Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Review of Accounting Studies 4/2015

01.12.2015

Growth in residual income, short and long term, in the OJ model

verfasst von: Cheng Lai

Erschienen in: Review of Accounting Studies | Ausgabe 4/2015

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

The paper develops the valuation implications of the Ohlson/Juettner-Nauroth (Rev Account Stud 10(2–3):349–365, 2005, OJ) model having two growth parameters in the residual income dynamic—one for the long-term (g) and one for the short-term (g h ). The central result shows that the model can be transformed into \(V_{0} = BV_{0} + (RE_{ 1} /(r - g)) \cdot Scalar,\) where Scalar = 1 + (g h  − g)/r. As a benchmark, the scalar equals one if and only if g = g h . The Ohlson (Contemp Account Res 11(2):661–687, 1995) residual income valuation (RIV) model with a single-growth parameter then holds. The OJ model thus generalizes and enriches the set of residual income growth patterns when g ≠ g h . A scalar greater than one admits residual income that (i) grows at a relatively large short-term rate fading downward to a long-term rate or (ii) declines over the long-term. A scalar less than one admits residual income that (iii) grows at a rate fading upward to a long-term rate or (iv) starts out negative and turns positive. Under these scenarios, the RIV model cannot hold in any meaningful sense, even as an approximation. The transformed OJ model also provides a unique angle in explaining market-to-book ratios as a function of profitability and short- and long-term growth, generating empirical implications beyond the constrained RIV model.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
BV is the book value of equity; x is the comprehensive earnings; and d represents dividends (Ohlson 1995).
 
2
For simplicity, the expectation operator is suppressed.
 
3
\(\mathop {\lim }\limits_{t \to \infty } (RE_{t + 1} /RE_{t} - 1) = g\quad if \, g > 0\) and \(\mathop {\lim }\limits_{t \to \infty } (RE_{t + 1} /RE_{t} - 1) = 0\quad if \, g \le 0\). The residual income growth rate geometrically reverts to the long-term rate (Penman 2005).
 
4
The assumptions of the growth patterns are indicated in the figures.
 
5
In the Scalar > 1 and g < 0 and Scalar < 1 and g > 0 groups, two growth patterns are possible. The zero residual income case (case 1 in Penman 2012) is also included for completeness. This yields a total of 12 cases.
 
6
\(\frac{{RE_{t + 1} }}{{RE_{t} }} - 1 = g\left( {1 - \frac{{(g - g_{h} )}}{{(g - g_{h} ) + g_{h} (1 + g)^{t - 1} }}} \right) \, if \, g \ne 0\) and \(\frac{{RE_{t + 1} }}{{RE_{t} }} - 1 = \frac{{g_{h} }}{{1 + (t - 1)g_{h} }} \, if \, g = 0\). When g h  = g, the item in the brackets of the first equation becomes one. In any period t, residual income grows at the rate of g, which is also the growth rate of residual income growth. Similarly, when g h and g are both zero in the second equation, residual income and residual income growth are constant over time.
 
7
When t is very large, the residual income growth under negative g would be so close to zero that it would be economically insignificant. However, the growth rate would remain constant at g.
 
8
When ∆RE 2 > 0 and g > 0, residual income growth increases exponentially without limit at the rate of g, and residual income grows by an increasing amount over time. When ∆RE 2 > 0 and g = 0, residual income growth is constant, and residual income grows by a constant amount over time. When ∆RE 2 > 0 and g < 0, residual income growth declines towards zero at the rate of g, and residual income increases by a decreasing amount over time. The reverse is true in the case of ∆RE 2 < 0. Depending on whether g is positive, zero, or negative, negative residual income growth declines exponentially, stays constant, or declines towards zero, and residual income declines by an increasing, constant, or decreasing amount over time. Formally,
if g  0, \(RE_{t + 1} = \left( {1 + ((1 + g)^{t} - 1)(g_{h} /g)} \right)RE_{1}\) and \(\, \partial RE_{t + 1} /\partial t = RE_{1} \left( {\left( {1 + g} \right)^{t} \cdot \log \left( {1 + g} \right) \cdot \left( {g_{h} /g} \right)} \right)\). If g = 0, \(RE_{t + 1} = \left( {1 + t \cdot g_{h} } \right)RE_{1}\) and \(\partial RE_{t + 1} /\partial t =\Delta RE\).
 
9
When t is very large, the (1 + g) t−1 in the denominator dominates the first formula in footnote 6, and the term in the big brackets approaches one.
 
10
Under negative g and large t, the (1 + g) t−1 in the denominator of the first formula in footnote 6 becomes negligible, and the term in the big brackets approaches zero. Accounting numbers measure residual income growth in the nominal term. If the long-term growth rate is zero, residual income is not growing in the nominal term and decreases by the rate of inflation in the real term.
 
11
Negative g h cases due to positive RE 1 and negative ∆RE 2 are ruled out because they would result in negative long-term residual income. See the first paragraph of Sect. 3.
 
12
As residual income in a particular period equals RE 1 plus accumulated residual income growth, the effect of the latter eventually dominates. With the power of compounding, firms with negative RE 1 may outgrow firms with positive RE 1 if g is high enough.
 
13
There are missing data points at the beginning of the series because the graph only depicts sensible growth rates with a positive denominator.
 
14
One sensible growth rate is the long-term rate of inflation or GDP growth, capturing the notion that accounting value added is growing in the nominal term but maintained over time in real terms. A growth rate greater than the inflation rate implies residual income is growing in real terms.
 
