Skip to main content

2021 | OriginalPaper | Buchkapitel

Dark Spots in Trade Theory: Early Testing Attempts

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

The beginnings of the economic theory correspond to philosophers’ attempts to explain why and how do countries trade with each other. Yet even more puzzling was the question how should countries trade? It is no surprise that despite the formidable developments of the theory in the last 200 years plus, there still are dark spots in the economics of trade. Globalization has rendered the issue even murkier. Beside the fact that international trade cannot be insulated from other economic domains, which makes it inadequate for experiments, but even testing itself is cumbersome. Only, evidence on such a complex field as international trade is by no means easy to come by.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 390 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe




 

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
“Not so Absolutely Fabulous”, The Economist, Nov. 4th, 1995; “Free exchange, Revisiting Ricardo”, Aug. 23rd, 2014
 
2
MacDougall carried out his test on the economies of the United States and Britain, based on the average productivity in 1937. Wages were two times higher in the US at the time, which, according to the comparative cost’s theory, indicated a double level of productivity for the Americans. Hence, the author considered the United States to have comparative advantage in those industries where the ration was greater than two and Britain to have comparative advantage in industries where the ratio was below two (MacDougall 1951).
 
3
To add to the survey’s rigor, the author uses the net cost, equivalent to added value plus amortization, per product unit. The conclusions relieve a somewhat surprising fact, that is: exports are tightly correlated with productivity magnitude but poorly correlated with wage rates (correlation coefficient 0.24). The correlation between exports and unit cost per product (which includes the cost of capital) turned out to be strong enough (Balassa 1989).
 
4
“Productivity advantages are not counterbalanced by higher wages paid in industries with higher productivity, and productivity differences continue to account, in a large measure, for differences in export shares…This implies that the relationship between wages and export shares is by no means uni-directional; while lower wages could conceivably lead to higher export shares, higher export shares may also make possible paying higher wages.” (Balassa 1989)
 
5
“The last question we address in this section concerns the implications of sticky money wages. For a given world money supply, downward stickiness of money wages implies the possibility of unemployment. We assume upward flexibility in wages, once full employment is attained. (…) Thus, an increase in the foreign wage rate, by moving the terms of trade against us, shifts comparative advantage and employment toward the home country” (Dornbusch et al. 1977).
 
6
Changes in the structure of comparative advantage were highlighted with the aid of the standard deviation (s.d.) of RCA indices. Small values of the s.d. indicates increased diversification of exports, whereas relatively great values show a more pronounced trend toward deeper specialization (Balassa 1977).
 
7
American economist Wassily Leontief empirically tested Heckscher-Ohlin’s factor-proportion theorem in the 1950s, using data from the US economy. Leontief hypothesized that in US’s commercial relations with other countries exports of capital-intensive goods were preponderant, while US’ imports consisted mostly labor-intensive ones. The author made use of the input-output analysis and found that US’s imports were 30% more intensive in the capital factor in comparison with exports. This peculiar result was dubbed Leontief’s paradox (Leontief 1956).
 
8
Considering the elasticity of factor substitution within an industry as constant, the Cobb-Douglas function can take the general form: F (K, L) = γ [ − + (1 − ) ]−1/, where K, L stand for the value of capital respectively labor, γ is an efficiency parameter, is an income distribution parameter, and a parameter of factor distribution elasticity. (Arrow et al. 1961)
 
