Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Review of Accounting Studies 2/2018

12.04.2018

An information-based model for the differential treatment of gains and losses

verfasst von: Venky Nagar, Madhav V. Rajan, Korok Ray

Erschienen in: Review of Accounting Studies | Ausgabe 2/2018

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This study defines reporting conservatism as a higher verification standard for probable gains compared to losses and builds a model that endogenously generates optimal behavior resembling an asymmetric preference for gains versus losses. Our model considers the setting where one party produces a resource and another tries to expropriate it. The key factor determining the extent of the gain-loss asymmetry is the level of information asymmetry or trust between the two parties. The information asymmetry-based results of our model provide a simpler explanation for the vast empirical literature on conservatism, where the bulk of the economic relationships among the parties appear to be information-based with little direct relation to explicit debt contracts, a factor that has been the focus of theoretical arguments. We also suggest new empirical analyzes.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
Gigler et al. (2009, p.779) explicitly note that “we do not seek to characterize conservatism by modeling the actual measurement process ... Instead, we develop a reduced form statistical representation of conservatism.”
 
2
Kahneman (2011)’s subtler point is that it’s not just preferences that are evolutionary but also the survival games. Two firms fighting for market share may spill no blood today (at least in advanced countries), but the notions of winning/losing/gains/losses/signaling/threatening are all evolutionary in nature. And it is precisely because the human brain recognizes the evolutionary skeleton of these games that it activates the evolutionary response. Breiter et al. (2001) document how gains and losses trigger different responses in the amygdala, while Knutson et al. (2003) show that gains trigger increased neuronal activation in the mesial prefrontal cortex, while losses trigger activity in the hippocampus. In addition, Montague and Berns (2002) show that the human brain evaluates monetary and material rewards similarly, suggesting that the various asymmetries in investor attitudes toward financial gains and losses in modern stock markets appear to be emerging from an evolutionary timeframe. Chen et al. (2006)’s results lend further credence to this evolutionary survival conjecture, showing that capuchin monkeys also display various gain-loss asymmetries. Also see Williams (1966, pp.77-83).
 
3
Context-dependent preferences that do not yield traditional montonic utility functions have been extensively studied both in behavioral and mathematical economics (Chipman 1960), and this literature recognizes both the virtues and the mathematical cumbersomeness of such preferences, relative to traditional preferences that have other shortcomings but yield monotonic utility functions (Kreps 1990, Section 3.5).
 
4
In fact, there is no guarantee that preferences with such reference points can be built up into a utility function, for the existence of a utility function demands considerable mathematical regularities from the underlying preferences (Chipman 1960). Our goal however is not to build full-fledged utility functions but simply to construct endogenous preferences that we can use to compare lotteries and sure payoffs.
 
5
Note that it is essential that the joint distribution of x1, x2, y be correlated. Otherwise the conditional distribution of y given the future realization of {x1, x2} will be the marginal distribution of y itself and thus has no information content.
 
6
Our focus on the asymmetric treatment of gains versus losses is silent on the relative treatment of lotteries with smaller gains versus lotteries with larger gains, or lotteries with smaller losses versus lotteries with larger losses. If we follow Gigler et al. (2009) and exogenously posit the existence of a joint correlated distribution x1, x2, y with various statistical properties, we will have a mathematical answer for all possible ranges of x1, x2, y, but the question is if that is what the FASB’s definition of conservatism really means. In other words, the notion of conservation is not so precisely defined by the FASB or Basu (1997) so as to give an unambiguous mathematical answer for every lottery (Lambert 2010, p.294). We therefore view conservatism in the limited sense as any measurement system that imposes an asymmetrical treatment of probable gains versus probable loss. Also see footnote 4 where we argue that we build our endogenous preferences for this limited sense of conservatism.
 
8
Over time, each lottery will pay off, and the clean surplus relation means the that the lottery will be finally recorded at its liquidation value. Our bias is therefore related to the set of lotteries that have not yet paid off at any given point in time. We acknowledge that our logic may not work when the sequence of transactions is not i.i.d. More interestingly, Gigler et al. (2009, p.784) explicitly eschew the timeliness argument and state instead that Basu’s statistical regularity is amenable to more than one interpretation and use an alternative explanation to fit Basu to their model. So we are not alone in not having nailed down the timeliness argument completely.
 
