Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Applied Network Science 1/2022

Open Access 01.12.2022 | Research

Identifying key sectors in the regional economy: a network analysis approach using input–output data

verfasst von: Fernando DePaolis, Phil Murphy, M. Clara De Paolis Kaluza

Erschienen in: Applied Network Science | Ausgabe 1/2022

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

By applying network analysis techniques to large input–output system, we identify key sectors in the local/regional economy. We overcome the limitations of traditional measures of centrality by using random-walk based measures, as an extension of Blöchl et al. (Phys Rev E 83(4):046127, 2011). These are more appropriate to analyze very dense networks, i.e. those in which most nodes are connected to all other nodes. These measures also allow for the presence of recursive ties (loops), since these are common in economic systems (depending to the level of aggregation, most firms buy from and sell to other firms in the same industrial sector). The centrality measures we present are well suited for capturing sectoral effects missing from the usual output and employment multipliers. We also develop and make available an R implementation for computing the newly developed measures.
Hinweise

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Introduction

Wassily Leontief won the Nobel prize in economics in 1973 for developing the Input-Output [I–O] modeling system, in the years before and during WWII. The original purpose of the I–O approach was to identify flows among economic sectors of a region or a country. Those flows represent the exchanges that take place among sectors. In market economies, this functions as a fair representation of sectors buying from and selling to one another. Over time it was clear that the identification of key sectors in the economy was emerging as a new and exciting application as shown in the early contributions of Rasmussen (1956), Laumas (1975), Schultz (1977) and Hewings (1982). In those early times, the implication was that any industrial policy intended to protect or stimulate specific sectors would start with the proper identification of their importance to the system. Today this application still remains relevant, even though I–O systems themselves have been superseded by more sophisticated and complex economic modeling approaches, such as general equilibrium (Jorgenson 2016). Local and regional policy makers and planners can certainly refer to the sectors thus identified to allocate infrastructure funds, grant tax exemptions, employment support programs, and implement other policy actions geared toward strengthening the economic system and ensuring its resilience.
The identification of the most relevant sectors is not, however, an easy task. Is the most important sector the one that produces the highest output? or the one with the highest employment? or the one that buys the most from local suppliers? It is quite obvious that the choice of measurement will greatly affect the results; different sectors are “key” under different assumptions, and for different purposes.
The I–O approach provides a rather straight forward process to describing local economies. This was discovered very early by economic geographers, planners and others who began using it to, first, describe, and later analyze the relationships among local sectors and the emergence or presence of clusters or other groupings that were meaningful in the performance of the local/regional economy as a system (Hubbell 1965; Streit 1969; Roepke et al. 1974 and Campbell 1975).
In recent years, there has a been a growing interest in revisiting those early attempts, but this time with the aid of network analysis techniques. For the most part those efforts have focused on national economies, either at the country level (Giuliani 2013), the regional block level (Guo and Planting 2000; García Muñiz et al. 2008; Montresor and Marzetti 2009; Aroche Reyes and Marquez Mendoza 2012; García Muñiz 2013) or at the global scale (Blöchl et al. 2011). On the other hand, there are relatively few examples of this type of analysis at the sub-national level.
Therefore, there remains a clear and strong motivation to find alternative ways for the identification of key sectors in the local and regional economy, or at the very least the systematic analysis of the connections among sectors (Reid et al. 2008). One such approach is social network analysis (SNA). Though the roots of SNA, as a field, stretch back to the 1930s with Jacob Moreno’s sociometry (Moreno 1934), the field experienced its greatest initial growth and expansion beginning with advances in computing power and ubiquity in the 1970s (Freeman 2004). Although the vast majority of early efforts in SNA applied to networks that are interpersonal and social in nature, the field has since bloomed and has become well-developed, with extensions into a variety of disciplines, such as biology, genetics, physics, and economics. At the core of the network analysis approach is a set of measures that provide a variety of conceptualizations of how one may operationalize the concept of relative prominence of each of the nodes that constitute the network. At its simplest, prominence may be measured as a function of the frequency in which a node is connected to others. Somewhat more nuanced conceptualizations of such measures, however, will consider the structure of the pathways that the ties create and relative distances between nodes in the network when traveling such paths. Frequency, path, and distance considerations have been incorporated into dozens of centrality measures (degree, closeness, betweenness, eigenvector, reach, and flow, just to mention some of the most commonly used measures). The concept of prominence within a network, as operationalized through centrality measures, remains fairly fluid and context-dependent. Even the earliest treatments on the topic, Freeman (1978) asserted that there was no unanimity on what centrality is or on the proper method(s) for its measurement. Despite attempts to evaluate and prioritize various centrality measures (e.g., Harrison et al. 2016; Meng et al. 2017), context and interpretability remain the most valid determinants of their selection and application.
As we see it, we contribute to the advancement of the field by setting multiple objectives. First, we want to consolidate definitions and interpretations from existing frameworks. As it is common with methods that extend into other fields, multiple terms are used to refer to the same concept, and vice-versa. We are not aware of similar efforts. Second, we test whether the newly developed network metrics are applicable to I–O systems at the subnational level (state, and even municipal). This is not a technical issue, but one of interpretation. As we show, the same metrics have different values at the national, state and local level, hinting at the different role that specific industrial sectors play at different level of geographic aggregation. We have not identified other contributions in the literature that analyze subnational geographies in similar fashion. Finally, we implement all the metrics discussed in the paper in R. The code is publicly available and—with relatively little pre-processing—a user can compute all metrics for any network.1

