner T (1994) Locating a single new facility among existing unequally attractive facilities. J Reg Sci 34:237–252CrossRef Drezner T (1994) Locating a single new facility among existing unequally attractive facilities. J Reg Sci 34:237–252CrossRef
17.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner T (1994) Optimal continuous location of a retail facility, facility attractiveness, and market share: an interactive model. J Retail 70:49–64CrossRef Drezner T (1994) Optimal continuous location of a retail facility, facility attractiveness, and market share: an interactive model. J Retail 70:49–64CrossRef
18.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner T (1995) Competitive facility location in the plane. In: Drezner Z (ed) Facility location: a survey of applications and methods. Springer, NYCrossRef Drezner T (1995) Competitive facility location in the plane. In: Drezner Z (ed) Facility location: a survey of applications and methods. Springer, NYCrossRef
19.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner T (1998) Location of multiple retail facilities with a limited budget. J Retail Consum Serv 5:173–184CrossRef Drezner T (1998) Location of multiple retail facilities with a limited budget. J Retail Consum Serv 5:173–184CrossRef
20.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner T (2006) Derived attractiveness of shopping malls. IMA J Manage Math 4:349–358CrossRef Drezner T (2006) Derived attractiveness of shopping malls. IMA J Manage Math 4:349–358CrossRef
21.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner T (2009) Location of retail facilities under conditions of uncertainty. Ann Oper Res 167:107–120CrossRef Drezner T (2009) Location of retail facilities under conditions of uncertainty. Ann Oper Res 167:107–120CrossRef
22.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner T (2011) Cannibalization in a competitive environment. Int Reg Sci Rev 34:306–322CrossRef Drezner T (2011) Cannibalization in a competitive environment. Int Reg Sci Rev 34:306–322CrossRef
23.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner T, Drezner Z (1996) Competitive facilities: market share and location with random utility. J Reg Sci 36:1–15CrossRef Drezner T, Drezner Z (1996) Competitive facilities: market share and location with random utility. J Reg Sci 36:1–15CrossRef
24.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner T, Drezner Z (1997) Replacing discrete demand with continuous demand in a competitive facility location problem. Naval Res Logist 44:81–95CrossRef Drezner T, Drezner Z (1997) Replacing discrete demand with continuous demand in a competitive facility location problem. Naval Res Logist 44:81–95CrossRef
25.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner T, Drezner Z (1998) Location of retail facilities in anticipation of future competition. Locat Sci 6:155–173CrossRef Drezner T, Drezner Z (1998) Location of retail facilities in anticipation of future competition. Locat Sci 6:155–173CrossRef
26.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner T, Drezner Z (2001) A note on applying the gravity rule to the airline hub problem. J Reg Sci 41:67–73CrossRef Drezner T, Drezner Z (2001) A note on applying the gravity rule to the airline hub problem. J Reg Sci 41:67–73CrossRef
27.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner T, Drezner Z (2002) Validating the gravity-based competitive location model using inferred attractiveness. Ann Oper Res 11:227–237CrossRef Drezner T, Drezner Z (2002) Validating the gravity-based competitive location model using inferred attractiveness. Ann Oper Res 11:227–237CrossRef
28.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner T, Drezner Z (2004) Finding the optimal solution to the huff based competitive location model. CMS 11:193–208 Drezner T, Drezner Z (2004) Finding the optimal solution to the huff based competitive location model. CMS 11:193–208
29.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner T, Drezner Z (2006) Multiple facilities location in the plane using the gravity model. Geogr Anal 38:391–406CrossRef Drezner T, Drezner Z (2006) Multiple facilities location in the plane using the gravity model. Geogr Anal 38:391–406CrossRef
30.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner T, Drezner Z (2007) The gravity p-median model. Eur J Oper Res 179:1239–1251CrossRef Drezner T, Drezner Z (2007) The gravity p-median model. Eur J Oper Res 179:1239–1251CrossRef
31.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner T, Drezner Z (2008) Lost demand in a competitive environment. J Oper Res Soc 59:362–371CrossRef Drezner T, Drezner Z (2008) Lost demand in a competitive environment. J Oper Res Soc 59:362–371CrossRef
32.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner T, Drezner Z (2011) The gravity multiple server location problem. Comput Oper Res 38:694–701CrossRef Drezner T, Drezner Z (2011) The gravity multiple server location problem. Comput Oper Res 38:694–701CrossRef
