Skip to main content
Erschienen in: The Annals of Regional Science 2/2017

26.06.2017 | Original Paper

A theoretical assessment on the trading arrangements for a small Asian economy with footloose entrepreneur movement toward China

verfasst von: I-Ju Tsai

Erschienen in: The Annals of Regional Science | Ausgabe 2/2017

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

A new economic geography model is used to assess the impacts of trading arrangements on the industrial development of a small economy with footloose entrepreneur movement toward China. With three regions—the small economy, the large economy (China), and the global market—the simulation results show that, to maintain itself as an industrial core, the small economy should pursue a decentralizing trade arrangement, either by significantly lowering its trade costs with the global market, or by serving as a trading hub. Without reducing the small economy’s trade costs with a third region, the trade liberalization between the small and the large economy will cause the core–periphery effect, even if labor costs rise in the large economy.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 390 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe




 

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
China’s devaluation of yuan in 1994 was one of the major reasons causing weak export in the countries affected by the crisis.
 
2
Source: Taiwan’s Investment Commission, Ministry of Economic Affairs (MOEA).
 
3
The ratio of Taiwan’s export orders produced in China for all industries combined was 51% in 2015. Notably, the ratio of information and communication products produced in China reached 89.2% in 2015. It suggests the hollowing out of the information and communication industry in Taiwan.
 
4
If only the second condition is satisfied, small economy and the third region are endowed with similar factor endowments, and the trade between them is the North–North type or the intra-industry trade and cannot be explained by comparative advantage. If only the first condition is satisfied, that is the trade between the small and the large economy addressed in the present paper. If both conditions are not sustained, that corresponds to the trade among regions of a country, e.g., domestic trade within the USA. Under the third and fourth circumstances, free trade leads to footloose entrepreneurs moving toward the center, i.e., the larger market, as suggested by the NEG models.
 
5
The Puga and Venables (1997) analysis started from very high trade barriers among all countries, each with self-sufficient, domestically oriented production in its manufacturing sector. An initially symmetric equilibrium exists where all countries have the same number of firms. By contrast, Puga and Venables (1998) assumed an initial equilibrium in which manufacturing is concentrated in two of four countries, labeled North, and the other two countries with no industry are labeled South. The policy implications are different in three ways between this analysis and Puga and Venables’. First, unlike Puga and Venables (1997) and Puga and Venables (1998), the relationship between reductions in trade costs and agglomeration is monotonic in this model so that the reindustrialization will not occur in a small country at low enough trade costs. Second, Puga and Venables (1998) suggested a North–South preferential trade agreement (PTA) that is favorable to the liberalizing southern economy compared to the other southern economy. In this model, the favorable outcome of a North–South PTA arrangement for the liberalizing southern economy, such as Taiwan, depends on whether the trade costs across Strait are high enough, or whether Taiwan can successfully transform itself as a hub with high trade efficiency.
Third, in Puga and Venables (1998), for both southern economies, multilateral liberalization among all countries is more beneficial than the North acting as a hub, since first industrialized southern country gets a larger share of industry. However, because the size of China is extremely larger than Taiwan, the spread of industry to Taiwan will not arise under multilateral liberalization. All the differences in the effects of trade policies between this paper and Puga and Venables (1998) are mainly brought about by the assumption related to the size of the two developing countries.
 
6
For instance, in Baldwin et al. (2003)’s footloose capital model, all members in the preferential trade agreement gain from any level of preferential liberalization. However, Puga and Venables (1997) find a counter example to this result in a different model with vertical linkages among firms, which has much stronger agglomeration forces.
 
7
Commendatore et al. (2014) consider the impacts of two aspects of trade liberalization: regional integration and globalization.
 
8
That is, entrepreneurs can only migrate within the country composed of two domestic regions, while there is no factor mobility between the country and the third region.
 
9
Most inter-regional migration from Taiwan to China, mainly done by skilled works or entrepreneurs, comes along with the flow of FDI to China by the Taiwanese firms, and that will create a circular causality to produce agglomeration of manufacturing firms in a single location.
 
10
Due to the clustering of industry, the disappearing of demographic dividend, certain policies implemented by the Chinese government, such as the Employment Contract Law and the rise in minimum wage, and the appreciation of China’s yuan since 2005. China’s manufacturing wage was increased by 791% in terms of US dollars between 2000 and 2014 according to China Statistical Yearbook.
 
11
There is a US$ 50 million ceiling on any investment project to China and upper limits on accumulated amount invested in China for Taiwan’s companies ranged over 20–40% of equity according to the size of an enterprise.
 
12
The US$ 50 million ceiling on individual investment project to China had been cancelled, and the NT$ 60 million limit on accumulated investment made by person or small- and medium-sized enterprises to China had been lifted to NT $80 million. In 2002, there was an addition of over 2000 items to the existing list of legal imports from China to Taiwan, and the final list would embrace almost 5700 products. However, cross-Strait imports and exports still required to be shipped via a third territory, and domestic vessels unable to participate in shipment before 2008.
 
13
To avoid excessively economic dependence on China, Taiwan’s mainland policy guideline was adjusted to “proactive management and effective liberalization” in 2006. The Taiwanese government newly stipulated “Directions Governing Policy Review and Coordination for Major China-bound Investment Projects,” which defined major investments, the review procedures and items for major investment projects, investor coordination items, and due investor commitments. However, the enforcement period of the new policy is short and its effects can hardly be evaluated since Taiwan’s ruling party changed in 2008.
 
14
For instance, the upper limits on accumulated amount invested in China for Taiwan’s companies were lifted to 60% of equity (the former limits ranged over 20–40%). However, firms establishing headquarter or being the subsidiary of global enterprise in Taiwan can be exempted from the 60% upper limit. Direct cross-Strait flights and transportation began in December 15, 2008. Memorandum of understanding on financial regulation and supervision with China effected in January 16, 2010, mutually opened up banks of both areas to set up new branches in the other.
 
15
According to DGBAS and the World Bank, Taiwan’s average fixed capital formation as a percentage of GDP decreased by 3.5%, from 26.30% over the period 1997–2000 to 22.82% over the period 2001–2014, compared to the much smaller decrease of 1.5%, from 31.61 (over the period 1997–2000) to 30.5% (over the period 2001–2014) that occurred in South Korea over the same periods.
 
16
If firms enter and exit in response to positive and negative profits, at equilibrium manufacturing sector profits will be exhausted in both economies. There is a unique level of output that gives firms zero profit, see (6).
 
17
The profit-maximizing price for firms in the large economy is \(p_1 (1-1/\delta )=w_1^{1-\theta } {\varvec{\Omega }}_{\mathrm{m},1}^\theta b\) . The price index of the large economy and the global market is \({\varvec{\Omega }}_{\mathrm{m},1} =(n(\tau \cdot p)^{1-\delta }+n_1 p_1 ^{1-\delta })^{1/(1-\delta )}\) and \({\varvec{\Omega }}_{\mathrm{m},0} =(n(\rho _c \cdot p)^{1-\delta }+n_1 (\rho \cdot p_1 )^{1-\delta })^{1/(1-\delta )}\) , respectively.
 
18
E is the expenditure in equilibrium.
 
19
The zero-profit condition for the large economy is \(1\!=\!p_1 ^{-\delta }\!\big (\tau ^{1-\delta }{\varvec{\Omega }} _\mathrm{m}^{\delta -1} E\!+\!(\rho )^{1-\delta }{\varvec{\Omega }}_{\mathrm{m},0}^{\delta -1} E_0 \!+\!{\varvec{\Omega }}_{\mathrm{m},1}^{\delta -1} E_1 \big )\).
 
20
On the contrary, Baldwin et al. (2003, CH 14) suggest that, when the spokes maintain very high levels of protection but trade between hub and spoke is quite free, then there will be proportionally less share of world industry in hub, assuming that each nation accounts for equal share of world expenditure. However, if the differential in the trade freeness between hub–spoke and spoke–spoke is small, hub has a share of world industry larger than its share of world expenditure.
 
21
The downward shift of line \(L_{\mathrm{m},1,0} \) occurs as the manufacturing employment in the large economy shrinks due to its rising wage.
 
22
However, if the level of trade barriers between the two economies is high enough, the incentive to supply the small economy’s domestic market locally and the rising labor costs in the large economy will draw industry into the small one.
 
23
The industrial policy of Taiwan’s government mainly regulated in the Statute for Upgrading Industry before 2010 and the Statute for Industrial Innovation after 2010.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Baldwin E, Richard R, Forslid P, Martin GO, Robert-Nicoud F (2003) Economic geography and public policy. Princeton University Press, Princeton Baldwin E, Richard R, Forslid P, Martin GO, Robert-Nicoud F (2003) Economic geography and public policy. Princeton University Press, Princeton
Zurück zum Zitat Behrens K, Lamorgese AR, Ottaviano GIP, Tabuchi T (2009) Testing the ‘home market effect’ in a multi-country world: a theory-based approach. J Int Econ 79:259–265CrossRef Behrens K, Lamorgese AR, Ottaviano GIP, Tabuchi T (2009) Testing the ‘home market effect’ in a multi-country world: a theory-based approach. J Int Econ 79:259–265CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brulhart M, Crozet M, Koenig P (2004) Enlargement and the EU periphery: the impact of changing market potential. World Econ 27(6):853–875CrossRef Brulhart M, Crozet M, Koenig P (2004) Enlargement and the EU periphery: the impact of changing market potential. World Econ 27(6):853–875CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chang CL, Oxley L (2009) Industrial agglomeration, geographic innovation and total factor productivity: the case of Taiwan. Math Comput Simul 79:2787–2796CrossRef Chang CL, Oxley L (2009) Industrial agglomeration, geographic innovation and total factor productivity: the case of Taiwan. Math Comput Simul 79:2787–2796CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Commendatore P, Kubin I, Petraglia C, Sushko I (2014) Regional integration, international liberalisation and the dynamics of industrial agglomeration. J Econ Dyn Control 48:265–287CrossRef Commendatore P, Kubin I, Petraglia C, Sushko I (2014) Regional integration, international liberalisation and the dynamics of industrial agglomeration. J Econ Dyn Control 48:265–287CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Crozet M, Koenig Soubeyran P (2004) EU enlargement and the internal geography of countries. J Comp Econ 32:265–279CrossRef Crozet M, Koenig Soubeyran P (2004) EU enlargement and the internal geography of countries. J Comp Econ 32:265–279CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Forslid R (2004) Regional policy, integration and the location of industry in a multiregion framework. In: C. E. P. R. working paper, no. 4630 Forslid R (2004) Regional policy, integration and the location of industry in a multiregion framework. In: C. E. P. R. working paper, no. 4630
Zurück zum Zitat Forslid R, Ottaviano GIP (2003) An analytically solvable core-periphery model. J Econ Geogr 3(3):229–240CrossRef Forslid R, Ottaviano GIP (2003) An analytically solvable core-periphery model. J Econ Geogr 3(3):229–240CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Krugman PR, Venables AJ (1995) Globalization and the inequality of nations. Q J Econ 110(4):85780CrossRef Krugman PR, Venables AJ (1995) Globalization and the inequality of nations. Q J Econ 110(4):85780CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Krugman P, Livas Elizondo R (1996) Trade policy and the third world metropolis. J Dev Econ 49:137–150CrossRef Krugman P, Livas Elizondo R (1996) Trade policy and the third world metropolis. J Dev Econ 49:137–150CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lee Y, Chyi Y-L, Lin ES, Wu S-Y (2013) Do local industrial agglomeration and foreign direct investment to China enhance the productivity of Taiwanese firms? J Int Trade Econ Dev 22(6):839–865CrossRef Lee Y, Chyi Y-L, Lin ES, Wu S-Y (2013) Do local industrial agglomeration and foreign direct investment to China enhance the productivity of Taiwanese firms? J Int Trade Econ Dev 22(6):839–865CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Paluzie E (2001) Trade policy and regional inequalities. Pap Reg Sci 80(1):67–85CrossRef Paluzie E (2001) Trade policy and regional inequalities. Pap Reg Sci 80(1):67–85CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Puga D (1999) The rise and fall of regional inequalities. Eur Econ Rev 43:303–334CrossRef Puga D (1999) The rise and fall of regional inequalities. Eur Econ Rev 43:303–334CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Puga D, Venables A (1997) Preferential trading arrangements and industrial location. J Int Econ 43:347–368CrossRef Puga D, Venables A (1997) Preferential trading arrangements and industrial location. J Int Econ 43:347–368CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Puga D, Venables A (1998) Trading arrangements and industrial development. World Bank Econ Rev 12(2):221–249CrossRef Puga D, Venables A (1998) Trading arrangements and industrial development. World Bank Econ Rev 12(2):221–249CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ricci LA (1999) Economic geography and comparative advantage: agglomeration versus specialization. Eur Econ Rev 43:35777 Ricci LA (1999) Economic geography and comparative advantage: agglomeration versus specialization. Eur Econ Rev 43:35777
Zurück zum Zitat Suedekum J (2007) Identifying the dynamic home market effect in a three-country model. J Econ 92(3):209–228CrossRef Suedekum J (2007) Identifying the dynamic home market effect in a three-country model. J Econ 92(3):209–228CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Venables A (1996) Equilibrium locations of vertically linked industries. Int Econ Rev 37:341–359CrossRef Venables A (1996) Equilibrium locations of vertically linked industries. Int Econ Rev 37:341–359CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wang J, Zheng X-P (2013) Industrial agglomeration: asymmetry of regions and trade costs. Rev Urban Reg Dev Stud 25(2):61–78CrossRef Wang J, Zheng X-P (2013) Industrial agglomeration: asymmetry of regions and trade costs. Rev Urban Reg Dev Stud 25(2):61–78CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
A theoretical assessment on the trading arrangements for a small Asian economy with footloose entrepreneur movement toward China
verfasst von
I-Ju Tsai
Publikationsdatum
26.06.2017
Verlag
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Erschienen in
The Annals of Regional Science / Ausgabe 2/2017
Print ISSN: 0570-1864
Elektronische ISSN: 1432-0592
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s00168-017-0836-3

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 2/2017

The Annals of Regional Science 2/2017 Zur Ausgabe