Theoretical considerations

As discussed above, I–O systems can be represented by networks in which the nodes (also referred to as vertices) are economic sectors or industries, and the links connecting them (also conceptialized as ties) represent the flows among those industries. More precisely, I–O systems are very dense, valued, directed networks. In a network, density refers to the proportion of links that actually exist as a share of all possible links. I–O networks are very dense because–especially at high levels of aggregation–most, if not all, nodes (industries) will be connected to almost all other nodes.That is, network density (d) approaches 1 (in symbols, \(d\rightarrow \>\)1).2 They are valued networks because the links do not only represent the presence of a connection, but such a connection has a specific magnitude. Finally, they are also directed networks because I–O systems represent bi-directional flows between economic sectors. That is, each pair of nodes is connected by two links, one for each of the directions in which transactions may take place, typically with differing values. At greater levels of sectoral disaggregation, a more granular classification captures narrower and narrower definitions of industries and commodities. This results in more differentiation in the flows between sectors, with one direction potentially overshadowing the other by orders of magnitude (Lovász 2009; Miller and Blair 2009). Ties with similar values in both directions are extremely rare in I–O systems.
If the objective is to determine how important a sector is in the economic network, one may consider using vertex centrality measures such as those introduced by Freeman (Freeman 1977, 1978; Freeman et al. 1991). Common vertex centrality measures are of ambiguous applicability in the case of I–O networks. The difficulties associated with applying such vertex centrality measures to I–O systems become apparent when considering some common features that describe such networks. Of particular relevance are the values of the ties between vertices, loops representing recursive trade within an industry, and the overall density of I–O networks.3
The simplest of the measures Freeman defined, degree, is calculated as the number of ties that are incident upon a node.4 As such, the degree of a node describes how often each industry participates in the production function of others, and which sectors are part of its own production function. Given the high density found in I–O networks, however, the number of links that are incident upon any given node is not likely to vary greatly throughout the network, making degree a relatively poor measure of a given industry’s relative prominence in a local economy.5 In addition, because degree measures only direct access to others, it fails to capture the larger systemic effects that are distributed throughout the wider network.
Path-based measures were introduced to take into account a node’s place within the larger network. Two measures that were introduced to take the entire network into account were closeness and betweenness Freeman (1978). Closeness provides a measure of the inverse distance between a node and all other nodes reachable from it. More specifically, closeness centrality for a given node i is calculated as
$$\begin{aligned} C_i^{CLO}=\left[ {{\sum _{j=1}^n}d_{(i,j)}}\right] ^{-1} \end{aligned}$$
(1)
where \(d_{ij}\) is the distance of the shortest path (i.e., geodesic distance, or, simply, geodesic) between node i and any other node j. In this manner, closeness provides a measure of a node’s strategic positioning within an network in terms of the speed or efficiency with which the flows within a network will pass through a particular node. Larger measures of closeness may, for example, indicate a node that will be able to access information or materials more frequently or quickly than others with lower values.
Another means of conceptualizing prominence of a node in terms of flows through a network is betweenness, which measures a node’s potential for being able to capture, enable, or impede the passage of informaiton or materials in a network. As such, it is calculated as
$$\begin{aligned} C_i^{BET}=\frac{g_{jk}(i)}{g_{jk}} \end{aligned}$$
(2)
where \(g_{jk}\) is the number of shortest paths (i.e., geodesics) between node j and node k, and \(g_{jk}(i)\) is the number of those paths that include i. In this manner, betweenness measures the degree to which a particular node i commands strategic junctures within the network.
A major weakness of both betweenness and closeness, as they are commonly used, is that neither measure was conceived to take the value of the ties into account. For I–O networks, this is a major shortcoming, as the actual magnitudes of intersectoral flows are a critical consideration. A solution has been proposed by Dijkstra (1959), Brandes (2001) and Newman (2001) and further modified by Opsahl et al. (2010) to seek the path with the least cumulative impedance, as opposed to the one with the fewest steps. The idea that drives this modification is that ties with lower values transmit less, and may be considered to impede flow more than ties with greater tie values. The resulting implementation is a weighted distance measure given by
$$\begin{aligned} d^{w\alpha }_{(i,j)}=min\left( \frac{1}{(w_{ih})^\alpha }+\cdots +\frac{1}{(w_{hj})^\alpha }\right) \end{aligned}$$
(3)
where the inverse of the tie values (i.e., weights) \(w_{ij}\) is summed for each of the paths between node i and node j, and the path of least resistance (i.e., the one with the lowest value) is selected. The \(\alpha\) coefficient functions as a tuning parameter that is used to either emphasize or deemphasize whether the number of steps should be taken into account. Setting \(\alpha =0\) produces the same measure as if the ties were of binary values; setting \(\alpha =1\) sums the inverse tie values; setting \(0<\alpha <1\) favors fewer steps; and setting \(\alpha >1\) favors stronger tie weights in calculating shortest path distances.
Opsahl et al. (2010) employed the weighted geodesic measure shown in (3) in both closeness (4) and betweenness (5) in a manner that is fairly straightforward.
$$\begin{aligned} C_i^{WCLO}= & {} \left[ {{\sum _{j=1}^n}d^{w\alpha }_{(i,j)}}\right] ^{-1} \end{aligned}$$
(4)
$$\begin{aligned} C_i^{WBET}= & {} \frac{g_{jk}^{w\alpha }(i)}{g^{w\alpha }_{jk}} \end{aligned}$$
(5)
In each case, the weighted geodesic (i.e., shortest path) distance measure has been substituted for the binary form. In the case of weighted closeness, depending on the \(\alpha\) setting, the relative distance in terms of summed inverse tie values is substituted for a count of the number of steps in each path when selecting the lowest value. For, weighted betweenness, on the other hand, \({g^{w\alpha }_{jk}}\) is a count of the number of geodesics occurring between node j and node k (Opsahl 2015).
Weighted path-based centrality measures hold the potential to reveal the relative prominence of nodes in a valued network. Each is well suited for use with valued networks, though there are some shortcomings for each that should be noted in regard to their potential for application in I–O networks. The characteristics of I–O networks that make them a challenge for both standard and weighted network metrics include the values of ties in I–O networks, the recursive loops present in aggregated networks, and their density merit consideration in modeling the flow of resources.
If one considers the weighted distance equation given in Eq. (3) to modify closeness (4) and betweenness (5), it should quickly become apparent that such a weighting metric will function in a manner similar to the measures designed for dichotomous ties (Eqs. (1) and (2)) only when the tie values are limited to a relatively narrow range of integer values. Given that I–O networks are expected to take a theoretically unlimited range of positive continuous values, it becomes increasingly likely that the measure will produce one unique shortest path for any given node pair. Such a solution would emphasize the prominence of nodes that are situated in some of the most proiminent production sectors in the region being evaluated. Although prominence within key sectors will produce useful information, the lack of alternate shortest paths between nodes holds the potential to mask the relative importance of other nodes that may hold secondary importance–something that is also important from a planning and disaster mitigation standpoint. The ability to tune the measure using the \(\alpha\) setting helps to reduce this tendency, but also requires a more standardized approach to tuning that has not yet been evaluated in I–O networks at this point.
An additional challenge to the anlaysis of I–O networks occurs when considering the recursive loops that are used to best model flows within a system that has been aggregated to create a set of nodes that would normally trade amongst themselves into a metanode that represents an entire industrial sector. Depending on the level of aggregation, the presence of loops within I–O networks can be substantial. However, both the classic binary and the weighted assessments of shortest paths through a network will logically always ignore such loops, as they would not normally constitute a “shorter” path through the network. This is not a realistic representation of the actual behavior of flows within an I–O network.
The final consideration that should be important to those modeling I–O networks is the high density of ties within the network. Using path-based measures that treat ties as binary tends to make it look as though all nodes are relatively “close” to one another since, on average, the paths throughout exceptionally dense networks will be of roughly the same length. This tendency is somewhat reduced by using weighted ties. When employing weighted measures, both closeness and betweenness will produce measures of prominence that are relative to the total network. They do not provide any special consideration for the more immediate neighborhood (e.g., manufacturing sector) around each node.
One way of avoiding most of those limitations is adopting measures of centrality based on random walks. Newman (2005) explored and further developed the notion of a measure of centrality based on random walks to overcome the need for a pre-determined, known flow from each source (s) to each target (t), and stated that “the random-walk betweenness of a vertex i is equal to the number of times that a random walk starting at s and ending at t passes through i along the way, averaged over all s and t.”
Experts in I–O modeling, not yet familiar with network metrics, perceive the notion of random walk as one that does not correctly represent the relationships in the economic system. Their complaints are not without merit because, after all, industrial sectors do not consume a random collection of inputs in the hopes of producing a very specific output. Those input are indeed very well defined by a sector’s production function. In the same vein, one could conceptualize random walks as representing a way of exhausting all possible combinations of inputs that produce all outputs in the economy. Because the computation of any random walk-based measure involves the “value” of the flow between two given sectors, only the ties that are present will influence the magnitude of the metric. Therefore, all random walked-based measures of an I–O system will reflect the true underlying production functions that link those sectors.
Network metrics that use random walks could identify those sectors that participate in all other sectors’ production functions more often and with a greater insidence. This is one of the most significant differences between simple measures of centrality (which would identify the “presence” of the tie, in an on–off fashion) and random walk-based measures of centrality, which also include an apt representation of the intensity of the tie.