9
Every loss is the counterparty expropriating money from the agent without giving anything back in return.
 
10
In additional analysis, we have also checked robustness to the ESS criterion.
 
11
Throughout the model, both in the production stage and protecting the output from the stealer stage, we assume that the probability measure and the unit of output are such that maximizing the expected value of output maximizes the probability of survival for the entity.
 
12
The assumption of decreasing marginal returns is not controversial even in biological production games; the hunter may get too tired searching for a large catch (Laundre 2014). The convex function \(C(e)\) is one way to model this phenomenon.
 
13
Note that because the stealer and the producer are assumed to be strangers, a one-period analysis will suffice, even if the game is played repeatedly among strangers in the population.
 
14
The model allows for \(\phi \) to vary by stealer. There is nothing in the model that requires \(\phi \) to be the same for all stealers.
 
15
The strength of the producer is relative to the stealer, which depends from game to game. In each game, the producer has a pure strategy over the stealer, but over many games, the observed behavior of the producer will be either to let go or to keep the output but never to share a part of it.
 
16
The use of exogenous impartial third parties to generate better outcomes has precedence in standard game theory as well; see Kreps (1990, pp.411–412). Also note that k accrues to the impartial party and is therefore not a social loss like the fight costs.
 
17
Studying how trust and reputation for impartiality are built, either through repeated games or some other mechanism, is beyond the scope of this study (Alesina and Giuliano 2015); our more modest goal is to show how such trust, when present, can alter the nature of information asymmetry and thus preferences.
 
18
When preferences fail to satisfy the necessary mathematical regularities, the utility function that emerges is a not a typical function but a complicated vector-like object (Chipman 1960).
 
19
The fact that our model generates the asymmetry as a consequence of two different games mirrors the biological evidence that gains and losses are evaluated in a different manner by the brain (Breiter et al. 2001; Knutson et al. 2003; Dickhaut et al. 2010).
 
20
Note that these preferences are valid for both producers and stealers. The preferencetoward a surer gamble is typically defined in a setting where the individual’s information setdoes not change as he chooses among gambles. But as Fig. 2notes, the stealer’s informationsets and beliefs evolve in the game. The stealer’s decision to fight when he is more certainthat the producer is Weak is not inconsistent with his overall preference for a surer gaingamble, should such a gamble be available. As Proposition5 notes, the stealer will fight whenthere is no certification, because his information set at that point is that the producer isWeak with a probability of one.
 
21
Our approach of linking verification standards to user preferences raises the issue of userpreference heterogeneity (Kothari et al. 2010, Section 2.3). Our interest isnot in the fact that different users’ reporting preferences are different. Instead, our focusis that these preferences switch their sign at zero. On average therefore one should see anasymmetry in reporting standards for probable gains versus probable losses.
 
22
Basu’s empirical measure of conservatism, which almost all the above studies employ in some form or the other, relies not just on earnings but also on prices. And prices depend on both investor preference and investor information sets. We acknowledge that the representative investor from an accounting perspective may not necessarily be the marginal investor in the firm’s stock who determines the price; see footnote 5 in Barberis (2013). Gigler et al. (2009, p.784) explicitly list Basu’s assumptions on the investor information sets.
 
23
See, for example, Henrich et al. (2001), who show that individuals’ experience with markets is correlated with greater fairness in experimental games.
 
24
Interestingly, accounting research has examined the association between social capital and several accounting variables (Jha and Chen 2015), but we are not aware of any similar empirical analysis of conservatism.
 