15
These scenarios are ruled out in the previous analysis. See the first paragraph of Sect. 3.
 
16
A sufficiently positive ∆RE 2 (the numerator of g h ) would result in a highly negative g h .
 
17
If ROE > r, the −(r  g)*[ROE 1 /(ROE 1 –r)] < g h  < −(r − g) condition ensures that 0 < MTB < 1.
 
18
The reverse is true when ROE < r, and the linear relation turns negative and is less negative with a higher ROE, a lower r, or both.
 
19
Page 29 of Ohlson and Gao (2006) makes similar points.
 
20
Under the clean surplus relation, ∆RE is the same as abnormal earnings growth in the OJ model but on a total dollar rather than per share basis.
 
21
The clean surplus relation admits the role of accounting in valuation, addressing a problem in the OJ model where the EPS is primitive and arbitrarily chosen (Penman 2005). The book value and residual income in model (2) are both unambiguously relevant. As clean surplus accounting holds for both biased and neutral accounting principles, expressions (2) and (3) are versatile to any accounting policy.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Easton, P. D. (2004). PE ratios, PEG ratios, and estimating the implied expected rate of return on equity capital. The Accounting Review, 79(1), 73–95.CrossRef Easton, P. D. (2004). PE ratios, PEG ratios, and estimating the implied expected rate of return on equity capital. The Accounting Review, 79(1), 73–95.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Easton, P. (2009). Estimating the cost of capital implied by market prices and accounting data. Boston and Delft: Now Publishers Inc. Easton, P. (2009). Estimating the cost of capital implied by market prices and accounting data. Boston and Delft: Now Publishers Inc.
Zurück zum Zitat Feltham, G. A., & Ohlson, J. A. (1995). Valuation and clean surplus accounting for operating and financial activities. Contemporary Accounting Research, 11(2), 689–731.CrossRef Feltham, G. A., & Ohlson, J. A. (1995). Valuation and clean surplus accounting for operating and financial activities. Contemporary Accounting Research, 11(2), 689–731.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Feltham, G. A., & Ohlson, J. A. (1996). Uncertainty resolution and the theory of depreciation measurement. Journal of Accounting Research, 34(2), 209–234.CrossRef Feltham, G. A., & Ohlson, J. A. (1996). Uncertainty resolution and the theory of depreciation measurement. Journal of Accounting Research, 34(2), 209–234.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Jorgensen, B. N., Lee, Y. G., & Yoo, Y. K. (2011). The valuation accuracy of equity value estimates inferred from conventional empirical implementations of the abnormal earnings growth model: US evidence. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 38(3–4), 446–471.CrossRef Jorgensen, B. N., Lee, Y. G., & Yoo, Y. K. (2011). The valuation accuracy of equity value estimates inferred from conventional empirical implementations of the abnormal earnings growth model: US evidence. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 38(3–4), 446–471.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nissim, D., & Penman, S. H. (2001). Ratio analysis and equity valuation: From research to practice. Review of Accounting Studies, 6(1), 109–154.CrossRef Nissim, D., & Penman, S. H. (2001). Ratio analysis and equity valuation: From research to practice. Review of Accounting Studies, 6(1), 109–154.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ohlson, J. A. (1995). Earnings, book values, and dividends in equity valuation. Contemporary Accounting Research, 11(2), 661–687.CrossRef Ohlson, J. A. (1995). Earnings, book values, and dividends in equity valuation. Contemporary Accounting Research, 11(2), 661–687.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ohlson, J. A. (2005). On accounting-based valuation formulae. Review of Accounting Studies, 10(2–3), 323–347.CrossRef Ohlson, J. A. (2005). On accounting-based valuation formulae. Review of Accounting Studies, 10(2–3), 323–347.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ohlson, J. A., & Gao, Z. (2006). Earnings, earnings growth and value. Boston and Delft: Now Publishers Inc.MATH Ohlson, J. A., & Gao, Z. (2006). Earnings, earnings growth and value. Boston and Delft: Now Publishers Inc.MATH
Zurück zum Zitat Ohlson, J. A., & Juettner-Nauroth, B. E. (2005). Expected EPS and EPS growth as determinants of value. Review of Accounting Studies, 10(2–3), 349–365.CrossRef Ohlson, J. A., & Juettner-Nauroth, B. E. (2005). Expected EPS and EPS growth as determinants of value. Review of Accounting Studies, 10(2–3), 349–365.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Palepu, K. G., & Healy, P. M. (2012). Business analysis and valuation: Using financial statements, text and cases (5th ed.). Boston: Cengage Learning. Palepu, K. G., & Healy, P. M. (2012). Business analysis and valuation: Using financial statements, text and cases (5th ed.). Boston: Cengage Learning.
Zurück zum Zitat Penman, S. (2005). Discussion of “on accounting-based valuation formulae” and “expected EPS and EPS growth as determinants of value”. Review of Accounting Studies, 10(2–3), 367–378.CrossRef Penman, S. (2005). Discussion of “on accounting-based valuation formulae” and “expected EPS and EPS growth as determinants of value”. Review of Accounting Studies, 10(2–3), 367–378.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Penman, S. (2012). Financial statement analysis and security valuation (5th ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill/Irwin. Penman, S. (2012). Financial statement analysis and security valuation (5th ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Zurück zum Zitat Zhang, X.-J. (2000). Conservative accounting and equity valuation. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 29(1), 125–149.CrossRef Zhang, X.-J. (2000). Conservative accounting and equity valuation. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 29(1), 125–149.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Growth in residual income, short and long term, in the OJ model
verfasst von
Cheng Lai
Publikationsdatum
01.12.2015
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Review of Accounting Studies / Ausgabe 4/2015
Print ISSN: 1380-6653
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7136
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-015-9320-4

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 4/2015

Review of Accounting Studies 4/2015 Zur Ausgabe