Methods

Following Friedkin (1991) we present a means of measuring immediate effects and mediative effects, in addition to the already defined total effects. Lee (2006) provides a more extended discussion about the equivalency between total, immediate and mediative effects and eigenvector, closeness and betweenness centrality, respectively. In this section we discuss approaches that provide a better definition of mediative and immediate effects within a network, as presented in García Muñiz et al. (2008) and Blöchl et al. (2011). Table 1 presents our own attempt to establish the equivalence between the measures proposed by each author.
Table 1
Equivalency of measurements
García Muñiz et al. (2008)
Blöchl et al. (2011)
Immediate effects
Random walk centrality (analogous to closeness centrality)
Mediative effects
Counting betweenness (analogous to betweenness centrality)
What follows is a discussion of two alternative conceptualizations and corresponding definitions for closeness and betweenness centrality. In each case, these metrics provide a measurement that more closely mimics flows within I–O networks than the more widely shared (Freeman 1978) versions. We have elected to implement the definitions set by Blöchl et al. (2011). The metrics proposed in García Muñiz et al. (2008) are the inverse of those considered in Blöchl et al. (2011). This does not alter the outcome in terms of–for instance–sectoral rankings because the information transmitted by those metrics is equivalent.
One question remains. Is it appropriate to add the immediate and mediative effects to obtain a sort of total effects? Friedkin (1991) refers to total effects in the context of social networks but we have not found any work in which such definition is applied to I–O networks. Our cursory examination shows that immediate and mediative effects could show opposite directions, producing ambiguous interpretation of total effects. This is perhaps a computational confirmation of our intuition, which is that immediate and mediative effects correspond to two substantially different processes, and their combination is–at least–questionable. This is certainly an area for further investigation.

Random walk centrality for immediate effects

Sectors that have effects transmitted over long sequences of economic relations have lower economic impacts than those sectors that have a large number of direct linkages. The measure immediate effects is the reciprocal of the mean length of the sequences of relations from the \(\hbox {j}{th}\) sector to all others.
Consider a weighted network, either directed or undirected, with n nodes denoted by j = 1,..., n; and a random walk process on this network with a transition matrix M.6 The \(\hbox {m}_{jk}\) element of M describes the probability of the random walker that has reached node i, proceeds directly to node j. These probabilities are defined by Eq. (6).
$$\begin{aligned} M_{ij} = \frac{a_{ij}}{ \sum \nolimits _{j=1}^{n}a_{ij}} \end{aligned}$$
(6)
where \(\hbox {a}_{ij}\) is the (i, j)th element of the weighting matrix A of the network. When there is no tie between two nodes, the corresponding element of the A matrix is zero. In the case of I–O system as we implement it, A is a matrix of regional absorption coefficients. Equation (7) shows the random walk closeness centrality of a node i as a function of the inverse of the average mean first passage time to that node.
$$\begin{aligned} C_{i}^{RWC} = \frac{n}{ \sum\nolimits _{j=1}^{n}H_{ij}} \end{aligned}$$
(7)
The mean first passage time (MFPT) from node i to node j is the expected number of steps it takes for the process to reach node j from node i for the first time (Eq. (8)). Random walk centrality is the inverse of MFPT to a given sector. MFPT is the starting point in the computation of a random walk-based measure. Noh and Rieger (2004) define it as the expected number of steps a random walker who starts at source i needs to reach target j for the first time, \(H_{ij}\).
$$\begin{aligned} H_{ij}= \sum _{j=1}^{\infty }rP_{ijr} \end{aligned}$$
(8)
where \(P_{ijr}\) denotes the probability that it takes exactly r steps to reach j from i for the first time. To calculate these probabilities of reaching a node for the first time in r steps, it is useful to regard the target node as an absorbing one, and introduce a transformation of M (in Eq. (6) by deleting its \(\hbox {j}{th}\) row and column and denoting it by \(M_{-j}\).
As the probability of a process starting at i and being in k after r-1 steps is simply given by the (ik)th element of \(M_{-j}^{r-1}\), P(ijr) can be expressed as:
$$\begin{aligned} P_{ijr}= \sum _{k\ne {j}}((M_{-j}^{r-1}))_{ik}m_{kj} \end{aligned}$$
(9)
where \(\hbox {m}_{jk}\) is a column of M with the element \(\hbox {m}_{kk}\) deleted. Substituting Eq. (9) into equation(8), and vectorizing for computational convenience yields:
$$\begin{aligned} H(\bullet ,j)=(I-M_{-j})^{-1}e \end{aligned}$$
(10)
where H(\(\bullet\),j) is the vector of first passage times for a walk ending at node j, e is an n-1 dimensional vector of ones and I is the identity matrix. The result is then used in Eq. (7). The calculation of random walk betweenness centrality is very computationally intensive; for that reason we conducted most of our calculation at the 86-sector level of aggregation7 rather at the 536-sector aggregation8, which proved to be excessively challenging.