9
The authors attempted to demonstrate the invalidity of this identical technologies hypothesis by discussing the role of infrastructure in the growth of efficiency and competitiveness of both industries and sectors, and whole national economies. The named study set out from an empirical observation regarding the scarcity of foreign investment in developing economies, namely that the precarity of infrastructure in these countries diminishes the return of the invested capital. It is one of the main reasons for which western companies are often reluctant to invest in these countries, despite the latter having a lower capital-labor ratio than developed countries. (Yeaple and Golub 2007) As a matter of fact, the observation belongs to another American economist, R. Lucas, who employs the paradox term to emphasize this difference. (Lucas 1990)
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Arrow, K., Chenery, H., Minhas, B., & Solow, R. (1961). Capital-Labor Substitution and Economic Efficiency. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 43(3), 225–250. Arrow, K., Chenery, H., Minhas, B., & Solow, R. (1961). Capital-Labor Substitution and Economic Efficiency. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 43(3), 225–250.
Zurück zum Zitat Balassa, B. (1963). An empirical demonstration of classical comparative cost theory. Review of Economics and Statistics, 45, 231–238.CrossRef Balassa, B. (1963). An empirical demonstration of classical comparative cost theory. Review of Economics and Statistics, 45, 231–238.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Balassa, B. (1965a). Trade liberalization and revealed comparative advantage. Manchester School, 33(2), 176–177.CrossRef Balassa, B. (1965a). Trade liberalization and revealed comparative advantage. Manchester School, 33(2), 176–177.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Balassa, B. (1965b). Trade liberalization and “revealed comparative advantage”. Manchester School, 33(2), 176–177.CrossRef Balassa, B. (1965b). Trade liberalization and “revealed comparative advantage”. Manchester School, 33(2), 176–177.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Balassa, B. (1977). “Revealed” comparative advantage revisited: An analysis of relative export shares of the industrial countries, 1953-1971. Manchester School, 45(4), 324–344.CrossRef Balassa, B. (1977). “Revealed” comparative advantage revisited: An analysis of relative export shares of the industrial countries, 1953-1971. Manchester School, 45(4), 324–344.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Balassa, B. (1989). An empirical demonstration of classical comparative advantage. In Comparative Advantage Trade Policy and Economic Development (pp. 3–16). New York: New York University Press. Balassa, B. (1989). An empirical demonstration of classical comparative advantage. In Comparative Advantage Trade Policy and Economic Development (pp. 3–16). New York: New York University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Ball, D. S. (1966). Factor-intensity reversals in international comparison of factor costs and factor use. Journal of Political Economy, 74(1), 77–80.CrossRef Ball, D. S. (1966). Factor-intensity reversals in international comparison of factor costs and factor use. Journal of Political Economy, 74(1), 77–80.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bhagwati, J. (1964). The pure theory of international trade: A survey. The Economic Journal, 74(29), 1–84.CrossRef Bhagwati, J. (1964). The pure theory of international trade: A survey. The Economic Journal, 74(29), 1–84.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dornbusch, R., Fischer, S., & Samuelson, P. A. (1977). Comparative advantage, trade, and payments in a Ricardian model with a continuum of goods. The American Economic Review, 67(5), 823–839. Dornbusch, R., Fischer, S., & Samuelson, P. A. (1977). Comparative advantage, trade, and payments in a Ricardian model with a continuum of goods. The American Economic Review, 67(5), 823–839.
Zurück zum Zitat Heller, P. S. (1976). Factor endowment change and comparative advantage: The case of Japan, 1956-1969. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 58(3), 283–292.CrossRef Heller, P. S. (1976). Factor endowment change and comparative advantage: The case of Japan, 1956-1969. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 58(3), 283–292.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Jones, R. W. (1957). Factor proportions and the Heckscher-Ohlin theorem. The Review of Economic Studies, 24(1), 5. Jones, R. W. (1957). Factor proportions and the Heckscher-Ohlin theorem. The Review of Economic Studies, 24(1), 5.
Zurück zum Zitat Kravis, I. B. (1956). Wages and foreign trade. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 38, 14–30.CrossRef Kravis, I. B. (1956). Wages and foreign trade. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 38, 14–30.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leontief, W. (1956). Factor Proportions and the Structure of American Trade: Further Theoretical and Empirical Analysis. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 38, 386–407. Leontief, W. (1956). Factor Proportions and the Structure of American Trade: Further Theoretical and Empirical Analysis. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 38, 386–407.
Zurück zum Zitat Leontief, W. W. (1969). Domestic production and foreign trade: The American capital position re-examined. In J. Bhagwati (Ed.), International trade: Selected readings (p. 94). Baltimore: Penguin. Leontief, W. W. (1969). Domestic production and foreign trade: The American capital position re-examined. In J. Bhagwati (Ed.), International trade: Selected readings (p. 94). Baltimore: Penguin.
Zurück zum Zitat Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1990). Why Doesn’t capital flow from rich to poor countries? The American Economic Review, 80(2), 92–96. Papers and Proceedings of the Hundred and Second Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association. Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1990). Why Doesn’t capital flow from rich to poor countries? The American Economic Review, 80(2), 92–96. Papers and Proceedings of the Hundred and Second Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association.
Zurück zum Zitat MacDougall, G. D. A. (1951). British and American exports: A study suggested by the theory of comparative costs. The Economic Journal, 61(244), 697–724.CrossRef MacDougall, G. D. A. (1951). British and American exports: A study suggested by the theory of comparative costs. The Economic Journal, 61(244), 697–724.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Minhas, B. S. (1962). The Homohypallagic production function, factor-intensity reversals, and the Heckscher-Ohlin theorem. Journal of Political Economy, 70(2), 138–139. 143-44.CrossRef Minhas, B. S. (1962). The Homohypallagic production function, factor-intensity reversals, and the Heckscher-Ohlin theorem. Journal of Political Economy, 70(2), 138–139. 143-44.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ohlin, B. (1957). Interregional and international trade (Vol. 39). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Studies. Ohlin, B. (1957). Interregional and international trade (Vol. 39). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Studies.
Zurück zum Zitat Ricardo, D. (1996). Principles of political economy and taxation (p. 66). New York: Prometheus Books. Ricardo, D. (1996). Principles of political economy and taxation (p. 66). New York: Prometheus Books.
Zurück zum Zitat Stern, R. (1962). British and American productivity and comparative costs in international trade. Oxford Economic Papers, 14, 275–296.CrossRef Stern, R. (1962). British and American productivity and comparative costs in international trade. Oxford Economic Papers, 14, 275–296.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Yeaple, S., & Golub, S. S. (2007). International productivity differences, infrastructure, and comparative advantage. Review of International Economics, 15(2), 223–242.CrossRef Yeaple, S., & Golub, S. S. (2007). International productivity differences, infrastructure, and comparative advantage. Review of International Economics, 15(2), 223–242.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Dark Spots in Trade Theory: Early Testing Attempts
verfasst von
Sorin Burnete
Copyright-Jahr
2021
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-50676-6_3

Premium Partner