Skip to main content

2015 | OriginalPaper | Buchkapitel

3. Enabling Knowledge

verfasst von : Nico Stehr

Erschienen in: Geographies of Knowledge and Power

Verlag: Springer Netherlands

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This chapter explores the multiple linkages between knowledge, civil society, governance, and democracy. Broader questions about relations between knowledge and freedom are placed in the context of whether these linkages are codetermined by an enabling of the knowledgeability of modern actors. Emphasis is placed on the growing opportunities for reflexive cooperation in civil society organizations, for social movements, and for an increasing influence on democratic regimes by growing segments of society. The specific aim of this chapter is more modest. Access to knowledge and the command thereof are at the core of its inquiry. Both access to knowledge and its command are stratified. Three barriers to access to knowledge are examined and questions raised about whether expertise and civil society can be reconciled, whether reconciling civil society and knowledge can be conceived of as a private good, and, finally, whether the social sciences and humanities are a source of enabling knowledge.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 390 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe




 

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
The historian James Harvey Robinson (1923, p. 76) stresses, in a treatise entitled The Humanizing of Knowledge—that is, of ensuring that the “scientific frame of mind” and specialized scientific knowledge are not an esoteric enterprise confined to a small number of members of the scientific community—that the “divisions of knowledge … form one of the most effective barriers to the cultivation of a really scientific frame of mind in thee young and thee public at large.” The solution therefore lies in “re-synthesizing” and “re-humanizing” knowledge.
 
2
Applying an economic logic to the question of the lack of knowledge among ordinary citizens with respect to policy issues or, for that matter, any issue in everyday life, Olson’s observations raise the question of the incentive of ordinary citizens to learn enough about issues that require a decision from them. If the acquisition of relevant knowledge entails costs and the consequences of their decisions or informed participation are obscure, citizens presumably have little incentive to acquire relevant knowledge—at least according to the “economic theory of democracy” proposed by Anthony Downs (1957). However, it would be shortsighted to limit the possible incentives to acquire knowledge to mere economic considerations.
 
3
Aside from the ability to enter a field of discourse, there is also the question of the desire to enter a field of discourse in an active manner. Ability and desire likely interact on a psychological level, and desire and ability do vary from person to person as well as from issue to issue (cf. Mulder, 1971).
 
4
My observations in this chapter draw on a study in which I explore the origins, formations, and sustainability of the linkages between knowledge, knowledgeability, and democracy (see Stehr, 2013). I have also relied on a paper jointly written with Jason Mast (Stehr & Mast, 2011).
 
5
Russell Hardin (2002, p. 214) argues that the answer to this question requires, first of all, what he calls a “street-level epistemology”. Unlike standard philosophical epistemology, street-level epistemology attends to what counts as knowledge among ordinary citizens, not to what justifies truth claims. For Hardin, a street-level epistemology is essentially an economic theory of knowledge since it is not about justification but about usefulness; relevant consequences that are part of such an economic theory of knowledge include all of the costs and benefits of acquiring knowledge and deploying it.
 
6
To begin with, I use the term “knowledge” as a generic term that encompasses all forms of knowledge and not only knowledge produced in the scientific community. In the context of the discussion of “enabling knowledge,” knowledge generated in science is in the forefront of the discussion, last but not least because the scientific community in highly differentiated societies is the main institution in charge of generating “additional knowledge” (including negating or destroying knowledge claims) rather than merely reproducing existing and often widely shared forms of knowledge (i.e., common knowledge). In other words, aside from other differences in the forms of knowledge in different social institutions (e.g., with respect to dissemination, accessibility, formalization), what counts in most modern social institutions, such as those of education, religion, and the economy, are the processes designed to transmit common knowledge.
 
7
Today, we are constantly engaged—whether deliberately or in response to the unintended consequences of deliberate conduct—in remaking not only our social but most significantly our natural environment. It follows that the boundaries between social and natural constructs are constantly and deliberately shifting in favor of social constructs.
 
8
For the record, Jean-Jacques Rousseau, Thomas Hobbes, and Karl Marx do not share the positive assessment of the role of (scientific) knowledge in rationalizing political action and enhancing democracy, let alone with regard to happiness or controlling human passions.
 
9
Foucault’s assertion about the affinity between the powerful and knowledge brings to mind the thesis that an increase in collective human capital, though it “raises the people’s ability to resist oppression,” also “raises the ruler’s benefits from subjugating them” (Barro, 1999, p. 159).
 
10
The justification for concern about a gap between expertise and democratic governance in the political sphere is of course based on the premise that the right to democratic governance should not be restricted and that the expert should be no more influential than the layperson. In the case of organizational governance (e.g., in industrial or governmental organizations), other norms such as employee satisfaction or productivity gains may be employed to legitimate and assess broad participation in organizational decision-making processes. In other words, is it feasible to equalize power in organizations? After reviewing a range of empirical studies of organizations, Mohr (1994, p. 55) concluded that such a goal is a utopian ambition on account of the attendant costs of power equalization.
 
11
Despite the lack of detailed scientific and technical knowledge held by the public, Collins and Evans (2007, p. 138) stress that the public’s interest and involvement in any regulation of genetically modified technologies, for example, remain unaffected; what “we should be celebrating is this political right in a democratic society, not the spurious technical abilities of the public.”
 
12
The alleged dominance of scientific knowledge in society and the respect granted to scientific knowledge to the exclusion of other forms of knowledge provoked Paul Feyerabend (2006) to ask how society can be defended against science. His answer is with the help of an education system that is more inclusive in its intellectual pursuits.
 
