Skip to main content

2004 | Buch | 2. Auflage

Risk-Neutral Valuation

Pricing and Hedging of Financial Derivatives

verfasst von: Nicholas H. Bingham, ScD, Rüdiger Kiesel, PhD

Verlag: Springer London

Buchreihe : Springer Finance

insite
SUCHEN

Über dieses Buch

Since its introduction in the early 1980s, the risk-neutral valuation principle has proved to be an important tool in the pricing and hedging of financial derivatives. Following the success of the first edition of ‘Risk-Neutral Valuation’, the authors have thoroughly revised the entire book, taking into account recent developments in the field, and changes in their own thinking and teaching. In particular, the chapters on Incomplete Markets and Interest Rate Theory have been updated and extended, there is a new chapter on the important and growing area of Credit Risk and, in recognition of the increasing popularity of Lévy finance, there is considerable new material on: · Infinite divisibility and Lévy processes · Lévy-based models in incomplete markets Further material such as exercises, solutions to exercises and lecture slides are also available via the web to provide additional support for lecturers.

Inhaltsverzeichnis

Frontmatter
1. Derivative Background
Abstract
The main focus of this book is the pricing of financial assets. Price formation in financial markets may be explained in an absolute manner in terms of fundamentals, as, e.g. in the so-called rational expectation model, or, more modestly, in a relative manner explaining the prices of some assets in terms of other given and observable asset prices. The second approach, which we adopt, is based on the concept of arbitrage. This remarkably simple concept is independent of beliefs and tastes (preferences) of the actors in the financial market. The basic assumption simply states that all participants in the market prefer more to less, and that any increase in consumption opportunities must somehow be paid for. Underlying all arguments is the question: Is it possible for an investor to restructure his current portfolio (the assets currently owned) in such a way that he has to pay less today for his restructured portfolio and still has the same (or a higher) return at a future date? If such an opportunity exists, the arbitrageur can consume the difference today and has gained a free lunch.
Nicholas H. Bingham, Rüdiger Kiesel
2. Probability Background
Abstract
No one can predict the future! All that can be done by way of prediction is to use what information is available as well as possible. Our task is to make the best quantitative statements we can about uncertainty — which in the financial context is usually uncertainty about the future. The basic tool to quantify uncertainty is a probability density or distribution. We will assume that most readers will be familiar with such things from an elementary course in probability and statistics; for a clear introduction see, e.g. Grimmett and Welsh (1986), or the first few chapters of Grimmett and Stirzaker (2001); Ross (1997), Resnick (2001), Durrett (1999), Ross (1997), Rosenthal (2000) are also useful.
Nicholas H. Bingham, Rüdiger Kiesel
3. Stochastic Processes in Discrete Time
Abstract
Access to full, accurate, up-to-date information is clearly essential to anyone actively engaged in financial activity or trading Indeed, information is arguably the most important determinant of success in financial life. Partly for simplicity, partly to reflect the legislation and regulations against insider trading, we shall confine ourselves to the situation where agents take decisions on the basis of information in the public domain, and available to all. We shall further assume that information once known remains known — is not forgotten — and can be accessed in real time.
Nicholas H. Bingham, Rüdiger Kiesel
4. Mathematical Finance in Discrete Time
Abstract
We will study so-called finite markets — i.e. discrete-time models of financial markets in which all relevant quantities take a finite number of values. Following the approach of Harrison and Pliska (1981) and Taqqu and Willinger (1987), it suffices, to illustrate the ideas, to work with a finite probability space (Ω, F, ), with a finite number |Ω| of points ω, each with positive probability: ℙ({ω}) > 0.
Nicholas H. Bingham, Rüdiger Kiesel
5. Stochastic Processes in Continuous Time
Abstract
The underlying set-up is as in Chapter 3: we need a complete probability space (Ω, F, ), equipped with a filtration, i.e a nondecreasing family \(\mathbb{F} = {\left( {{F_t}} \right)_{t \geqslant 0}}\) of sub-σ-fields of F: F s F t F for 0 ≤ s < t < ∞. Here, F t represents the information available at time t, and the filtration \(\mathbb{F}\) represents the information flow evolving with time.
Nicholas H. Bingham, Rüdiger Kiesel
6. Mathematical Finance in Continuous Time
Abstract
This chapter discusses the general principles of continuous-time financial market models. In the first section we use a rather general model, which will serve also as a reference in the later chapters. A thorough discussion of the benchmark multi-dimensional Black-Scholes model is the topic of the second section. We discuss the valuation of several standard and exotic contingent claims in the continuous-time Black-Scholes model in the third section. After examining the relation between continuous-time and discrete-time models we close with a discussion of futures and currency markets.
Nicholas H. Bingham, Rüdiger Kiesel
7. Incomplete Markets
Abstract
We now return to general continuous-time financial market models in the setting of §6.1, i.e. there are d + 1 primary traded assets whose price processes are given by stochastic processes S 0,..., S d , which are assumed to be adapted, right-continuous with left-limits (RCLL) and strictly positive semi-martingales on a filtered probability space (Ω, F, ℙ, F) (as usual F = (F t ) t≤T ). We assume that the market is free of arbitrage, in the sense that there exist equivalent martingale measures, but it contains non-attainable contingent claims, i.e. there are cash flows that cannot be replicated by self-financing trading strategies. In view of Theorem 6.1.5 this means that we do not have a unique equivalent martingale measure. We try to answer the obvious questions in this setting: how should we price the non-attainable contingent claims, i.e. which of the possible equivalent martingale measures should we pick for our valuation formula based on expectation, and, how can we construct hedging strategies for the non-attainable contingent claims to ‘minimize the risk? We try to answer these two questions in the general setting and then consider a prominent example of an incomplete market, a market with stochastic volatility, in more detail.
Nicholas H. Bingham, Rüdiger Kiesel
8. Interest Rate Theory
Abstract
In this chapter, we apply the techniques developed in the previous chapters to the fast-growing fixed-income securities market. We mainly focus on the continuous-time model (since the available tools from stochastic calculus allow an elegant presentation) and comment of the discrete-time analogue (Jarrow (1996) gives a splendid account of discrete-time models). As we want to develop a relative pricing theory, based on the no-arbitrage assumption, we will assume prices of some underlying objects as given. In the present context we take zero-coupon bonds as the building blocks of our theory. In doing so we face the additional modelling restriction that the value of a zero-coupon bond at time of maturity is predetermined (= 1). Furthermore, since the entirety of fixed-income securities gives rise to the term-structure of interest rates (sometimes called the yield curve), which describes the relationship between the yield-to-maturity and the maturity of a given fixed-income security, we face the further task of calibrating our model to a whole continuum of initial values (and not just to a vector of prices). A first attempt at explaining the behaviour of the yield curve is in terms of a continuum of spot rates of maturities between τ and T, where τ is the shortest (instantaneous) lending/borrowing period, and T the longest maturity of interest. We model these rates as correlated stochastic variables with the degree of correlation decreasing in terms of the difference in maturity. Discretizing the maturity spectrum, we are tempted to start with a generalized Black-Scholes model (as in §6.2)
$$d{r_i}\left( t \right) = {a_i}\left( t \right) + \sum\limits_{j = 1}^d {{b_{ij}}} \left( t \right)d{W_j}\left( t \right),\;i = 1, \ldots ,\;d $$
with W = (W11..., W d) a standard d-dimensional Brownian motion. The degree of (instantaneous) correlation of the different rates can then be described in terms of their covariationt
$$d\langle {r_{i,}}{r_j}\rangle (t) = \sum\limits_{k = 1}^d {{b_{ik}}(t)dt = {\rho _{ij}}} (t)dt.$$
.
Nicholas H. Bingham, Rüdiger Kiesel
9. Credit Risk
Abstract
Approaches to modelling financial assets subject to credit risk can roughly be divided into two types of models: reduced-form and structural models.
Nicholas H. Bingham, Rüdiger Kiesel
Backmatter
Metadaten
Titel
Risk-Neutral Valuation
verfasst von
Nicholas H. Bingham, ScD
Rüdiger Kiesel, PhD
Copyright-Jahr
2004
Verlag
Springer London
Electronic ISBN
978-1-4471-3856-3
Print ISBN
978-1-84996-873-7
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4471-3856-3