Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Current Sustainable/Renewable Energy Reports 4/2019

05.09.2019 | Transportation (D Chen, Section Editor)

Implications of Behavioral Economics for the Costs and Benefits of Fuel Economy Standards

verfasst von: David L. Greene

Erschienen in: Current Sustainable/Renewable Energy Reports | Ausgabe 4/2019

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Purpose of Review

This review focuses on recent developments in the application of behavioral economics to the evaluation of energy efficiency and greenhouse gas regulations. Transportation is the largest source of CO2 emissions from energy use in the US economy and a major and growing source worldwide. Regulating the efficiency of motor vehicles has been a core component of energy policy in the USA, the EU, China, Japan, Canada, and many other nations. Recent findings concerning consumers’ actual decision-making about energy efficiency indicate that the premises of the rational economic model are not appropriate for evaluating energy-efficiency standards.

Recent Findings

Progress in behavioral psychology and economics has shown that loss aversion, the principle that faced with a risky choice human beings tend to weigh potential losses about twice as heavily as gains, is strongly affected by framing. Simple, risky choices in which there is a status quo option generally provoke loss-averse responses. Recent analyses show that the choice to buy or not buy energy-efficiency technologies induces loss aversion and can result in systematic underinvestment in energy efficiency. Empirical investigation of consumers’ fuel economy decision-making contradicts the rational economic model and is consistent with loss aversion. However, recent economic evaluations of fuel economy and greenhouse gas regulations are explicitly or implicitly premised on rational economic behavior.

Summary

Insights developed by behavioral psychologists and behavioral economists about the decision-making of real consumers provide a coherent explanation that fundamentally alters the way fuel economy regulations should be evaluated. If consumers are assumed to make decisions according to the rational economic model and markets are reasonably efficient, regulations cannot produce large private fuel savings. The behavioral economic model explains not only why such savings do exist but why consumers strongly support fuel economy regulations. The private savings from fuel economy regulations can be large relative to the social benefits of fuel economy and greenhouse gas regulations.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 390 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe




 

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
The sustainability goals are stabilizing global climate change, enhancing energy security and resiliency, eliminating air pollution, and achieving universal access to modern energy services.
 
2
Figure 1 does not include the “rebound effect,” which is the tendency for vehicle travel to increase when fuel economy improves; however, the 2 trillion gallon estimate does [2].
 
3
Daniel Kahneman was awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics in 2002 for his work in behavioral economics including Cumulative Prospect Theory and loss aversion. His book cited here, Thinking Fast and Slow, won the National Academies’ Best Book Award for 2012 [31]. Richard Thaler won the 2017 Nobel Prize in Economics for his work in behavioral economics.
 
4
Weighing losses twice as much as gains is a typical or average loss-averse response. Kahneman [27] cites a range of 1.5 to 2.5, but there is even greater variation among individuals.
 
5
“Third, by implementing the modular elements of CPT, we can conclude that loss aversion is the major driver of the EE gap. Our results indicate that other elements of CPT, such as probability weighting, have a rather negligible influence. As an exception, however, we find the determination of the reference-point to be very important. Depending on how the EE investment is framed, or perceived by the decision-maker, the EE gap might vanish or be amplified.” [23]
 
6
Sallee [34] simulated annual fuel costs based on 100,000 random drawings from actual distributions of annual miles, discount rates and the gasoline price forecasts of individual consumers. The estimates varied widely in relation to label values even though uncertainty about actual on-road fuel economy was not included. “This means that even if a fuel economy label explained the lifetime fuel costs accurately for the median driver, that estimate will be too high or too low by $6200, or 50%, on average.” [34], p., 789
 
7
The measure of variability is insensitive to the discount rate assumed. The analysis is based on annual prices of regular grade gasoline from the EIA October 26, 2018 Monthly Energy Review Table 9.4, converted to 2017 dollars using the FRED GDP price deflator.
 
8
Hamilton [36] demonstrated that world oil prices are indistinguishable from a random walk, and nearly all the variability in US gasoline prices over time can be explained by changes in world oil prices [37].
 
9
This result is consistent with Dharshing and Hille [45] who found that numeracy and energy literacy were not statistically significantly related to the energy efficiency choices of Swiss households but impulsivity and risk aversion were.
 