33.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner T, Drezner Z (2012) Modelling lost demand in competitive facility location. J Oper Res Soc 63:201–206CrossRef Drezner T, Drezner Z (2012) Modelling lost demand in competitive facility location. J Oper Res Soc 63:201–206CrossRef
34.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner T, Drezner Z, Salhi S (2002) Solving the multiple competitive facilities location problem. Eur J Oper Res 142:138–151CrossRef Drezner T, Drezner Z, Salhi S (2002) Solving the multiple competitive facilities location problem. Eur J Oper Res 142:138–151CrossRef
35.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner T, Drezner Z, Shiode S (2002) A threshold satisfying competitive location model. J Reg Sci 42:287–299CrossRef Drezner T, Drezner Z, Shiode S (2002) A threshold satisfying competitive location model. J Reg Sci 42:287–299CrossRef
36.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner T, Drezner Z, Wesolowsky GO (1998) On the logit approach to competitive facility location. J Reg Sci 38:313–327CrossRef Drezner T, Drezner Z, Wesolowsky GO (1998) On the logit approach to competitive facility location. J Reg Sci 38:313–327CrossRef
37.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner T, Drezner Z, Eiselt HA (1996) Consistent and inconsistent rules in competitive facility choice. J Oper Res Soc 47:1494–1503CrossRef Drezner T, Drezner Z, Eiselt HA (1996) Consistent and inconsistent rules in competitive facility choice. J Oper Res Soc 47:1494–1503CrossRef
38.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner T, Drezner Z, Kalczynski P (2011) A cover-based competitive location model. J Oper Res Soc 62:100–113CrossRef Drezner T, Drezner Z, Kalczynski P (2011) A cover-based competitive location model. J Oper Res Soc 62:100–113CrossRef
39.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner T, Drezner Z, Kalczynski P (2012) Strategic competitive location: improving existing and establishing new facilities. J Oper Res Soc 63:1720–1730CrossRef Drezner T, Drezner Z, Kalczynski P (2012) Strategic competitive location: improving existing and establishing new facilities. J Oper Res Soc 63:1720–1730CrossRef
40.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner T, Eiselt HA (2002) Consumers in competitive location models. In: Drezner Z, Hamacher H (eds) Facility location: applications and theory. Springer, Berlin, pp 151–178CrossRef Drezner T, Eiselt HA (2002) Consumers in competitive location models. In: Drezner Z, Hamacher H (eds) Facility location: applications and theory. Springer, Berlin, pp 151–178CrossRef
41.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner Z (1982) Competitive location strategies for two facilities. Reg Sci Urban Econ 12:485–493CrossRef Drezner Z (1982) Competitive location strategies for two facilities. Reg Sci Urban Econ 12:485–493CrossRef
42.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner Z (2009) On the convergence of the generalized Weiszfeld algorithm. Ann Oper Res 167:327–336CrossRef Drezner Z (2009) On the convergence of the generalized Weiszfeld algorithm. Ann Oper Res 167:327–336CrossRef
43.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner Z, Suzuki A (2004) The big triangle small triangle method for the solution of non-convex facility location problems. Oper Res 52:128–135CrossRef Drezner Z, Suzuki A (2004) The big triangle small triangle method for the solution of non-convex facility location problems. Oper Res 52:128–135CrossRef
44.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner Z, Drezner T (1998) Applied location models. In: Marcoulides GA (ed) Modern methods for business research. Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Mahwah, NJ Drezner Z, Drezner T (1998) Applied location models. In: Marcoulides GA (ed) Modern methods for business research. Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Mahwah, NJ
45.
Zurück zum Zitat Drezner Z, Zemel E (1992) Competitive location in the plane. Ann Oper Res 40:173–193CrossRef Drezner Z, Zemel E (1992) Competitive location in the plane. Ann Oper Res 40:173–193CrossRef
46.
Zurück zum Zitat Eiselt HA, Laporte G, Thisse J-F (1993) Competitive location models: a framework and bibliography. Transp Sci 27:44–54CrossRef Eiselt HA, Laporte G, Thisse J-F (1993) Competitive location models: a framework and bibliography. Transp Sci 27:44–54CrossRef
47.
Zurück zum Zitat Fernandez J, Pelegrin B, Plastria F, Toth B (2007) Solving a Huff-like competitive location and design model for profit maximization in the plane. Eur J Oper Res 179:1274–1287CrossRef Fernandez J, Pelegrin B, Plastria F, Toth B (2007) Solving a Huff-like competitive location and design model for profit maximization in the plane. Eur J Oper Res 179:1274–1287CrossRef
48.