Counting betweenness for mediative effects

Mediative effects capture the prominence of sectors as instruments of transmission of total effects. The assumption is that it measures the involvement of a sector in the paths connecting other sectors, as if they were intermediaries in the transactions among other sectors. The more paths a sector participates in, the more its relevance as a connector or conduit in the overall economy. Counting Betweenness generalizes Newman’s random walk for directed networks with loops. It measures how often a sector (a node in the network) is visited on first-passage walks, averaged over all source-target pairs, \(\hbox {N}_{ij}^{st}\), and it is shown in Eq. (11).
$$\begin{aligned} C_i^{CB} = \frac{\sum^{n} _{j=1} \sum^{n} _{k \ne j} N^{jk}(i)}{n(n-1)} \end{aligned}$$
(11)
where \(N^{jk}(i)\) is a measure of the frequency with which a random walker reaches node i while going from j to k.9

Data and application to two cases

In the U.S., the commercial product \(\hbox {IMPLAN}^{{\textregistered} }\) is regarded as an industry standard in terms of its widespread use as a tool for regional economic analysis. IMPLAN captures the inter-sector relationships with the parameter “gross absorption,” which is the total amount of each commodity that is needed for production in one sector.10 We decided to use “regional absorption,” which is the amount of the required inputs (gross absorption) purchased locally.11 This, we think, captures the relationships at the local level better than gross absorption, and is a better starting point in the identification of key sectors in the local economy. A sector’s relative importance in the local economy increases as it uses more locally sourced inputs.
  • Gross Absorption describes the total amount of each commodity that is needed in the production of a sector’s output.
  • Regional Absorption describes the amount of the required inputs that can be obtained locally (the total amount of production requirements that can be sourced within the model’s geography).
We developed two different settings for the application of our algorithms. In the first case, we examine the economic structure of Monterey County, California. Here we show the differences between the more commonly used multipliers (total output and employment multipliers) and the centrality measures defined above. For the second application, we compare a metro area (Wayne County, Michigan, where the Detroit metropolitan region is located), a state (Michigan), and the whole country (United States). In this case, we show how the same centrality measures vary with the geographic scale and offer some interpretations.
At the time of the analysis, the IMPLAN system provided data at the local level, counties or zipcodes, using a 536-sector aggregation schema. Sectoral aggregations at 2- and 3-digit NAICS were also available. We produced datasets at all three levels: 2-digit NAICS (20 sectors); 3-digit NAICS (86 sectors); and native IMPLAN format (536 sectors). At the 86-sector level, the base matrix is a grid which cells are 86 by 86 matrices, that is, its full dimension is 7396 by 7396, or almost 55 million cells; at the 536-sector level, the full dimension is over 82 billion cells. These values are a measure of the computational demands under each aggregation schema.12 The results presented below correspond to the 86-sector, 3-digit NAICS structure because we think that is the best sectoral map for this application. There are enough sectors to distinguish between sub-activities that would be masked under the 20-sector schema, but not so many sectors that would result in the processing of huge matrices. The 3-digit NAICS aggregation has the additional advantage of providing a realistic description of almost any local or regional economy, with relatively very few missing sectors.

Results and interpretation

When applying our algorithm to the datasets in Blöchl et al. (2011), we replicated their results for a variety of countries. Although, they do not report the actual values of their metrics, we are confident our algorithm performs as expected because the high concordance between the rankings they report and our own computations. The R code is available on RPubs.13
For Monterey County, “Appendix 1” shows both sets of results, that is the traditional multipliers and the network metrics developed in our research. It shows the top-10 sectors, ranked by each of the measures (Output multiplier, Employment multiplier, Random Walk Centrality and Counting Betweenness). “Appendix 2” shows the ranking of all 86 sectors for the same four measures.
For the metropolitan area of Detroit, the state of Michigan, and the United States, “Appendix 3”, “Appendix 4” and “Appendix 5” show the top ten sectors for Random Walk Centrality and Counting Betweenness, and the complete ranks in all three measures for all 86 sectors, respectively.
Both measures, Random Walk Centrality (RWC) and Counting Betweenness (CBET), are dynamic in nature as they capture the impacts on each sector as effects propagate throughout the local economy.14 Random walk centrality measures to what extent a sector will be impacted earlier or later during the shock transmission process. Counting betweenness is a measure of impedance in the flow of a shock. A shock will reach a sector with a higher RWC before a sector with lower value of RWC. A shock will transit faster–or will reach more sectors from–an industry with a larger value of CBET. The commonly used output and employment multipliers cannot capture these dynamic effects. In fact, if the objective is to identify systemic weakness in the local economy, the multipliers could be misleading. Compared to a game of falling dominoes, the multipliers would be equivalent to the size of a single domino, while RWC and CBET would show how fast and in which direction the flow of falling dominoes will move, once the initial wave is set in motion (i.e. a shock).15
In the case of Monterey County, the sectors at the top of the RWC and CBET rankings are quite different from those for the output and employment multipliers. Professional and Scientific Services and Management of Companies are first and second for RWC and first and eight for CBET, while they are 32nd and 12th, and 41st and 50th for output and employment multipliers, respectively. One interpretation is that RWC and CBET for those sectors show that, although their output and employment levels are not very high, they do participate in many (or most) other sectors’ production functions. This is one way of assigning preeminence to a sector in the context of the local economy.
When comparing the results for the Detroit metro region, the state of Michigan and the United States, the rankings of RWC and CBET show some interesting effects. For example, sector #9, Utilities, has RWC ranking values 8, 10 and 13 respectively for each geography. That would imply that at the smaller geography (Detroit metro), the “Utilities” sector plays a more important role than in the larger geographies (although it is quite important in all of them). The rankings in CBET show a similar effect. Conversely, for sector #20, Chemical Manufacturing, the effects seem to be opposite. The ranking is much lower for the Detroit metro area (70) than for the state and the nation (37 and 12, respectively). This means one of two things: (1) There is some production for the sector in the Detroit metro region but its output is consumed mostly outside the region, and therefore its local effect is lower; or (2) There is some local production but other local sectors utilize inputs from outside the region (this could be the result of the sectoral aggregation being too coarse to capture sub-sector effects). On the other end of the geographic scale, at the national level the Chemical Manufacturing sector provides inputs to all local production. That becomes meaningless when considering that “local” in this case refers to the whole of the United States.
The reader can derive similar inferences for all other sectors shown in “Appendix 5”. Regardless of the remaining ambiguity, the interpretation confirms that both RWC and CBET measures performed as expected in identifying those sectors that are more relevant as contributors of locally sourced production. This attribute is not directly captured by output multipliers, which makes the identification of key sectors in the local economy more difficult.