25
The ideas of trust and culture have a rich history in economic thought. In his 1751 Enquiry concerning the Principles of Morals, David Hume notes: “It is sufficient for our present purpose, if it be allowed, what surely, without the greatest absurdity, cannot be disputed, that there is some benevolence, however small, infused into our bosom; some spark of friendship for human kind; some particle of the dove, kneaded into our frame, along with the elements of the wolf and serpent.”
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Alesina, A., & Giuliano, P. (2015). Culture and institutions. Journal of Economic Literature, 53, 898–944.CrossRef Alesina, A., & Giuliano, P. (2015). Culture and institutions. Journal of Economic Literature, 53, 898–944.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ball, R., & Shivakumar, L. (2005). Earnings quality in uk private firms: Comparative loss recognition timeliness. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 39, 83–128.CrossRef Ball, R., & Shivakumar, L. (2005). Earnings quality in uk private firms: Comparative loss recognition timeliness. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 39, 83–128.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Barberis, N. (2013). Thirty years of prospect theory in economics: A review and assessment. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 27, 173–196.CrossRef Barberis, N. (2013). Thirty years of prospect theory in economics: A review and assessment. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 27, 173–196.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Barberis, N., & Huang, M. (2007). The loss aversion/narrow farming approach to the equity premium puzzle. In: Mehra, R., editor, Handbook of the Equity Risk Premium, Elsevier Science, pp. 199–229. Barberis, N., & Huang, M. (2007). The loss aversion/narrow farming approach to the equity premium puzzle. In: Mehra, R., editor, Handbook of the Equity Risk Premium, Elsevier Science, pp. 199–229.
Zurück zum Zitat Basu, S. (1997). The conservatism principle and the asymmetric timeliness of earnings. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 24, 3–37.CrossRef Basu, S. (1997). The conservatism principle and the asymmetric timeliness of earnings. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 24, 3–37.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Basu, S. (2009). Conservatism research: Historical development and future prospects. China Journal of Accounting Research, 2, 1–20.CrossRef Basu, S. (2009). Conservatism research: Historical development and future prospects. China Journal of Accounting Research, 2, 1–20.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Basu, S., Kirk, M., Waymire, G. (2009). Memory, transaction records, and the wealth of nations. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 34, 895–917.CrossRef Basu, S., Kirk, M., Waymire, G. (2009). Memory, transaction records, and the wealth of nations. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 34, 895–917.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bloom, N., Sadun, R., Reenen, J.V. (2012). The organization of firms across countries. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127, 1663–1705.CrossRef Bloom, N., Sadun, R., Reenen, J.V. (2012). The organization of firms across countries. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127, 1663–1705.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Breiter, H., Aharon, I., Kahneman, D., Dale, A., et al. (2001). Functional imaging of neural responses to expectancy and experience of monetary gains and losses. Neuron, 30, 619–639.CrossRef Breiter, H., Aharon, I., Kahneman, D., Dale, A., et al. (2001). Functional imaging of neural responses to expectancy and experience of monetary gains and losses. Neuron, 30, 619–639.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bushman, R., & Piotroski, J. (2006). Financial reporting incentives for conservative accounting: The influence of legal and political institutions. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 42, 107–148.CrossRef Bushman, R., & Piotroski, J. (2006). Financial reporting incentives for conservative accounting: The influence of legal and political institutions. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 42, 107–148.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Caskey, J., & Hughes, J. (2012). Assessing the impact of alternative fair value measures on the efficiency of project selection and continuation. The Accounting Review, 87, 483–512.CrossRef Caskey, J., & Hughes, J. (2012). Assessing the impact of alternative fair value measures on the efficiency of project selection and continuation. The Accounting Review, 87, 483–512.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chen, M., Lakshminaryanana, V., Santos, R. (2006). How basic are behavioral biases? evidence from capuchin monkey trading behavior. Journal of Political Economy, 114, 517–537.CrossRef Chen, M., Lakshminaryanana, V., Santos, R. (2006). How basic are behavioral biases? evidence from capuchin monkey trading behavior. Journal of Political Economy, 114, 517–537.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chen, Q., Hemmer, T., Zhang, Y. (2007). On the relation between conservatism in accounting standards and incentives for earnings management. Journal of Accounting Research, 45, 541–565.CrossRef Chen, Q., Hemmer, T., Zhang, Y. (2007). On the relation between conservatism in accounting standards and incentives for earnings management. Journal of Accounting Research, 45, 541–565.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chipman, J. (1960). The foundations of utility. Econometrica, 28, 193–224.CrossRef Chipman, J. (1960). The foundations of utility. Econometrica, 28, 193–224.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cohen, L. (2017). Discussion: Do common inherited beliefs and values influence ceo pay? Journal of Accounting and Economics, forthcoming. Cohen, L. (2017). Discussion: Do common inherited beliefs and values influence ceo pay? Journal of Accounting and Economics, forthcoming.