Zurück zum Zitat Fotheringham AS (1988) Consumer store choice and choice set definition. Mark Sci 7:299–310CrossRef Fotheringham AS (1988) Consumer store choice and choice set definition. Mark Sci 7:299–310CrossRef
49.
Zurück zum Zitat Fotheringham AS, Trew R (1993) Chain image and store-choice modeling: the effects of income and race. Environ Plan A 25:179–196CrossRef Fotheringham AS, Trew R (1993) Chain image and store-choice modeling: the effects of income and race. Environ Plan A 25:179–196CrossRef
50.
Zurück zum Zitat Francis RL, Lowe TJ, Rayco MB, Tamir A (2009) Aggregation error for location models: survey and analysis. Ann Oper Res 167:171–208CrossRef Francis RL, Lowe TJ, Rayco MB, Tamir A (2009) Aggregation error for location models: survey and analysis. Ann Oper Res 167:171–208CrossRef
51.
Zurück zum Zitat Ghosh A, Harche F (1993) Location-allocation models in the private sector: progress, problems, and prospects. Locat Sci 1:81–106 Ghosh A, Harche F (1993) Location-allocation models in the private sector: progress, problems, and prospects. Locat Sci 1:81–106
52.
Zurück zum Zitat Ghosh A, Craig CS (1991) FRANSYS: a franchise location model. J Retail 67:212–234 Ghosh A, Craig CS (1991) FRANSYS: a franchise location model. J Retail 67:212–234
53.
Zurück zum Zitat Ghosh A, Rushton G (1987) Spatial analysis and location allocation models. Van Nostrand Reinhold, New Jersey Ghosh A, Rushton G (1987) Spatial analysis and location allocation models. Van Nostrand Reinhold, New Jersey
54.
Zurück zum Zitat Goodchild MF (1984) ILACS: a location allocation model for retail site selection. J Retail 60:84–100 Goodchild MF (1984) ILACS: a location allocation model for retail site selection. J Retail 60:84–100
55.
Zurück zum Zitat Goodchild MF, Noronha VT (1987) Location-allocation and impulsive shopping: the case of gasoline retailing. In: Ghosh A, Rushton G (eds) Spatial analysis and location-allocation models. Van Nostrand Reinhold Company, New Jersey, pp 121–136 Goodchild MF, Noronha VT (1987) Location-allocation and impulsive shopping: the case of gasoline retailing. In: Ghosh A, Rushton G (eds) Spatial analysis and location-allocation models. Van Nostrand Reinhold Company, New Jersey, pp 121–136
56.
Zurück zum Zitat Hansen P, Peeters D, Thisse J (1981) On the location of an obnoxious facility. Sistemi Urbani 3:299–317 Hansen P, Peeters D, Thisse J (1981) On the location of an obnoxious facility. Sistemi Urbani 3:299–317
57.
Zurück zum Zitat Hodgson MJ (1978) Toward more realistic allocation in location-allocation models: an interaction approach. Environ Plan A 10:1273–1285CrossRef Hodgson MJ (1978) Toward more realistic allocation in location-allocation models: an interaction approach. Environ Plan A 10:1273–1285CrossRef
58.
Zurück zum Zitat Hodgson JM (1981) A location-allocation model maximizing consumers’ welfare. Reg Stud 15:493–506CrossRef Hodgson JM (1981) A location-allocation model maximizing consumers’ welfare. Reg Stud 15:493–506CrossRef
59.
60.
Zurück zum Zitat Huff DL (1966) A programmed solution for approximating an optimum retail location. Land Econ 42:293–303CrossRef Huff DL (1966) A programmed solution for approximating an optimum retail location. Land Econ 42:293–303CrossRef
61.
Zurück zum Zitat Huff DL (1964) Defining and estimating a trade area. J Mark 28:34–38CrossRef Huff DL (1964) Defining and estimating a trade area. J Mark 28:34–38CrossRef
62.
Zurück zum Zitat Jain AK, Mahajan V (1979) Evaluating the competitive environment in retailing using multiplicative competitive interactive models. In: Sheth JN (ed) Research in marketing, vol 2. JAI Press, Greenwich, CT, pp 217–235 Jain AK, Mahajan V (1979) Evaluating the competitive environment in retailing using multiplicative competitive interactive models. In: Sheth JN (ed) Research in marketing, vol 2. JAI Press, Greenwich, CT, pp 217–235
63.
Zurück zum Zitat Jensen MC (2000) Value maximization and the corporate objective function. In: Beer M, Norhiaeds N (eds) Breaking the code of change. Harvard Business School Press, Boston, pp 37–57 Jensen MC (2000) Value maximization and the corporate objective function. In: Beer M, Norhiaeds N (eds) Breaking the code of change. Harvard Business School Press, Boston, pp 37–57
64.