Closing remarks

Following the work of Blöchl et al. (2011) and García Muñiz et al. (2008), we implemented random walk-based measures of centrality in I–O networks to identify key sectors in the local and regional economy, using IMPLAN data and our own R code. The brief examination of the literature confirmed that the need for identifying key sectors remains and that improved network analysis techniques are apt instruments for the task. Thus we completed the three original objectives of our research (1) implement RWC and CBET in R; (2) test the implementation on subnational regional datasets; and (3) the presenting a preliminary consolidated version of network metrics from the existing literature.
Future explorations include the analysis of other applications of these network metrics, such as identification of industrial clusters.We posit that the measures developed in this paper could uncover previously unidentified clusters and analyze their evolution over time; both could be instrumental in informing future policy actions.

Declarations

Competing interests

The authors declare that there are no competing interests or conflicts related to this research.
Open AccessThis article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://​creativecommons.​org/​licenses/​by/​4.​0/​.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Anhänge

Appendix 1: Top 10 sectors by selected indicators for Monterey County

Order
Output multiplier
Employment multiplier
Random walk centrality
Counting betweenness
1
Securities other financial
Social assistance
Professional, scientific, tech svcs
Professional, scientific, tech svcs
2
Funds, trusts, other finan
Misc retailers
Management of companies
Real estate
3
Electronics, appliances stores
Personal, laundry svcs
Real estate
Admin support svcs
4
Broadcasting
Private households
Admin support svcs
Wholesale Trade
5
Food products
Admin support svcs
Wholesale Trade
Construction
6
Personal, laundry svcs
Educational svcs
Construction
Insurance carriers, related
7
Social assistance
Nursing, residential care
Government, non NAICs
Monetary authorities
8
Sightseeing transportation
Sports, hobby, book, music stores
Monetary authorities
Management of companies
9
Religious, grantmaking, similar orgs
Food svcs, drinking places
Securities, other financial
Securities, other financial
10
Telecommu-nications
Ag, Forestry Svcs
Food svcs, drinking places
Government, non NAICs

Appendix 2: Complete rankings for Monterey County

Sector ID
Sector description
Output multiplier
Employment multiplier
Random walk centrality
Counting betweenness centrality
1
Crop Farming
66
36
38
37
2
Livestock
20
66
49
48
3
Forestry & Logging
35
29
78
79
4
Fishing- Hunting & Trapping
70
19
79
72
5
Ag & Forestry Svcs
55
10
81
49
6
Oil & gas extraction
72
68
35
34
7
Mining
83
73
71
71
8
Mining services
58
53
37
31
9
Utilities
85
85
27
20
10
Construction
23
44
6
5
11
Food products
5
62
26
23
12
Beverage & Tobacco
36
70
64
64
13
Textile Mills
78
58
74
75
14
Textile Products
42
43
70
70
15
Leather & Allied
15
31
80
80
16
Wood Products
59
46
65
65
17
Paper Manufacturing
71
74
75
76
18
Printing & Related
47
37
56
57
19
Petroleum & coal prod
27
83
59
59
20
Chemical Manufacturing
79
84
46
44
21
Plastics & rubber prod
81
69
76
77
22
Nonmetal mineral prod
69
65
72
73
23
Primary metal mfg
61
61
69
69
24
Fabricated metal prod
74
55
60
60
25
Machinery Mfg
75
76
30
28
26
Computer & oth electron
65
71
36
35
27
Electircal eqpt & appliances
77
67
77
78
28
Transportation eqpmt
80
80
53
51
29
Furniture & related prod
60
47
58
58
30
Miscellaneous mfg
51
51
68
68
31
Wholesale Trade
54
60
5
4
32
Motor veh & parts dealers
67
40
33
36
33
Furniture & home furnishings
37
27
61
61
34
Electronics & appliances stores
3
11
66
66
35
Bldg materials & garden dealers
33
25
45
46
36
food & beverage stores
50
15
51
52
37
Health & personal care stores
26
20
39
39
38
Gasoline stations
34
34
43
43
39
Clothing & accessories stores
49
22
21
24
40
Sports- hobby- book & music stores
38
8
52
53
41
General merch stores
48
16
31
32
42
Misc retailers
17
2
41
41
43
Non-store retailers
68
35
15
16
44
Air transportation
41
64
32
33
45
Rail Transportation
29
59
62
62
46
Water transportation
86
86
86
86
47
Truck transportation
28
39
19
22
48
Transit & ground passengers
40
17
20
30
49
Pipeline transportation
45
63
73
74
50
Sightseeing transportation
8
32
18
15
51
Couriers & messengers
18
14
24
25
52
Warehousing & storage
30
33
28
27
53
Publishing industries
76
72
57
56
54
Motion picture & sound recording
82
77
34
26
55
Broadcasting
4
56
47
42
56
Internet publishing and broadcasting
62
82
12
13
57
Telecommunications
10
52
48
47
58
Internet & data process svcs
64
81
63
63
59
Other information services
43
75
50
50
60
Monetary authorities
16
45
8
7
61
Credit inmediation & related
19
48
14
14
62
Securities & other financial
1
13
9
9
63
Insurance carriers & related
57
54
13
6
64
Funds- trusts & other finan
2
18
55
55
65
Real estate
84
78
3
2
66
Rental & leasing svcs
63
49
17
21
67
Lessor of nonfinance intang assets
56
79
16
18
68
Professional- scientific & tech svcs
32
41
1
1
69
Management of companies
12
50
2
8
70
Admin support svcs
39
5
4
3
71
Waste mgmt & remediation svcs
53
57
22
17
72
Educational svcs
21
6
54
54
73
Ambulatory health care
25
30
67
67
74
Hospitals
22
38
82
81
75
Nursing & residential care
13
7
84
83
76
Social assistance
7
1
84
83
77
Performing arts & spectator sports
14
21
23
19
78
Museums & similar
11
26
25
83
79
Amusement- gambling & recreation
31
23
44
45
80
Accommodations
46
24
29
29
81
Food svcs & drinking places
24
9
10
11
82
Repair & maintenance
52
28
11
12
83
Personal & laundry svcs
6
3
42
40
84
Religious- grantmaking- & similar orgs
9
12
40
38
85
Private households
44
4
86
86
86
Government & non NAICs
73
42
7
10