10
The Ford Model T was introduced in 1908.
 
11
The fifth committee’s work is still in progress and no findings have been issued.
 
12
Assumes a 6% annual discount rate and a 13-year vehicle lifetime.
 
13
The four studies are not independent. Helfand and Wolverton [52] make extensive use of Greene [49], and Greene et al. [51] is based on estimates presented in EPA [50].
 
14
A vehicle’s mass determines the physical work that must be done to accelerate it and to overcome the friction of rolling resistance. Mass is also correlated with size and frontal area, a key determinant of aerodynamic resistance. Finally, apart from a vehicle’s mass, for vehicles with stoichiometric engines, engine size determines how much fuel is consumed per engine revolution.
 
15
The mathematical representation of loss aversion used is taken from Bernartzi and Thaler [65] and was intended to describe consumers’ behavior in the case of simple win or lose bets. Uncertainties about future fuel savings are far more complex. How best to describe consumers’ decision-making in the face of more complex uncertainties would seem to be an important subject for future research.
 
16
EUT can include risk aversion. However, risk aversion is different from loss aversion and cannot explain the magnitude of undervaluing implied by loss aversion [66].
 
17
A common definition of willingness to pay is the maximum amount of money a consumer will give up to obtain a good or avoid a bad [67].
 
18
A large part of this may be due to different vehicles having different drivers making different kinds of trips.
 
19
The assumption of independence is a convenient simplification. There is some evidence that the on-road shortfall responds to the price of gasoline [24].
 
20
The NRC’s high cost function was chosen because it better illustrates situations in which loss-averse consumers would decline fuel economy improvements.
 
21
A car buyer’s willingness to pay (WTP) for increased fuel economy is calculated based on estimated on-road as opposed to test cycle fuel economy, annual miles driven and the rate at which miles decrease over time, expected vehicle life, expected price of gasoline, and the discount rate for future fuel savings.
 
22
Taking external costs of fuel consumption into account, the socially optimal mpg would be higher than the privately optimal mpg. On the other hand, the private optimum would include fuel taxes in the price of fuel while the social optimum would not.
 
23
The automotive market is very competitive even if it is not perfectly competitive. Even assuming oligopolistic supply and Bertrand competition, the shadow price of a binding fuel economy or greenhouse gas emission constraint will induce the adoption of fuel economy improving technologies across all vehicles, except for vehicles that have already adopted all technologies justified by the shadow price.
 
24
Surveys indicate that US consumers consistently and overwhelmingly approved of fuel economy standards. Typically, 70 to 80% of respondents favored fuel economy standards and raising the standards (5, Table 9.2; 4).
 
25
Feebates that tax-inefficient vehicles and subsidize efficient vehicles at a fixed rate per gallon per mile are an example of such taxes [79, 80].
 
Literatur
1.
Zurück zum Zitat Global Energy Assessment (GEA). Global Energy Assessment: Toward a Sustainable Future. Laxenburg, Austria: Cambridge University press, Cambridge, UK and New York, NY, USA and the International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis; 2012. Global Energy Assessment (GEA). Global Energy Assessment: Toward a Sustainable Future. Laxenburg, Austria: Cambridge University press, Cambridge, UK and New York, NY, USA and the International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis; 2012.
4.
Zurück zum Zitat Greene DL, Welch JG. Impacts of fuel economy improvements on the distribution of income in the US. Energy Policy. 2018;122:528–41. Greene DL, Welch JG. Impacts of fuel economy improvements on the distribution of income in the US. Energy Policy. 2018;122:528–41.
5.
Zurück zum Zitat Consumer Reports Survey Group (CRSG). 2017 and 2018. “2018 Automotive Fuel Economy Survey Report” and “2017 Automotive Fuel Economy Survey Report”, provided by Shannon Baker-Brandstetter, Consumers Union, 2018. Consumer Reports Survey Group (CRSG). 2017 and 2018. “2018 Automotive Fuel Economy Survey Report” and “2017 Automotive Fuel Economy Survey Report”, provided by Shannon Baker-Brandstetter, Consumers Union, 2018.
6.
Zurück zum Zitat National Research Council (NRC). Cost, effectiveness, and deployment of fuel economy technologies for light-duty vehicles. Washington, DC: National Academies Press; 2015. National Research Council (NRC). Cost, effectiveness, and deployment of fuel economy technologies for light-duty vehicles. Washington, DC: National Academies Press; 2015.
7.
Zurück zum Zitat Klier T, Linn J. The effect of vehicle fuel economy standards on technology adoption. J Public Econ. 2016;133(C):41–63. Klier T, Linn J. The effect of vehicle fuel economy standards on technology adoption. J Public Econ. 2016;133(C):41–63.
8.
Zurück zum Zitat Jacobsen M, Benthem V. Vehicle scrappage and gasoline policy. Am Econ Rev. 2015;105(3):1312–38. Jacobsen M, Benthem V. Vehicle scrappage and gasoline policy. Am Econ Rev. 2015;105(3):1312–38.
9.
Zurück zum Zitat Jacobsen MR. Evaluating US fuel economy standards in a model with producer and household heterogeneity. Am Econ J Econ Pol. 2013;5(2):148–87. Jacobsen MR. Evaluating US fuel economy standards in a model with producer and household heterogeneity. Am Econ J Econ Pol. 2013;5(2):148–87.
10.
Zurück zum Zitat Goulder LH, Jacobsen MR, van Benthem AA. Unintended consequences from nested state & federal regulations: the case of the Pavley greenhouse-gas-per mile limits. J Environ Econ Manag. 2012;63(2):187–207. Goulder LH, Jacobsen MR, van Benthem AA. Unintended consequences from nested state & federal regulations: the case of the Pavley greenhouse-gas-per mile limits. J Environ Econ Manag. 2012;63(2):187–207.
11.
Zurück zum Zitat Klier T, Linn J. New-vehicle characteristics and the cost of the corporate average fuel economy standard. RAND J Econ. 2012;43(1):186–213. Klier T, Linn J. New-vehicle characteristics and the cost of the corporate average fuel economy standard. RAND J Econ. 2012;43(1):186–213.
12.
Zurück zum Zitat Fischer C, Harrington W, Parry I. Do market failures justify tightening corporate average fuel economy (CAFEE) standards? Energy J. 2007;28(4):1–30. Fischer C, Harrington W, Parry I. Do market failures justify tightening corporate average fuel economy (CAFEE) standards? Energy J. 2007;28(4):1–30.
13.
Zurück zum Zitat Austin D, Dinan T. Clearing the air: the costs and consequences of higher CAFE standards and increased gasoline taxes. J Environ Econ Manag. 2005;50(3):562–82.MATH Austin D, Dinan T. Clearing the air: the costs and consequences of higher CAFE standards and increased gasoline taxes. J Environ Econ Manag. 2005;50(3):562–82.MATH
14.
Zurück zum Zitat West SE, Williams RC. The cost of reducing gasoline consumption. Am Econ Rev. 2005;95(2):294–9. West SE, Williams RC. The cost of reducing gasoline consumption. Am Econ Rev. 2005;95(2):294–9.
15.
Zurück zum Zitat Kleit AN. Impacts of long-range increases in the fuel economy (CAFE) standard. Econ Inq. 2004;42(2):279–94. Kleit AN. Impacts of long-range increases in the fuel economy (CAFE) standard. Econ Inq. 2004;42(2):279–94.
17.
Zurück zum Zitat National Research Council (NRC). Automotive fuel economy: how far can we go? Report of the committee on automobile and light truck fuel economy. Washington, DC: National Academy Press; 1992. National Research Council (NRC). Automotive fuel economy: how far can we go? Report of the committee on automobile and light truck fuel economy. Washington, DC: National Academy Press; 1992.
18.
Zurück zum Zitat National Research Council (NRC). Effectiveness and impact of corporate average fuel economy (CAFE) standards, Report of the Committee. Washington: National Academy Press; 2002. p. 2002. National Research Council (NRC). Effectiveness and impact of corporate average fuel economy (CAFE) standards, Report of the Committee. Washington: National Academy Press; 2002. p. 2002.
19.
Zurück zum Zitat National Research Council (NRC). Assessment of fuel economy technologies for light-duty vehicles, report of the committee on the assessment of technologies for improving light-duty vehicle fuel economy. Washington, D.C.: National Academies Press; 2011. National Research Council (NRC). Assessment of fuel economy technologies for light-duty vehicles, report of the committee on the assessment of technologies for improving light-duty vehicle fuel economy. Washington, D.C.: National Academies Press; 2011.
20.
Zurück zum Zitat Gerarden TD, Newell RG, Stavins RN, Stowe RC. An assessment of the energy-efficiency gap and its implications for climate-change policy, working paper 20905. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of economic research; 2015. Gerarden TD, Newell RG, Stavins RN, Stowe RC. An assessment of the energy-efficiency gap and its implications for climate-change policy, working paper 20905. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of economic research; 2015.
21.
Zurück zum Zitat Gillingham K, Palmer K. Bridging the energy efficiency gap: policy insights from economic theory and empirical evidence. Rev Environ Econ Policy. 2014;8(1):18–38. Gillingham K, Palmer K. Bridging the energy efficiency gap: policy insights from economic theory and empirical evidence. Rev Environ Econ Policy. 2014;8(1):18–38.
22.
Zurück zum Zitat Heutel G. Prospect theory and energy efficiency, NBER working paper 23692. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of economic research; 2017. Heutel G. Prospect theory and energy efficiency, NBER working paper 23692. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of economic research; 2017.
23.
Zurück zum Zitat Häckel B, Pfosser S, Tränkler T. Explaining the energy efficiency gap – expected utility theory versus cumulative prospect theory. Energy Policy. 2017;111:414–26. Häckel B, Pfosser S, Tränkler T. Explaining the energy efficiency gap – expected utility theory versus cumulative prospect theory. Energy Policy. 2017;111:414–26.
24.
Zurück zum Zitat Greene DL. Uncertainty, loss aversion and markets for energy efficiency. Energy Econ. 2011;33:608–16. Greene DL. Uncertainty, loss aversion and markets for energy efficiency. Energy Econ. 2011;33:608–16.
25.
Zurück zum Zitat Starmer C. Developments in non-expected utility theory: the hunt for a descriptive theory of choice under risk. J Econ Lit. 2000;38:332–82. Starmer C. Developments in non-expected utility theory: the hunt for a descriptive theory of choice under risk. J Econ Lit. 2000;38:332–82.
26.
Zurück zum Zitat Dellavigna S. Psychology and economics: evidence from the field. J Econ Lit. 2009;47(2):315–72. Dellavigna S. Psychology and economics: evidence from the field. J Econ Lit. 2009;47(2):315–72.
27.
Zurück zum Zitat Kahneman D. Thinking fast and slow. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux; 2011. Kahneman D. Thinking fast and slow. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux; 2011.
28.
Zurück zum Zitat Thaler RH. Misbehaving: the making of behavioral economics. New York: W.W. Norton & Company; 2015. Thaler RH. Misbehaving: the making of behavioral economics. New York: W.W. Norton & Company; 2015.
29.
Zurück zum Zitat Novemsky N, Kahneman D. The boundaries of loss aversion. J Market Res. 2005;XLII:119–28. Novemsky N, Kahneman D. The boundaries of loss aversion. J Market Res. 2005;XLII:119–28.
30.
Zurück zum Zitat Ert E, Erev I. On the descriptive value of loss aversion in decisions under risk: six clarifications. Judgm Decis Mak. 2013;8(3):214–35. Ert E, Erev I. On the descriptive value of loss aversion in decisions under risk: six clarifications. Judgm Decis Mak. 2013;8(3):214–35.
32.
Zurück zum Zitat Tom SM, Fox CR, Trepel C, Poldrack RA. The neural basis of decision-making under risk. Science. 2007;315:515–8. Tom SM, Fox CR, Trepel C, Poldrack RA. The neural basis of decision-making under risk. Science. 2007;315:515–8.
33.
Zurück zum Zitat Kahneman D, Tversky A. Prospect theory: an analysis of decision making under risk. Econometrica. 1979;47:263–91.MathSciNetMATH Kahneman D, Tversky A. Prospect theory: an analysis of decision making under risk. Econometrica. 1979;47:263–91.MathSciNetMATH
34.
Zurück zum Zitat Sallee JM. Rational inattention and energy efficiency. J Law Econ. 2014;57(3):781–820. Sallee JM. Rational inattention and energy efficiency. J Law Econ. 2014;57(3):781–820.
35•.
Zurück zum Zitat Greene DL, Khattak AJ, Liu J, Wang X, Hopson JL, Goeltz R. What is the evidence concerning the gap between on-road and Environmental Protection Agency fuel economy ratings? Transport Policy. 2017;53:146–60. This paper summarizes evidence from four U.S. nationwide random sample surveys that framed fuel economy choices as risky bets. The results were as predicted by the behavioral economic principle of loss aversion and were also consistent with the stated beliefs of automobile manufacturers. Greene DL, Khattak AJ, Liu J, Wang X, Hopson JL, Goeltz R. What is the evidence concerning the gap between on-road and Environmental Protection Agency fuel economy ratings? Transport Policy. 2017;53:146–60. This paper summarizes evidence from four U.S. nationwide random sample surveys that framed fuel economy choices as risky bets. The results were as predicted by the behavioral economic principle of loss aversion and were also consistent with the stated beliefs of automobile manufacturers.
36.
Zurück zum Zitat Hamilton JD. Understanding crude oil prices. Energy J. 2009;30(2):179–206. Hamilton JD. Understanding crude oil prices. Energy J. 2009;30(2):179–206.
38.
Zurück zum Zitat Lin Z, Greene DL. Predicting individual on-road fuel economy using simple consumer and vehicle attributes, SAE Technical Paper Series No. 11SDP-0014. Warrendale, PA: Society of Automotive Engineers; 2011. Lin Z, Greene DL. Predicting individual on-road fuel economy using simple consumer and vehicle attributes, SAE Technical Paper Series No. 11SDP-0014. Warrendale, PA: Society of Automotive Engineers; 2011.
39.
Zurück zum Zitat Tversky A, Kahneman D. The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice. Science. 1981;211(4481):453–8.MathSciNetMATH Tversky A, Kahneman D. The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice. Science. 1981;211(4481):453–8.MathSciNetMATH
40.
Zurück zum Zitat Gal D, Rucker DD. The loss of loss aversion: will it loom larger than its gain. J Consum Psychol. 2018;28(3):497–516. Gal D, Rucker DD. The loss of loss aversion: will it loom larger than its gain. J Consum Psychol. 2018;28(3):497–516.
41.
Zurück zum Zitat Erev I, Ert E, Plonsky O, Cohen D, Cohen O. From anomalies to forecasts: toward a descriptive model of decisions under risk, under ambiguity, and from experience. Psychol Rev. 2017;124(4):369–409. Erev I, Ert E, Plonsky O, Cohen D, Cohen O. From anomalies to forecasts: toward a descriptive model of decisions under risk, under ambiguity, and from experience. Psychol Rev. 2017;124(4):369–409.
44•.
Zurück zum Zitat Turrentine TS, Kurani KS. Car buyers and fuel economy? Energy Policy. 2007;35:1213–23. This descriptive investigation of the car purchase decisions of households in California found that the rational economic model was not employed by any household when making decisions about fuel economy. Instead, consumers’ fuel economy decisions were overwhelmingly intuitive or based on simple rules. Turrentine TS, Kurani KS. Car buyers and fuel economy? Energy Policy. 2007;35:1213–23. This descriptive investigation of the car purchase decisions of households in California found that the rational economic model was not employed by any household when making decisions about fuel economy. Instead, consumers’ fuel economy decisions were overwhelmingly intuitive or based on simple rules.
45.
Zurück zum Zitat Dharshing S, Hille SL. The energy paradox revisted: analyzing the role of individual differences and framing effects in information perception. J Consum Policy. 2017;40:485–508. Dharshing S, Hille SL. The energy paradox revisted: analyzing the role of individual differences and framing effects in information perception. J Consum Policy. 2017;40:485–508.
46.
Zurück zum Zitat Leard B. Consumer inattention and the demand for vehicle fuel cost savings. J Choice Model. 2018;29:1–16. Leard B. Consumer inattention and the demand for vehicle fuel cost savings. J Choice Model. 2018;29:1–16.
47.
Zurück zum Zitat Greene DL, Evans DH, Hiestand J. Survey evidence on the willingness of U.S. consumers to pay for automotive fuel economy. Energy Policy. 2013;61:1539–50. Greene DL, Evans DH, Hiestand J. Survey evidence on the willingness of U.S. consumers to pay for automotive fuel economy. Energy Policy. 2013;61:1539–50.
48•.
Zurück zum Zitat Greene DL, DeCicco JM. Engineering-economic analyses of automotive fuel economy potential in the United States. Annu Rev Energ Environ. 2000;25:477–536. This paper finds that for consumers’ choices among energy efficiency options, the important aspects of cumulative prospect theory are loss aversion and reference dependence. Greene DL, DeCicco JM. Engineering-economic analyses of automotive fuel economy potential in the United States. Annu Rev Energ Environ. 2000;25:477–536. This paper finds that for consumers’ choices among energy efficiency options, the important aspects of cumulative prospect theory are loss aversion and reference dependence.
49.
Zurück zum Zitat Greene DL. How consumers value fuel economy: a literature review, EPA-420-R-10-008, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, 2010. Greene DL. How consumers value fuel economy: a literature review, EPA-420-R-10-008, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, 2010.
50.
Zurück zum Zitat U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (USEPA). Consumer willingness to pay for vehicle attributes: what is the current state of knowledge? Ann Arbor, MI: EPA-420-R-18-016, Assessment and Standards Division, Office of Transportation and Air Quality, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency; 2018. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (USEPA). Consumer willingness to pay for vehicle attributes: what is the current state of knowledge? Ann Arbor, MI: EPA-420-R-18-016, Assessment and Standards Division, Office of Transportation and Air Quality, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency; 2018.
51.
Zurück zum Zitat Greene DL, Hossain A, Hofmann J, Helfand G, Beach R. Consumer willingness to pay for vehicle attributes: what do we know? Transport Res A. 2018;118:258–79. Greene DL, Hossain A, Hofmann J, Helfand G, Beach R. Consumer willingness to pay for vehicle attributes: what do we know? Transport Res A. 2018;118:258–79.
52•.
Zurück zum Zitat Helfand G, Wolverton A. Evaluating consumer response to fuel economy: a review of the literature. Int Rev Environ Resour Econ. 2011;5(2):103–46. The experiments analyzed in this paper show that loss aversion can explain consumers’ choices among energy efficiency options and that the private savings from cost-effective increases in energy efficiency can exceed the value of reduced externalities. Helfand G, Wolverton A. Evaluating consumer response to fuel economy: a review of the literature. Int Rev Environ Resour Econ. 2011;5(2):103–46. The experiments analyzed in this paper show that loss aversion can explain consumers’ choices among energy efficiency options and that the private savings from cost-effective increases in energy efficiency can exceed the value of reduced externalities.
53.
Zurück zum Zitat Allcott H, Wozny N. Gasoline prices, fuel economy and the energy paradox. Rev Econ Stat. 2014;XCVI(5):779–95. Allcott H, Wozny N. Gasoline prices, fuel economy and the energy paradox. Rev Econ Stat. 2014;XCVI(5):779–95.
54.
Zurück zum Zitat Anderson ST, Kellogg R, Sallee JM. What do consumers believe about future gasoline prices? J Environ Econ Manag. 2013;66(3):383–403. Anderson ST, Kellogg R, Sallee JM. What do consumers believe about future gasoline prices? J Environ Econ Manag. 2013;66(3):383–403.
55.
Zurück zum Zitat Sallee JM, West SE, Fan W. Do consumers recognize the value of fuel economy? Evidence from used car prices and gasoline price fluctuations. J Public Econ. 2016;135:61–73. Sallee JM, West SE, Fan W. Do consumers recognize the value of fuel economy? Evidence from used car prices and gasoline price fluctuations. J Public Econ. 2016;135:61–73.
56.
Zurück zum Zitat U.S. Department of Transportation, National Highway Traffic Safety Administration (USDOT NHTSA). Vehicle survivability and travel mileage schedules, Technical Report DOT HS 809 952, National Center for Statistics and Analysis, U.S. Department of Transportation, 2006. U.S. Department of Transportation, National Highway Traffic Safety Administration (USDOT NHTSA). Vehicle survivability and travel mileage schedules, Technical Report DOT HS 809 952, National Center for Statistics and Analysis, U.S. Department of Transportation, 2006.
57.
Zurück zum Zitat Busse MR, Knittel CR, Zettelmeyer F. Are consumers myopic? Evidence from new and used car purchases. Am Econ Rev. 2013;103(1):220–56. Busse MR, Knittel CR, Zettelmeyer F. Are consumers myopic? Evidence from new and used car purchases. Am Econ Rev. 2013;103(1):220–56.
58.
Zurück zum Zitat Bento AM, Roth K, Zuo Y. Vehicle lifetime trends and scrappage behavior in the U.S. Used Car Market, UCLA. 2016, available at file:///C:/Users/HP%20USER/Desktop/Reviews/BentoetalFuelEconScrappage_18Jan2016.pdf. Bento AM, Roth K, Zuo Y. Vehicle lifetime trends and scrappage behavior in the U.S. Used Car Market, UCLA. 2016, available at file:///C:/Users/HP%20USER/Desktop/Reviews/BentoetalFuelEconScrappage_18Jan2016.pdf.
59.
Zurück zum Zitat Leard B, Linn J, Zhou YC. How much do consumers value fuel economy and performance?, RFF report. Washington, D.C., June: Resources for the Future; 2017. Leard B, Linn J, Zhou YC. How much do consumers value fuel economy and performance?, RFF report. Washington, D.C., June: Resources for the Future; 2017.
60.
Zurück zum Zitat Pagerit S, Sharer P, Rousseau A. Fuel economy sensitivity to vehicle mass for advanced vehicle powertrains. Warrendale, PA: SAE-2006-01-0665, Society of Automotive Engineers; 2006. Pagerit S, Sharer P, Rousseau A. Fuel economy sensitivity to vehicle mass for advanced vehicle powertrains. Warrendale, PA: SAE-2006-01-0665, Society of Automotive Engineers; 2006.
61.
Zurück zum Zitat Knittel CR. Automobiles on steroids: product attribute trade-offs and technological progress in the automobile sector. Am Econ Rev. 2012;101:3368–99. Knittel CR. Automobiles on steroids: product attribute trade-offs and technological progress in the automobile sector. Am Econ Rev. 2012;101:3368–99.
62.
Zurück zum Zitat Larrick RP, Soll JB. The MPG illusion. Science. 2008;320:1593–4. Larrick RP, Soll JB. The MPG illusion. Science. 2008;320:1593–4.
63.
Zurück zum Zitat Schoemaker PJH. The expected utility model: its variants, purposes, evidence and limitations. J Econ Literature. 1982;XX:529–63. Schoemaker PJH. The expected utility model: its variants, purposes, evidence and limitations. J Econ Literature. 1982;XX:529–63.
64.
Zurück zum Zitat Katsikopolous KV. Bounded rationality: the two cultures. J Econ Methodol. 2014;21(4):361–74. Katsikopolous KV. Bounded rationality: the two cultures. J Econ Methodol. 2014;21(4):361–74.
65.
Zurück zum Zitat Bernartzi S, Thaler R. Myopic loss aversion and the equity premium puzzle. Q J Econ. 1995;110:73–92.MATH Bernartzi S, Thaler R. Myopic loss aversion and the equity premium puzzle. Q J Econ. 1995;110:73–92.MATH
66.
Zurück zum Zitat Rabin M. Risk aversion and expected utility theory: a calibration theorem. Econometrica. 2003;68:1281–92. Rabin M. Risk aversion and expected utility theory: a calibration theorem. Econometrica. 2003;68:1281–92.
67.
Zurück zum Zitat Varian H. Microeconomic analysis. New York: W.W. Norton & Co., Inc.; 1992. Varian H. Microeconomic analysis. New York: W.W. Norton & Co., Inc.; 1992.
68.
Zurück zum Zitat Wali B, Greene DL, Khattak AJ, Liu J. Analyzing within garage fuel economy gaps to support vehicle purchasing decisions–a copula-based modeling & forecasting approach. Transp Res D. 2018;63:186–208. Wali B, Greene DL, Khattak AJ, Liu J. Analyzing within garage fuel economy gaps to support vehicle purchasing decisions–a copula-based modeling & forecasting approach. Transp Res D. 2018;63:186–208.
70.
71.
Zurück zum Zitat Davis SC, Williams SE, Boundy RG. Transportation energy data book: edition 36. ORNL/TM-2017/513-R2. Oak Ridge, TN: Oak Ridge National Laboratory; 2018. Available at https://cta.ornl.gov/ as of August 2018 Davis SC, Williams SE, Boundy RG. Transportation energy data book: edition 36. ORNL/TM-2017/513-R2. Oak Ridge, TN: Oak Ridge National Laboratory; 2018. Available at https://​cta.​ornl.​gov/​ as of August 2018
72.
Zurück zum Zitat U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (USEPA). Light-duty automotive technology, Carbon Dioxide Emissions, and Fuel Economy Trends: 1975 Through 2017, EPA-420-R-18-001, Ch. 5, section B, pp. 57-59, EPA-420-R-18-001, 2017. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (USEPA). Light-duty automotive technology, Carbon Dioxide Emissions, and Fuel Economy Trends: 1975 Through 2017, EPA-420-R-18-001, Ch. 5, section B, pp. 57-59, EPA-420-R-18-001, 2017.
75.
Zurück zum Zitat Tsvetanov T, Segerson K. Re-evaluating the role of energy efficiency standards: a behavioral economics approach. J Environ Econ Manag. 2013;66:347–63. Tsvetanov T, Segerson K. Re-evaluating the role of energy efficiency standards: a behavioral economics approach. J Environ Econ Manag. 2013;66:347–63.
76.
Zurück zum Zitat Bernheim BD. The good the bad and the ugly: a unified approach to behavioral welfare economics. J Benefit-cost Anal. 2016;7(1):12–68. Bernheim BD. The good the bad and the ugly: a unified approach to behavioral welfare economics. J Benefit-cost Anal. 2016;7(1):12–68.
77.
Zurück zum Zitat Kahneman D, Sugden R. Experienced utility as a standard of policy evaluation. Environ Resour Econ. 2005;31:161–81. Kahneman D, Sugden R. Experienced utility as a standard of policy evaluation. Environ Resour Econ. 2005;31:161–81.
78.
Zurück zum Zitat Allcott H, Mullainathan S, Taubinsky D. Energy policy with externalities and internalities. J Public Econ. 2014;112:72–88. Allcott H, Mullainathan S, Taubinsky D. Energy policy with externalities and internalities. J Public Econ. 2014;112:72–88.
79.
Zurück zum Zitat Greene DL, Patterson PD, Singh M, Li J. Feebates, rebates and gas-guzzler taxes: a study of incentives for increased fuel economy. Energy Policy. 2005;33(6):721–827. Greene DL, Patterson PD, Singh M, Li J. Feebates, rebates and gas-guzzler taxes: a study of incentives for increased fuel economy. Energy Policy. 2005;33(6):721–827.
80.
Zurück zum Zitat Liu C, Greene DL, Bunch DS. Vehicle manufacturer technology adoption and pricing strategies under fuel economy/emissions standards and Feebates. Energy J. 2014;35(3):71–89. Liu C, Greene DL, Bunch DS. Vehicle manufacturer technology adoption and pricing strategies under fuel economy/emissions standards and Feebates. Energy J. 2014;35(3):71–89.
Metadaten
Titel
Implications of Behavioral Economics for the Costs and Benefits of Fuel Economy Standards
verfasst von
David L. Greene
Publikationsdatum
05.09.2019
Verlag
Springer International Publishing
Erschienen in
Current Sustainable/Renewable Energy Reports / Ausgabe 4/2019
Elektronische ISSN: 2196-3010
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s40518-019-00134-3

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 4/2019

Current Sustainable/Renewable Energy Reports 4/2019 Zur Ausgabe

Electrification (J Logan, Section Editor)

Electric Company Investments for 21st Century Electrification

Deep Decarbonization: BECCS (N Mac Dowell and P Patrizio, Section Editors)

The Value of BECCS in IAMs: a Review

Deep Decarbonization: BECCS (P Patrizio and N Mac Dowell, Section Editors)

Beyond Social Acceptability: Applying Lessons from CCS Social Science to Support Deployment of BECCS