13
Robinson (1923, pp. 16–17) refers to a list of occupations and professions serving as mind-makers in modern society: “mind-seekers” are the questioners (of the taken-for-granted or the commonplace) and the seers. We classify them roughly as poets, religious leaders, moralists, storytellers, philosophers, theologians, artists, scientists, and inventors. But Robinson (p. 17) also raises a significant follow-up question: “What determines the success of a new idea; what establishes its currency and gives it social significance by securing its victory over ignorance and indifference or older rival and conflicting beliefs?” In this context, he stresses that the “truth of a new idea proposed for acceptance plays an altogether secondary role” (p. 20). Robinson’s question about the conditions for the success of a new idea must of course be extended to the question of why new ideas are incapable of displacing the commonplace and the taken-for-granted, or what ideas established by “social labor” exactly accomplish, and under what circumstances.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper. Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper.
Zurück zum Zitat Ezrahi, Y. (2004). Science and the political imagination in contemporary democracies. In S. Jasanoff (Ed.), States of knowledge: The co-production of science and the social order (pp. 254–273). London: Routledge. Ezrahi, Y. (2004). Science and the political imagination in contemporary democracies. In S. Jasanoff (Ed.), States of knowledge: The co-production of science and the social order (pp. 254–273). London: Routledge.
Zurück zum Zitat Feyerabend, P. (2006). How to defend society against science. In E. Selinger & R. P. Crease (Eds.), The philosophy of expertise (pp. 358–369). New York: Columbia University Press. Feyerabend, P. (2006). How to defend society against science. In E. Selinger & R. P. Crease (Eds.), The philosophy of expertise (pp. 358–369). New York: Columbia University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Foucault, M. (1972). The archaeology of knowledge. New York: Pantheon Books. Foucault, M. (1972). The archaeology of knowledge. New York: Pantheon Books.
Zurück zum Zitat Fukuyama, F. (1992). The end of history and the last man. New York: Free Press. Fukuyama, F. (1992). The end of history and the last man. New York: Free Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Gallie, W. B. (1955–1956). Essentially contested concepts. Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society New Series, 56, 167–198. Gallie, W. B. (1955–1956). Essentially contested concepts. Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society New Series, 56, 167–198.
Zurück zum Zitat Irwin, A. (1999). Science and citizenship. In E. Scanlon, E. Whitelegg, & S. Yates (Eds.), Communicating science: Contexts and channels (Reader 2, pp. 14–36). London: Routledge. Irwin, A. (1999). Science and citizenship. In E. Scanlon, E. Whitelegg, & S. Yates (Eds.), Communicating science: Contexts and channels (Reader 2, pp. 14–36). London: Routledge.
Zurück zum Zitat Jasanoff, S. (2005). Designs on nature: Science and democracy in Europe and the United States. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRef Jasanoff, S. (2005). Designs on nature: Science and democracy in Europe and the United States. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Jones, G. S. (2004). An end to poverty? A historical debate. New York: Columbia University Press. Jones, G. S. (2004). An end to poverty? A historical debate. New York: Columbia University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Leighninger, M. (2006). The next form of democracy: How expert rule is giving way to shared governance and why politics will never be the same. Nashville, TN: Vanderbilt University Press. Leighninger, M. (2006). The next form of democracy: How expert rule is giving way to shared governance and why politics will never be the same. Nashville, TN: Vanderbilt University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Mill, J. S. (1977). Democracy in America. In J. M. Robson (Ed.), The collected works of John Stuart Mill, volume XVIII – Essays on politics and society, part I. Toronto: University of Toronto Press. (Original work published 1832) Mill, J. S. (1977). Democracy in America. In J. M. Robson (Ed.), The collected works of John Stuart Mill, volume XVIII – Essays on politics and society, part I. Toronto: University of Toronto Press. (Original work published 1832)
Zurück zum Zitat Mill, J. S. (1986). The spirit of the age. Parts I–VII. In A. P. Robson & J. M. Robson (Eds.), The collected works of John Stuart Mill, volume XXII – Newspaper writings, December 1822–July 1831, part I. Toronto: University of Toronto Press. (Original work published 1831) Mill, J. S. (1986). The spirit of the age. Parts I–VII. In A. P. Robson & J. M. Robson (Eds.), The collected works of John Stuart Mill, volume XXII – Newspaper writings, December 1822–July 1831, part I. Toronto: University of Toronto Press. (Original work published 1831)
Zurück zum Zitat Mohr, L. B. (1994). Authority in organizations: On the reconciliation of democracy and expertise. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 4, 49–65. Mohr, L. B. (1994). Authority in organizations: On the reconciliation of democracy and expertise. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 4, 49–65.
Zurück zum Zitat Olson, M. (1982). The rise and decline of nations: Economic growth, stagflation, and social rigidities. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Olson, M. (1982). The rise and decline of nations: Economic growth, stagflation, and social rigidities. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Robinson, J. H. (1923). The humanizing of knowledge. New York: George H. Doran. Robinson, J. H. (1923). The humanizing of knowledge. New York: George H. Doran.
Zurück zum Zitat Schutz, A. (1946). The well-informed citizen. Social Research, 13, 463–478. Schutz, A. (1946). The well-informed citizen. Social Research, 13, 463–478.
Zurück zum Zitat Stehr, N. (1999). The future of social inequality. Society, 36, 54–59.CrossRef Stehr, N. (1999). The future of social inequality. Society, 36, 54–59.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stehr, N. (2005). Knowledge politics: Governing the consequences of science and technology. Boulder, CO: Paradigm Publishers. Stehr, N. (2005). Knowledge politics: Governing the consequences of science and technology. Boulder, CO: Paradigm Publishers.
Zurück zum Zitat Stehr, N. (2013). Die Freiheit ist eine Tochter des Wissens [Liberty is a daughter of knowledge]. Weilerswist, Germany: Velbrück Wissenschaft. Stehr, N. (2013). Die Freiheit ist eine Tochter des Wissens [Liberty is a daughter of knowledge]. Weilerswist, Germany: Velbrück Wissenschaft.
Zurück zum Zitat Wallerstein, I. (2004). The uncertainties of knowledge. Philadelphia: Temple University Press. Wallerstein, I. (2004). The uncertainties of knowledge. Philadelphia: Temple University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Wittgenstein, L. (1969). On certainty. Oxford, UK: Basil Blackwell. Wittgenstein, L. (1969). On certainty. Oxford, UK: Basil Blackwell.
Metadaten
Titel
Enabling Knowledge
verfasst von
Nico Stehr
Copyright-Jahr
2015
Verlag
Springer Netherlands
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-017-9960-7_3