Appendix 3: Top 10 sectors by random walk centrality for Detroit (Wayne County), State of Michigan, and the United States

Order
Detroit
Michigan
United States
1
Professional- scientific and tech svcs
Professional- scientific and tech svcs
Professional- scientific and tech svcs
2
Management of companies
Management of companies
Management of companies
3
Real estate
Real estate
Real estate
4
Admin support svcs
Admin support svcs
Admin support svcs
5
Construction
Construction
Wholesale Trade
6
Wholesale Trade
Wholesale Trade
Construction
7
Petroleum and coal prod
Insurance carriers and related
Petroleum and coal prod
8
Utilities
Monetary authorities
Securities and other financial
9
Monetary authorities
Securities and other financial
Monetary authorities
10
Insurance carriers and related
Utilities
Oil and gas extraction

Appendix 4: Top 10 sectors by counting betweenness for Detroit (Wayne County), State of Michigan, and the United States

Order
Detroit
Michigan
United States
1
Professional- scientific and tech svcs
Professional- scientific and tech svcs
Professional- scientific and tech svcs
2
Utilities
Insurance carriers and related
Insurance carriers and related
3
Real estate
Real estate
Real estate
4
Admin support svcs
Admin support svcs
Admin support svcs
5
Insurance carriers and related
Utilities
Utilities
6
Construction
Construction
Chemical Manufacturing
7
Wholesale Trade
Wholesale Trade
Wholesale Trade
8
Petroleum and coal prod
Monetary authorities
Securities and other financial
9
Management of companies
Securities and other financial
Management of companies
10
Monetary authorities
Management of companies
Monetary authorities

Appendix 5: Complete rankings for Detroit (Wayne County), State of Michigan, and the United States

Sector ID
Sector description
Random walk centrality
Counting betweenness
Detroit
Michigan
United States
Detroit
Michigan
United States
1
Crop Farming
11
61
55
70
59
54
2
Livestock
78
69
58
76
64
55
3
Forestry and Logging
83
65
66
81
56
58
4
Fishing- Hunting and Trapping
82
68
69
77
79
77
5
Ag and Forestry Svcs
80
67
67
78
66
65
6
Oil and gas extraction
31
23
10
28
24
14
7
Mining
79
46
29
79
46
25
8
Mining services
63
35
14
60
33
13
9
Utilities
8
10
13
2
5
5
10
Construction
5
5
6
6
6
11
11
Food products
39
48
41
31
45
35
12
Beverage and Tobacco
71
63
62
68
62
61
13
Textile Mills
75
78
73
73
76
70
14
Textile Products
74
81
79
72
80
78
15
Leather and Allied
81
82
82
80
81
81
16
Wood Products
62
44
49
57
42
42
17
Paper Manufacturing
77
53
35
75
49
32
18
Printing and Related
57
54
45
55
54
44
19
Petroleum and coal prod
7
20
7
8
20
12
20
Chemical Manufacturing
70
37
12
67
34
6
21
Plastics and rubber prod
33
41
31
29
40
31
22
Nonmetal mineral prod
76
34
42
74
32
41
23
Primary metal mfg
47
49
23
43
47
19
24
Fabricated metal prod
45
29
18
42
30
17
25
Machinery Mfg
18
55
21
15
55
22
26
Computer and oth electron
40
73
25
34
70
18
27
Electircal eqpt and appliances
35
64
51
32
65
52
28
Transportation eqpmt
23
33
34
17
29
28
29
Furniture and related prod
50
74
64
48
72
62
30
Miscellaneous mfg
66
75
65
62
73
64
31
Wholesale Trade
6
6
5
7
7
7
32
Motor veh and parts dealers
36
38
57
36
38
57
33
Furniture and home furnishings
69
76
78
66
74
76
34
Electronics and appliances stores
73
79
81
71
78
80
35
Bldg materials and garden dealers
52
56
74
49
57
72
36
food and beverage stores
61
71
76
59
69
74
37
Health and personal care stores
44
45
63
41
48
66
38
Gasoline stations
55
58
72
53
58
71
39
Clothing and accessories stores
25
30
50
25
31
51
40
Sports- hobby- book and music stores
60
66
77
58
67
75
41
General merch stores
34
36
56
33
35
56
42
Misc retailers
46
51
71
46
51
69
43
Non-store retailers
27
26
43
27
27
43
44
Air transportation
42
25
33
38
25
37
45
Rail Transportation
54
62
46
51
63
47
46
Water transportation
68
72
70
65
71
68
47
Truck transportation
16
17
27
16
17
30
48
Transit and ground passengers
17
18
28
39
44
46
49
Pipeline transportation
41
39
48
37
39
48
50
Sightseeing transportation
49
24
30
47
22
24
51
Couriers and messengers
24
22
32
24
19
33
52
Warehousing and storage
22
28
38
21
28
39
53
Publishing industries
59
42
52
56
37
50
54
Motion picture and sound recording
51
47
47
44
41
38
55
Broadcasting
58
57
54
54
52
49
56
Internet publishing and broadcasting
21
15
16
19
11
15
57
Telecommunications
43
19
24
40
21
27
58
Internet and data process svcs
67
52
61
64
53
63
59
Other information services
56
43
40
52
43
40
60
Monetary authorities
9
8
9
10
8
10
61
Credit inmediation and related
19
14
19
18
15
20
62
Securities and other financial
14
9
8
11
9
8
63
Insurance carriers and related
10
7
11
5
2
2
64
Funds- trusts and other finan
64
59
68
61
60
67
65
Real estate
3
3
3
3
3
3
66
Rental and leasing svcs
20
21
26
20
23
29
67
Lessor of nonfinance intang assets
26
16
22
26
16
26
68
Professional- scientific and tech svcs
1
1
1
1
1
1
69
Management of companies
2
2
2
9
10
9
70
Admin support svcs
4
4
4
4
4
4
71
Waste mgmt and remediation svcs
29
27
36
23
18
36
72
Educational svcs
65
70
75
63
68
73
73
Ambulatory health care
72
80
80
69
77
79
74
Hospitals
84
83
83
82
82
82
75
Nursing and residential care
84
83
83
83
83
83
76
Social assistance
84
83
83
83
83
83
77
Performing arts and spectator sports
28
31
37
22
26
34
78
Museums and similar
30
32
39
83
83
83
79
Amusement- gambling and recreation
53
60
60
50
61
60
80
Accommodations
32
77
44
30
75
45
81
Food svcs and drinking places
13
12
17
13
13
21
82
Repair and maintenance
15
13
20
14
14
23
83
Personal and laundry svcs
48
50
59
45
50
59
84
Religious- grantmaking- and similar orgs
37
40
53
35
36
53
85
Private households
38
86
86
86
86
86
Fußnoten
1
NOTE: In the field of network analytics it is very common to find multiple definitions and implementations for the same metric, or one with very slight variations. Whenever possible, we refer to the earliest definition of a measure or concept.
 