Zurück zum Zitat Leonardi G, Tadei R (1984) Random utility demand models and service location. Reg Sci Urban Econ 14:399–431CrossRef Leonardi G, Tadei R (1984) Random utility demand models and service location. Reg Sci Urban Econ 14:399–431CrossRef
65.
Zurück zum Zitat McFadden D (1986) The choice theory approach to market research. Mark Sci 5:275–297CrossRef McFadden D (1986) The choice theory approach to market research. Mark Sci 5:275–297CrossRef
66.
Zurück zum Zitat Nakanishi M, Cooper LG (1974) Parameter estimate for multiplicative interactive choice model: least squares approach. J Mark Res 11:303–311CrossRef Nakanishi M, Cooper LG (1974) Parameter estimate for multiplicative interactive choice model: least squares approach. J Mark Res 11:303–311CrossRef
67.
Zurück zum Zitat Okabe A, Suzuki A (1987) Stability of spatial competition for a large number of firms on a bounded two-dimensional space. Environ Plan A 16:107–114CrossRef Okabe A, Suzuki A (1987) Stability of spatial competition for a large number of firms on a bounded two-dimensional space. Environ Plan A 16:107–114CrossRef
68.
Zurück zum Zitat Okabe A, Boots B, Sugihara K (1992) Spatial tessellations: concepts and applications of Voronoi diagrams. John Wiley and Sons, Chichester Okabe A, Boots B, Sugihara K (1992) Spatial tessellations: concepts and applications of Voronoi diagrams. John Wiley and Sons, Chichester
69.
Zurück zum Zitat Openshaw S (1983) The modifiable areal unit problem. Geo books, Norwich Openshaw S (1983) The modifiable areal unit problem. Geo books, Norwich
70.
Zurück zum Zitat Plastria F (2001) Static competitive facility location: an overview of optimisation approaches. Eur J Oper Res 129:461–470CrossRef Plastria F (2001) Static competitive facility location: an overview of optimisation approaches. Eur J Oper Res 129:461–470CrossRef
71.
Zurück zum Zitat Plastria F (2005) Avoiding Cannibalization and/or Competitor Reaction in Planar Single Facility Location. J Oper Res Soc Jpn 48:148–157 Plastria F (2005) Avoiding Cannibalization and/or Competitor Reaction in Planar Single Facility Location. J Oper Res Soc Jpn 48:148–157
72.
Zurück zum Zitat Plastria F, Carrizosa E (2004) Optimal location and design of a competitive facility for profit maximisation. Math Progr 100:247–265CrossRef Plastria F, Carrizosa E (2004) Optimal location and design of a competitive facility for profit maximisation. Math Progr 100:247–265CrossRef
73.
Zurück zum Zitat Plastria F, Vanhaverbeke L (2007) Aggregation without Loss of Optimality in Competitive Location Models. Netw Spat Econ 7:3–18CrossRef Plastria F, Vanhaverbeke L (2007) Aggregation without Loss of Optimality in Competitive Location Models. Netw Spat Econ 7:3–18CrossRef
74.
Zurück zum Zitat Plastria F, Vanhaverbeke L (2008) “Discrete models for competitive location with foresight. Comput Oper Res 35:683–700CrossRef Plastria F, Vanhaverbeke L (2008) “Discrete models for competitive location with foresight. Comput Oper Res 35:683–700CrossRef
75.
Zurück zum Zitat Quirk JP (1986) Intermediate microeconomics, 3rd edn. SRA, Chicago Quirk JP (1986) Intermediate microeconomics, 3rd edn. SRA, Chicago
76.
Zurück zum Zitat Reilly WJ (1931) The law of retail gravitation. Knickerbocker Press, New York Reilly WJ (1931) The law of retail gravitation. Knickerbocker Press, New York
77.
Zurück zum Zitat ReVelle C (1986) The maximum capture or sphere of influence problem: Hotelling revisited on a network. J Reg Sci 26:343–357CrossRef ReVelle C (1986) The maximum capture or sphere of influence problem: Hotelling revisited on a network. J Reg Sci 26:343–357CrossRef
78.
Zurück zum Zitat Rusmevichientong P, Shen ZJM, Shmoys DB (2010) Dynamic assortment optimization with a multinomial logit choice model and capacity constraint. Oper Res 58:1666–1680CrossRef Rusmevichientong P, Shen ZJM, Shmoys DB (2010) Dynamic assortment optimization with a multinomial logit choice model and capacity constraint. Oper Res 58:1666–1680CrossRef
79.
Zurück zum Zitat Santos-Penate DR, Suarez-Vega R, Dorta-Gonzalez P (2007) The leader-follower location model. Netw Spat Econ 7:45–61CrossRef Santos-Penate DR, Suarez-Vega R, Dorta-Gonzalez P (2007) The leader-follower location model. Netw Spat Econ 7:45–61CrossRef
80.
Zurück zum Zitat Serra D, ReVelle C (1995) Competitive location on networks. In: Drezner Z (ed) Facility location: a survey of applications and methods. Springer, NY Serra D, ReVelle C (1995) Competitive location on networks. In: Drezner Z (ed) Facility location: a survey of applications and methods. Springer, NY
81.
Zurück zum Zitat Simpson PB (1969) On defining areas of voter choice: professor Tullock on stable voting. Q J Econ 83:478–490CrossRef Simpson PB (1969) On defining areas of voter choice: professor Tullock on stable voting. Q J Econ 83:478–490CrossRef
82.
Zurück zum Zitat Stackelberg HV (1934) Marktform und Gleichgewicht. Julius Springer, Vienne Stackelberg HV (1934) Marktform und Gleichgewicht. Julius Springer, Vienne
83.
Zurück zum Zitat Suzuki A, Drezner Z, Drezner T (2007) Locating multiple facilities in a planar competitive environment. J Oper Res Soc Jpn 50:1001–1014 Suzuki A, Drezner Z, Drezner T (2007) Locating multiple facilities in a planar competitive environment. J Oper Res Soc Jpn 50:1001–1014
84.
Zurück zum Zitat Timmermans H, Borgers A, Van der Waerden P (1992) Mother logit analysis of substitution effects in consumer shopping destination choice. J Bus Res 24:177–189CrossRef Timmermans H, Borgers A, Van der Waerden P (1992) Mother logit analysis of substitution effects in consumer shopping destination choice. J Bus Res 24:177–189CrossRef
85.
Zurück zum Zitat Toth B, Fernandez J, Pelegrin B, Plastria F (2009) Sequential versus simultaneous approach in the location and design of two new facilities using planar Huff-like models. Comput Oper Res 36:1393–1405CrossRef Toth B, Fernandez J, Pelegrin B, Plastria F (2009) Sequential versus simultaneous approach in the location and design of two new facilities using planar Huff-like models. Comput Oper Res 36:1393–1405CrossRef
86.
Zurück zum Zitat Volle P (2001) The short-term effect of store-level promotions on store choice, and the moderating role of individual variables. J Bus Res 53:63–73CrossRef Volle P (2001) The short-term effect of store-level promotions on store choice, and the moderating role of individual variables. J Bus Res 53:63–73CrossRef
87.
Zurück zum Zitat Wilson AG (1976) Retailers’ profits and consumers’ welfare in a spatial interaction shopping model. In: Masser I (ed) Theory and practice in regional science. Pion, London Wilson AG (1976) Retailers’ profits and consumers’ welfare in a spatial interaction shopping model. In: Masser I (ed) Theory and practice in regional science. Pion, London
88.
Zurück zum Zitat Winerfert B (1986) The relation between market share and profitability. J Bus Strategy 6:67–74CrossRef Winerfert B (1986) The relation between market share and profitability. J Bus Strategy 6:67–74CrossRef
89.
Zurück zum Zitat Wong SC, Yang H (1999) Determining market areas captured by competitive facilities: a continuous equilibrium modeling approach. J Reg Sci 39:51–72CrossRef Wong SC, Yang H (1999) Determining market areas captured by competitive facilities: a continuous equilibrium modeling approach. J Reg Sci 39:51–72CrossRef
90.
Zurück zum Zitat Yang H, Wong SC (2000) A continuous equilibrium model for estimating market areas of competitive facilities with elastic demand and market externality. Transp Sci 34:216–227CrossRef Yang H, Wong SC (2000) A continuous equilibrium model for estimating market areas of competitive facilities with elastic demand and market externality. Transp Sci 34:216–227CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
A review of competitive facility location in the plane
verfasst von
Tammy Drezner
Publikationsdatum
01.12.2014
Verlag
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Erschienen in
Logistics Research / Ausgabe 1/2014
Print ISSN: 1865-035X
Elektronische ISSN: 1865-0368
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s12159-014-0114-z

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 1/2014

Logistics Research 1/2014 Zur Ausgabe

Editorial

Editorial