Zurück zum Zitat Cosmides, L., & Tooby, J. (1997). Evolutionary psychology: A primer. UCSB Psychology Department. Cosmides, L., & Tooby, J. (1997). Evolutionary psychology: A primer. UCSB Psychology Department.
Zurück zum Zitat Dellavigna, S. (2009). Psychology and economics: Evidence from the field. Journal of Economic Literature, 47, 315–372.CrossRef Dellavigna, S. (2009). Psychology and economics: Evidence from the field. Journal of Economic Literature, 47, 315–372.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dickhaut, J., Basu, S., McCabe, K., Waymire, G. (2010). Neuroaccounting: Consilience between the biologically evolved brain and culturally evolved accounting principles. Accounting Horizons, 24, 221–255.CrossRef Dickhaut, J., Basu, S., McCabe, K., Waymire, G. (2010). Neuroaccounting: Consilience between the biologically evolved brain and culturally evolved accounting principles. Accounting Horizons, 24, 221–255.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ebert, S., & Strack, P. (2015). Until the bitter end: On prospect theory in a dynamic context. The American Economic Review, 105, 1618–1633.CrossRef Ebert, S., & Strack, P. (2015). Until the bitter end: On prospect theory in a dynamic context. The American Economic Review, 105, 1618–1633.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Effron, D., & Miller, D. (2011). Reducing exposure to trust-related risks to avoid self-blame. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 37, 181–192.CrossRef Effron, D., & Miller, D. (2011). Reducing exposure to trust-related risks to avoid self-blame. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 37, 181–192.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat FASB. (2010). Statements of Financial Accounting Concepts No 8: Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting. Chapter 1, The Objective of General Purpose Financial Reporting, and Chapter 3, Qualitiative Characteristics of Useful Financial Information. Financial Accounting Standards Board, Norwalk, CT. FASB. (2010). Statements of Financial Accounting Concepts No 8: Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting. Chapter 1, The Objective of General Purpose Financial Reporting, and Chapter 3, Qualitiative Characteristics of Useful Financial Information. Financial Accounting Standards Board, Norwalk, CT.
Zurück zum Zitat Gao, P. (2013). A measurement approach to conservatism and earnings management. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 55, 251–268.CrossRef Gao, P. (2013). A measurement approach to conservatism and earnings management. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 55, 251–268.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gigler, F., Kanodia, C., Sapra, H., Venugopalan, R. (2009). Accounting conservatism and the efficiency of debt contracts. Journal of Accounting Research, 47, 767–797.CrossRef Gigler, F., Kanodia, C., Sapra, H., Venugopalan, R. (2009). Accounting conservatism and the efficiency of debt contracts. Journal of Accounting Research, 47, 767–797.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gintis, H. (2009). Game theory evolving. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Gintis, H. (2009). Game theory evolving. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Gorman, M.L., Mills, M.G., Raath, J.P., Speakman, J.R. (1998). High hunting costs make african wild dogs vulnerable to kleptoparasitism by hyaenas. Nature, 391, 479.CrossRef Gorman, M.L., Mills, M.G., Raath, J.P., Speakman, J.R. (1998). High hunting costs make african wild dogs vulnerable to kleptoparasitism by hyaenas. Nature, 391, 479.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Greif, A. (2006). The birth of impersonal exchange: The community responsibility system and impartial justice. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20, 221–236.CrossRef Greif, A. (2006). The birth of impersonal exchange: The community responsibility system and impartial justice. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20, 221–236.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Guay, W., & Verrecchia, R. (2006). Discussion of an economic framework for conservative accounting and bushman and piotroski. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 42, 149–165.CrossRef Guay, W., & Verrecchia, R. (2006). Discussion of an economic framework for conservative accounting and bushman and piotroski. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 42, 149–165.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Henrich, J., & et al. (2001). In search of homo economicus: Behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies. American Economic Review P&P, 91, 73–78.CrossRef Henrich, J., & et al. (2001). In search of homo economicus: Behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies. American Economic Review P&P, 91, 73–78.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Holthausen, R. , & Watts, R. (2001). The relevance of the value-relevance literature for financial accounting standard setting. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 31, 3–75.CrossRef Holthausen, R. , & Watts, R. (2001). The relevance of the value-relevance literature for financial accounting standard setting. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 31, 3–75.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hui, K., Klasa, S., Yeung, E. (2012). Corporate suppliers and customers and accounting conservatism. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 53, 115–135.CrossRef Hui, K., Klasa, S., Yeung, E. (2012). Corporate suppliers and customers and accounting conservatism. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 53, 115–135.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Jha, A., & Chen, Y. (2015). Audit fees and social capital. The Accounting Review, 90, 611–639.CrossRef Jha, A., & Chen, Y. (2015). Audit fees and social capital. The Accounting Review, 90, 611–639.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kahneman, D. (2011). Thinking, Fast and Slow. Farrar, Straus and Giroux. Kahneman, D. (2011). Thinking, Fast and Slow. Farrar, Straus and Giroux.
Zurück zum Zitat Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–291.CrossRef Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–291.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Khan, M., & Watts, R. (2009). Estimation and empirical properties of a firm-year measure of conservatism. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 48, 132–150.CrossRef Khan, M., & Watts, R. (2009). Estimation and empirical properties of a firm-year measure of conservatism. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 48, 132–150.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kim, Y., Li, S., Pan, C., Zuo, L. (2013). The role of accounting conservatism in the equity market: Evidence from seasoned equity offerings. The Accounting Review, 88, 1327–1356.CrossRef Kim, Y., Li, S., Pan, C., Zuo, L. (2013). The role of accounting conservatism in the equity market: Evidence from seasoned equity offerings. The Accounting Review, 88, 1327–1356.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Knutson, B., & et al. (2003). A region of mesial prefrontal cortex tracks monetarily rewarding outcomes: Characterization with rapid event-related fmri. NeuroImage, 18, 263–272.CrossRef Knutson, B., & et al. (2003). A region of mesial prefrontal cortex tracks monetarily rewarding outcomes: Characterization with rapid event-related fmri. NeuroImage, 18, 263–272.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kothari, S.P., Shu, S., Wysocki, P. (2009). Do managers withhold bad news Journal of Accounting Research, 47, 241–276.CrossRef Kothari, S.P., Shu, S., Wysocki, P. (2009). Do managers withhold bad news Journal of Accounting Research, 47, 241–276.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kothari, S., Ramanna, K., Skinner, D. (2010). Implications for gaap from an analysis of positive research in accounting. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 50, 246–286.CrossRef Kothari, S., Ramanna, K., Skinner, D. (2010). Implications for gaap from an analysis of positive research in accounting. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 50, 246–286.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kreps, D. (1990). A course in microeconomic theory. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Kreps, D. (1990). A course in microeconomic theory. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Kwon, Y., Newman, D., Suh, Y. (2001). The demand for accounting conservatism for management control. Review of Accounting Studies, 6, 29–51.CrossRef Kwon, Y., Newman, D., Suh, Y. (2001). The demand for accounting conservatism for management control. Review of Accounting Studies, 6, 29–51.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat LaFond, R., & Roychowdhury, S. (2008). Managerial ownership and accounting conservatism. Journal of Accounting Research, 46, 101–135.CrossRef LaFond, R., & Roychowdhury, S. (2008). Managerial ownership and accounting conservatism. Journal of Accounting Research, 46, 101–135.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat LaFond, R., & Watts, R. (2008). The information role of conservatism. The Accounting Review, 83, 447–478.CrossRef LaFond, R., & Watts, R. (2008). The information role of conservatism. The Accounting Review, 83, 447–478.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lambert, R. (2010). Discssion of “implications for gaap from an analysis of positive research in accounting”. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 50, 287–295.CrossRef Lambert, R. (2010). Discssion of “implications for gaap from an analysis of positive research in accounting”. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 50, 287–295.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Laundre, J. (2014). How large predators manage the cost of hunting. Science, 6205, 33–34.CrossRef Laundre, J. (2014). How large predators manage the cost of hunting. Science, 6205, 33–34.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat List, J. (2003). Does market experience eliminate market anomalies Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118, 41–71.CrossRef List, J. (2003). Does market experience eliminate market anomalies Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118, 41–71.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat List, J. (2004). Neoclassical theory versus prospect theory: Evidence from the marketplace. Econometrica, 72, 615–625.CrossRef List, J. (2004). Neoclassical theory versus prospect theory: Evidence from the marketplace. Econometrica, 72, 615–625.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Littleton, A. (1941). A genealogy for “cost or market”. The Accounting Review, 16, 161–167. Littleton, A. (1941). A genealogy for “cost or market”. The Accounting Review, 16, 161–167.
Zurück zum Zitat Lo, A. (2004). The adaptive markets hypothesis: Market efficiency from an evolutionary perspective. Journal of Portfolio Management, 30, 15–29.CrossRef Lo, A. (2004). The adaptive markets hypothesis: Market efficiency from an evolutionary perspective. Journal of Portfolio Management, 30, 15–29.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Montague, R., & Berns, G. (2002). Neural economics and the biological substrates of valuation. Neuron, 36, 265–284.CrossRef Montague, R., & Berns, G. (2002). Neural economics and the biological substrates of valuation. Neuron, 36, 265–284.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nowak, M., & Sigmund, K. (2005). Evolution of indirect reciprocity. Nature, 437, 1291–1298.CrossRef Nowak, M., & Sigmund, K. (2005). Evolution of indirect reciprocity. Nature, 437, 1291–1298.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat von Rohr, C., & et al. (2012). Impartial third-party interventions in captive chimpanzees: A reflection of community concern. PLoS ONE, 7, e32494.CrossRef von Rohr, C., & et al. (2012). Impartial third-party interventions in captive chimpanzees: A reflection of community concern. PLoS ONE, 7, e32494.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sapolsky, R. (1998). Why zebras don’t get ulcers. New York: Henry Holt & Co. Sapolsky, R. (1998). Why zebras don’t get ulcers. New York: Henry Holt & Co.
Zurück zum Zitat Scott, D., & et al. (1926). Conservatism in inventory valuations. The Accounting Review, 1, 18–30. Scott, D., & et al. (1926). Conservatism in inventory valuations. The Accounting Review, 1, 18–30.
Zurück zum Zitat Shleifer, A., & Wolfenzon, D. (2002). Investor protection and equity markets. Journal of Financial Economics, 66, 3–27.CrossRef Shleifer, A., & Wolfenzon, D. (2002). Investor protection and equity markets. Journal of Financial Economics, 66, 3–27.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Shleifer, A., LaPorta, R, de Silanes, F.L. (1998). Law and finance. Journal of Political Economy, 106, 1113–1155.CrossRef Shleifer, A., LaPorta, R, de Silanes, F.L. (1998). Law and finance. Journal of Political Economy, 106, 1113–1155.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Smith, J.M., & Price, G. (1973). The logic of animal conflict. Nature, 246, 15–18.CrossRef Smith, J.M., & Price, G. (1973). The logic of animal conflict. Nature, 246, 15–18.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Steiner, J., & Stewart, C. (2016). Perceiving prospects properly. American Economic Review, 106, 1601–1631.CrossRef Steiner, J., & Stewart, C. (2016). Perceiving prospects properly. American Economic Review, 106, 1601–1631.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Trivers, R. (1971). The evolution of reciprocal altruism. The Quarterly Review of Biology, 46, 35–57.CrossRef Trivers, R. (1971). The evolution of reciprocal altruism. The Quarterly Review of Biology, 46, 35–57.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Watts, R. (2003). Conservatism in accounting part i: Explanations and implications. Accounting Horizons, 17, 207–221.CrossRef Watts, R. (2003). Conservatism in accounting part i: Explanations and implications. Accounting Horizons, 17, 207–221.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Waymire, G. (2014). Neuroscience and ultimate causation in accounting research. The Accounting Review, 89, 2011–2019.CrossRef Waymire, G. (2014). Neuroscience and ultimate causation in accounting research. The Accounting Review, 89, 2011–2019.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Waymire, G., & Basu, S. (2008). Accounting is an evolved economic institution. Foundations and Trends in Accounting, 2, 1–174.CrossRef Waymire, G., & Basu, S. (2008). Accounting is an evolved economic institution. Foundations and Trends in Accounting, 2, 1–174.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Williams, G. (1966). Adaptation and natural selection. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Williams, G. (1966). Adaptation and natural selection. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Wilson, E. (2012). The social conquest of earth. New York: Liverlight Press. Wilson, E. (2012). The social conquest of earth. New York: Liverlight Press.
Metadaten
Titel
An information-based model for the differential treatment of gains and losses
verfasst von
Venky Nagar
Madhav V. Rajan
Korok Ray
Publikationsdatum
12.04.2018
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Review of Accounting Studies / Ausgabe 2/2018
Print ISSN: 1380-6653
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7136
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-018-9443-5

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 2/2018

Review of Accounting Studies 2/2018 Zur Ausgabe