2
One reason for high density is high levels of sectoral aggreation. But even highly disaggregated systems, with hundreds of nodes, can have, for example d > 0.7, where 70% of all possible ties are present.
 
3
Loops may disappear (or be drastically reduced) at higher levels sectoral aggregation.
 
4
In directed networks, the degree measure can be separated into in-degree and out-degree to account for ties coming to or going from a node, respectively.
 
5
When running the analysis at the 2-digic NAICS level (North American Industrial Classification System level which contains 20 sectors), we found degree values averaging around 19, meaning the almost every sector was connected to every other sectors.
 
6
In a random walk process (such as a Markov chain), for pair of “states”, there is a transition probability of going from the source node to the target node. The “transition matrix” M contains the probability of each step of the process of being at the source or the target. For detailed discussions, see Blum et al. (2015) and Schulman (2016).
 
7
Equivalent to the 3-digit level of NAICS.
 
8
Full specification of the IMPAN dataset.
 
9
For a detail discussion of the calculations, see Blöchl et al. (2011). They provide the corresponding Matlab code, but it did not work as stated by the authors.
 
10
IMPLAN granted us special permission to use internal components of their software for the development of our research, for which we are grateful.
 
11
The relationship between gross and regional absorption is capture by “regional purchase coefficients”.
 
12
IMPLAN has since shifted to a browser-based implementation and the data structure might have changed.
 
13
Contact the corresponding author for additional details.
 
14
In this context, I–O modelers can simulate “shocks” to the systems by, for instance, increasing or decreasing the value of output in a sector
 
15
The description of the process gives the appearance of dynamics, but in reality we are just computing the aggregate effects as if it were happening instantaneously. In our metrics, there is no explicit modeling of time.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Aroche Reyes F, Marquez Mendoza MA (2012) An economic network in North America. MPRA Paper 61391, University Library of Munich, Germany Aroche Reyes F, Marquez Mendoza MA (2012) An economic network in North America. MPRA Paper 61391, University Library of Munich, Germany
Zurück zum Zitat Blöchl F, Theis FJ, Vega-Redondo F, Fisher E (2011) Vertex centralities in input–output networks reveal the structure of modern economies. Phys Rev E 83(4):046127CrossRef Blöchl F, Theis FJ, Vega-Redondo F, Fisher E (2011) Vertex centralities in input–output networks reveal the structure of modern economies. Phys Rev E 83(4):046127CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Blum A, Hopcroft J, Kannan R (2015) Foundations of data science Blum A, Hopcroft J, Kannan R (2015) Foundations of data science
Zurück zum Zitat Brandes U (2001) A faster algorithm for betweenness centrality. J Math Sociol 25:163–177CrossRefMATH Brandes U (2001) A faster algorithm for betweenness centrality. J Math Sociol 25:163–177CrossRefMATH
Zurück zum Zitat Campbell J (1975) Application of graph theoretic analysis to inter-industry relationships. Reg Sci Urban Econ 5:91–106CrossRef Campbell J (1975) Application of graph theoretic analysis to inter-industry relationships. Reg Sci Urban Econ 5:91–106CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Freeman L (1977) A set of measures of centrality based on betweenness. Sociometry 40(1):35–41CrossRef Freeman L (1977) A set of measures of centrality based on betweenness. Sociometry 40(1):35–41CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Freeman L (1978/79) Centrality in social networks conceptual clarification. Soc Netw 1(3):215–239 Freeman L (1978/79) Centrality in social networks conceptual clarification. Soc Netw 1(3):215–239
Zurück zum Zitat Freeman L, Borgatti S, White D (1991) Centrality in valued graphs: a measure of betweenness based on network flow. Soc Netw 13:141–154MathSciNetCrossRef Freeman L, Borgatti S, White D (1991) Centrality in valued graphs: a measure of betweenness based on network flow. Soc Netw 13:141–154MathSciNetCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Freeman LC (2004) The development of social network analysis: a study of the sociology of science. Empirical Press, Vancouver Freeman LC (2004) The development of social network analysis: a study of the sociology of science. Empirical Press, Vancouver
Zurück zum Zitat Friedkin N (1991) Theoretical foundations for centrality measures. Am J Sociol 96(6):1478–1504CrossRef Friedkin N (1991) Theoretical foundations for centrality measures. Am J Sociol 96(6):1478–1504CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat García Muñiz A (2013) Modelling linkages versus leakages networks: the case of Spain. Reg Sect Econ Stud 13(1):43–54 García Muñiz A (2013) Modelling linkages versus leakages networks: the case of Spain. Reg Sect Econ Stud 13(1):43–54
Zurück zum Zitat García Muñiz A, Morillas Raya A, Ramos Carvajal C (2008) Key sectors: a new proposal from network theory. Reg Stud 42(7):1013–1030CrossRef García Muñiz A, Morillas Raya A, Ramos Carvajal C (2008) Key sectors: a new proposal from network theory. Reg Stud 42(7):1013–1030CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Giuliani E (2013) Network dynamics in regional clusters: evidence from Chile. Res Policy 42(8):1406–1419CrossRef Giuliani E (2013) Network dynamics in regional clusters: evidence from Chile. Res Policy 42(8):1406–1419CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Guo J, Planting M (2000) Using input–output analysis to measure the U.S. economic structural change over a 24 year period. BEA Papers 0004, Bureau of Economic Analysis Guo J, Planting M (2000) Using input–output analysis to measure the U.S. economic structural change over a 24 year period. BEA Papers 0004, Bureau of Economic Analysis
Zurück zum Zitat Harrison K, Ventresca M, Ombuki-Berman B (2016) A meta-analysis of centrality measures for comparing and generating complex network models. J Comput Sci 17:205–215CrossRef Harrison K, Ventresca M, Ombuki-Berman B (2016) A meta-analysis of centrality measures for comparing and generating complex network models. J Comput Sci 17:205–215CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hewings GJD (1982) The empirical identification of key sectors in an economy: a regional perspective. Dev Econ 20(2):173–195CrossRef Hewings GJD (1982) The empirical identification of key sectors in an economy: a regional perspective. Dev Econ 20(2):173–195CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hubbell C (1965) An input–output approach to clique identification. Sociometry 28(4):377–399CrossRef Hubbell C (1965) An input–output approach to clique identification. Sociometry 28(4):377–399CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Jorgenson D (2016) Econometric general equilibrium modeling. J Policy Model 38(3):436–447CrossRef Jorgenson D (2016) Econometric general equilibrium modeling. J Policy Model 38(3):436–447CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Laumas P (1975) Key sectors in some underdeveloped countries. Kyklos 28(1):62–79CrossRef Laumas P (1975) Key sectors in some underdeveloped countries. Kyklos 28(1):62–79CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lee C-Y (2006) Correlations among centrality measures in complex networks. ArXiv Physics e-prints Lee C-Y (2006) Correlations among centrality measures in complex networks. ArXiv Physics e-prints
Zurück zum Zitat Meng F, Gu Y, Fu S, Wang M, Guo Y (2017) Comparison of different centrality measures to find influential nodes in complex networks. In: Wang G, Atiquzzaman M, Yan Z, Choo K (eds) Security, privacy, and anonymity in computation, communication, and storage. Springer, pp 415–423CrossRef Meng F, Gu Y, Fu S, Wang M, Guo Y (2017) Comparison of different centrality measures to find influential nodes in complex networks. In: Wang G, Atiquzzaman M, Yan Z, Choo K (eds) Security, privacy, and anonymity in computation, communication, and storage. Springer, pp 415–423CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Miller R, Blair P (2009) Input–output analysis, foundations and extensions. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRefMATH Miller R, Blair P (2009) Input–output analysis, foundations and extensions. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRefMATH
Zurück zum Zitat Montresor S, Marzetti G (2009) Applying social network analysis to input–output based innovation matrices: an illustrative application to six OECD technological systems for middle 1990s. Econ Syst Res 21(2):129–149CrossRef Montresor S, Marzetti G (2009) Applying social network analysis to input–output based innovation matrices: an illustrative application to six OECD technological systems for middle 1990s. Econ Syst Res 21(2):129–149CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Moreno J (1934) Who shall survive? Nervous and Mental Disease Publishing Company, Washington Moreno J (1934) Who shall survive? Nervous and Mental Disease Publishing Company, Washington
Zurück zum Zitat Newman MEJ (2001) Scientific collaboration networks. II. Shortest paths, weighted networks, and centrality. Phys Rev E 64:016132CrossRef Newman MEJ (2001) Scientific collaboration networks. II. Shortest paths, weighted networks, and centrality. Phys Rev E 64:016132CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Newman M (2005) A measure of betweenness centrality based on random walks. Soc Netw 27(1):39–54CrossRef Newman M (2005) A measure of betweenness centrality based on random walks. Soc Netw 27(1):39–54CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Noh J, Rieger H (2004) Random walks on complex networks. Phys Rev Lett 92:118701CrossRef Noh J, Rieger H (2004) Random walks on complex networks. Phys Rev Lett 92:118701CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Opsahl T (2015) tnet: software for analysis of weighted, two-mode, and longitudinal networks Opsahl T (2015) tnet: software for analysis of weighted, two-mode, and longitudinal networks
Zurück zum Zitat Opsahl T, Agneessens F, Skvoretz J (2010) Node centrality in weighted networks: generalizing degree and shortest paths. Soc Netw 32:245–251CrossRef Opsahl T, Agneessens F, Skvoretz J (2010) Node centrality in weighted networks: generalizing degree and shortest paths. Soc Netw 32:245–251CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rasmussen PN (1956) Studies in inter-sectoral relations. E. Harck, Copenhagen Rasmussen PN (1956) Studies in inter-sectoral relations. E. Harck, Copenhagen
Zurück zum Zitat Reid N, Smith B, Carroll M (2008) Cluster regions. Econ Dev Q 22(4):345–352CrossRef Reid N, Smith B, Carroll M (2008) Cluster regions. Econ Dev Q 22(4):345–352CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Roepke H, Adams D, Wiseman R (1974) A new approach to the identification of industrial complexes using input–output data. J Reg Sci 14(1):15–29CrossRef Roepke H, Adams D, Wiseman R (1974) A new approach to the identification of industrial complexes using input–output data. J Reg Sci 14(1):15–29CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Schultz S (1977) Approaches to identifying key sectors empirically by means of input–output analysis. J Dev Stud 14(1):77–96CrossRef Schultz S (1977) Approaches to identifying key sectors empirically by means of input–output analysis. J Dev Stud 14(1):77–96CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Streit M (1969) Spatial associations and economic linkages between industries. J Reg Sci 9(2):177–187CrossRef Streit M (1969) Spatial associations and economic linkages between industries. J Reg Sci 9(2):177–187CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Identifying key sectors in the regional economy: a network analysis approach using input–output data
verfasst von
Fernando DePaolis
Phil Murphy
M. Clara De Paolis Kaluza
Publikationsdatum
01.12.2022
Verlag
Springer International Publishing
Erschienen in
Applied Network Science / Ausgabe 1/2022
Elektronische ISSN: 2364-8228
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s41109-022-00519-2

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 1/2022

Applied Network Science 1/2022 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner