Skip to main content

2021 | OriginalPaper | Buchkapitel

5. Currency War

verfasst von : Teoman M. Hagemeyer-Witzleb

Erschienen in: The International Law of Economic Warfare

Verlag: Springer International Publishing

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This chapter focusses on currency war, which is exemplified in a case study on the alleged undervaluation of the Renminbi by China. Currency undervaluation could have effects tantamount to a combination of an import tariff and an export subvention. Instruments of international law discussed in this chapter include the GATT, the Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures and the Articles of Agreement of the International Monetary Fund. In addition, the rules for countermeasures and retorsions are reviewed for their impact on currency war.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
The terms will be used interchangeably. The term “currency war” is credited to Brazil’s former finance minister Guido Mantega, see The Economist (2018w), p. 14; Bergsten and Gagnon (2017), p. 10; Lastra (2015), paras 2.35 (fn. 33) and 14.202 (fn. 262); examples for the use of financial war can be found here: Rickards (2011), p. 17; Zarate (2013b).
 
2
For instance Bracken (2007), p. 689; Katz (2013), p. 79 (emphasis added): “Accordingly, economic warfare is circumscribed to attacks on the enemy’s ability to produce and distribute goods and services; financial warfare is confined to attacks on the credit and monetary foundations that underlie production and distribution”.
 
3
Cf. The CORE Team (2017), pp. 410, 679; Krugman and Obstfeld (2016), pp. 375–377; on a legal definition of money Mann (1982), pp. 3–28.
 
4
Society for Worldwide Interbank Financial Telecommunication (2018), p. 29. By comparison, the Chinese renminbi only accounted for 0.98 percent.
 
5
Bhala (2013a), pp. 137–138.
 
6
See, for example, Katz (2013) and Zarate (2013a).
 
7
Katz (2013), p. 77.
 
8
Katz (2013), p. 79.
 
9
For instance, the increase of United States tariffs on Turkish steel and aluminum in August 2018 had a massive impact on the (already dwindling) Turkish lira, but was not effected by means of financial warfare (see The Economist 2018f); it would thus qualify as measure of trade war within this work.
 
10
Kirshner (1995). A narrower concept of currency war, viz. “when countries seek an advantage in international trade by positioning their currencies at a lower level than justified by fundamental economic forces and market outcomes […] by directly weakening their currencies through […] devaluation […] or depreciation […] [or] competitive nonappreciation.” (Bergsten and Gagnon 2017, p. 2) is not pursued here. It is too narrow in the present context due to its link to trade and the small number of means captured by it.
 
11
Kirshner (1995), pp. 8–18.
 
12
Monetary dependence refers to the creation of currency zones, areas, or blocs, which not only insulate its members but also lead to a dominance of certain, powerful members over others (for instance, the Sterling system, perhaps even the euro area); systemic disruptions do not aim to inflict harm on a currency but on its underlying system, for instance by destroying it (for instance, France’s attack on the Gold-Exchange Standard during 1927 to 1931), see in detail Kirshner (1995), pp. 115 et seqq., 170 et seqq.
 
13
Kirshner (1995), pp. 46–48.
 
14
Kirshner (1995), pp. 46, 265.
 
15
Kirshner (1995), pp. 266–267.
 
16
Historically, for instance the British pound sterling or French franc during colonial times; at the time of publication, the United States dollar (Kirshner 1995, pp. 263–264). Today, the euro could probably be added to the list.
 
17
McDougal and Feliciano (1958), p. 794. On the effects of deflating or overvaluing a currency see Zimmermann (2011a), p. 438. For a history of currency war see Bergsten and Gagnon (2017), pp. 3–10.
 
18
The CORE Team (2017), pp. 684–687; cf. Lastra (2017b), p. 550.
 
19
Cf. the overview at The CORE Team (2017), p. 685; Lastra (2017b), pp. 549–550 (also on other central bank functions).
 
20
Rickards (2011), p. 135 calls quantitative easing “the perfect currency war weapon”. For a different view see Bergsten and Gagnon (2017), pp. 11, 34–35, who argue that quantitative easing has little or no effect on the current accounts of states with high capital mobility. Thereby lacking a link to international trade, the policy is beyond their concept of currency war (fn. 10 above).
 
21
In addition, the example leads to hitherto neglected instruments of international law regarding international monetary law whereas discussion of other cases such as the Argentine debt crisis would reopen the discussion of BITs and their (security) exceptions (see Kämmerer 2018, para. 11).
 
22
Boughton (2000), pp. 16–20; Kirshner (1995), pp. 63–82 (for a comprehensive study of historical examples see pp. 51 et seqq.); Bracken (2007), pp. 689–690 and Bhala (2013a), para. 7-18 (both with additional examples); Katz (2013), pp. 78–79, who also explains that the United States viewed British withdrawal necessary to be able to credibly oppose the Soviet intervention in the Hungarian Revolution of 1956. In 2019, the United States also accused the European Central Bank of currency manipulation (see The Economist 2019a).
 
23
Cf. Bracken (2007), p. 689; for a history of currency wars see Bergsten and Gagnon (2017), pp. 3–8; Rickards (2011), pp. 37–142.
 
24
Buchheit (1974), p. 1008.
 
25
Posner and Sykes (2013), p. 325.
 
26
Herrmann (2010b), p. 40; for an explanation of the underlying (technical) economic aspects of currency war see Bergsten and Gagnon (2017), pp. 17–46.
 
27
Staiger and Sykes (2010), p. 589.
 
28
 Art. IV, Sec. 2 (b) IMF Statute; the text was changed by International Monetary Fund (1978); see International Monetary Fund (2006), pp. 4–7, 21; Herrmann (2010b), p. 40; Viterbo (2012), p. 291.
 
29
SDR are international reserve assets which can potentially be exchanged for (convertible) currencies of IMF member states. They were created in 1969 by the IMF in order to supplement the official reserves of its member states. As of 2 January 2020, the value of the SDR is determined by the British pound sterling, the Chinese renminbi, the euro, the Japanese Yen, and the United States dollar. See in detail International Monetary Fund (2005), pp. 99–100 (para. 440) and International Monetary Fund (2020).
 
30
Posner and Sykes (2013), p. 313.
 
31
Posner and Sykes (2013), p. 314.
 
32
International Monetary Fund (2019), pp. 4–5.
 
33
Herdegen (2016), p. 504.
 
34
International Monetary Fund (2019), pp. 4–8.
 
35
Bergsten and Gagnon (2017), pp. 8–10, 70–76 (also on other “currency aggressors”); Mattoo and Subramanian (2008), pp. 3–5; Hufbauer et al. (2006), pp. 16–17. For comprehensive references see Goldstein and Lardy (2008), p. 38. Cf. also Krugman (2010); with a balanced account of the United States-Chinese (“Chimerican”) interdependence Ferguson (2009), pp. 335–337. Summary and references to critics: Staiger and Sykes (2010), p. 589.
 
36
While referred to as renminbi in China, international custom refers to the currency as (Chinese) yuan. This denomination is ambiguous since yuan is also the currency’s primary unit.
 
37
International Monetary Fund (2019), p. 6. On earlier arrangements see Bhala (2013a), paras 7-007–7-009, 7-012–7-018; Mercurio and Leung (2009), pp. 1260–1262.
 
38
Morrison (2016), p. 1; on the history of Chinese currency policy briefly Herrmann (2010b), pp. 32–33.
 
39
See Yahoo Finance (2021f). On 5 August 2019, the currency weakened beyond seven CNY per USD for the first time since 2008 due to a decision by the Chinese central bank, which is read by some to be a reaction to the tariffs imposed by the United States (The Economist 2019b, p. 53). For a brief overview of the historical development see Krugman and Obstfeld (2016), pp. 732–734; Morrison (2016), p. 1.
 
40
Ferguson (2009), p. 335; Mercurio and Leung (2009), pp. 1262–1263; Posner and Sykes (2013), p. 321; Morrison (2016), p. 2. Some authors estimate that China spent USD 4 trillion between 2003 and 2013 to prevent its currency from appreciating, averaging around USD 2 billion per day in the peak year 2007 (Bergsten and Gagnon 2017, p. 75). If market valuation of the renminbi is above the peg, the currency comes under appreciation pressure which the central bank has to contravene by selling renminbi for foreign currency; vice versa, the central bank has to buy renminbi with foreign currency to avoid its depreciation in case of a market valuation below the peg.
 
41
The Economist (2018v); Mercurio and Leung (2009), p. 1268.
 
42
Krugman and Obstfeld (2016), p. 732.
 
43
Blustein (2019), p. 92; Krugman and Obstfeld (2016), p. 732; Herrmann (2010b), pp. 32–33.
 
44
Krugman (2015); Mitchell and Donnan (2015); for an earlier observation cf. Bhala (2013a), para. 7-65. For a different view cf. Bergsten and Gagnon (2017), p. 75.
 
45
For some time during the 2000s, it seemed as though China “owned” the United States because China was running a significant current account surplus while the United States ran an equally impressive current account deficit (Herrmann 2010b, pp. 31–32). In other words, the (on average much poorer) Chinese citizen loaned money to the (on average far richer) American citizen. For some time, this was a comfortable arrangement, with the United States being able to finance itself by selling bonds to the Chinese central bank at interest low rates and profiting from cheap imports. See in detail Ferguson (2009), pp. 333–341.
 
46
Overview by Bacchus and Shapiro (2007); see also Krugman (2010); Gadbaw (2017b), p. 555; Ciobanasu and Denters (2008), pp. 68–69; Viterbo (2012), pp. 308, 311–314; and Mercurio and Leung (2009), p. 1259 for further references.
 
47
Cf. Herrmann (2010b), p. 35.
 
48
Staiger and Sykes (2010), pp. 604, 624–626; inclined to agree is Zimmermann (2011a), p. 439.
 
49
To reach these conclusions, Staiger and Sykes (2010), pp. 594–599, 601–605, 620–627 asked a simple question: Which (combination of) trade policies (potentially illegal under WTO law) bear equivalent effects as does the monetary policy of restraining the renminbi from appreciating (although, for the sake of simplicity, the authors assumed that the Chinese central bank was even depreciating the renminbi)? Assuming flexible prices, i.e. the adjustment of prices in the long run, Staiger and Sykes found no real effects of a devaluation of the renminbi in terms of Chinese exports or imports. If prices are flexible, as they are commonly assumed to be in the long run, currency devaluation is nothing more than a change of the measuring unit: Goods formerly costing CNY 1 now cost CNY 10 and USD 1 (assuming its price was CNY 1 before the devaluation) now costs CNY 10. In other words, measurement now is taken in millimeters instead of centimeters. However, the relative prices, for instance the value of one Chinese car against one United States car (i.e. the terms of trade between China and the United States), remain unchanged by such devaluation, so that currency devaluation has no real effect assuming flexible prices (i.e. in the analogy the actual distance measured stays constant). The equivalent of a currency devaluation—which is a uniform, unexpected, permanent ad valorem export subsidy on all export goods in conjunction with an import tariff on all import goods—also has no real effect on the terms of trade because the effects of the export subsidy (drawing resources to the export sector) is entirely offset by the import tariff (drawing resources to the import sector). Only by looking at either the effects of the export subsidy or the import tariff (and not the combination thereof, which is in fact the (only real) equivalent to currency devaluation) can popular opinion maintain its allegations against China. Thus, reason Staiger and Sykes, popular opinion is in error in at least two regards: First, one cannot view currency devaluation only as export subsidy or only as import tariff, but only as a combination thereof. Second, one cannot react to currency devaluation in form of countervailing duties and tariffs as one would react to each of these equivalent policy measures as if they came without the other. This would ignore the fact that only in combination they form the equivalent of a currency devaluation, i.e. that only in combination would an export subsidy and an import tariff cause real effects on the terms of trade. Since the assumption of flexible prices is doubtful in the short run (and governments engaging in monetary intervention seem to believe that their actions have some effect), Staiger and Sykes also conduct their analysis based on the assumption of sticky (that is fixed) prices. In this analysis, the outcome is heavily dependent on whether exporters price their goods in their own, domestic currency (“producer currency pricing”), in the buyer’s currency (“local currency pricing”), or in a third state vehicle currency (“dollar pricing”). In the first case, currency depreciation would make imports for Chinese producers more expensive and Chinese export goods would become cheaper (in line with the arguments of the critics of Chinese currency policy); the effect is not that of an export subsidy, however, because the price of the “subsidized” goods remains the same in China and in the United States (by contrast, an export subsidy would only make the good cheaper on the United States market, to which it is exported) and because China’s terms of trade would deteriorate. In the third case, it is obvious that an appreciation of the renminbi would have no bearing on Chinese exports because they are priced in the (unchanged) vehicle currency. While currency devaluation has no effects on relative prices and the terms of trade in the first and the third case, it does impose change under the assumption of local currency pricing: Chinese exporters receive more renminbi (for the USD they take in) while United States exporters can exchange the fixed renminbi prices they receive for less USD at home. The trade policy equivalent is an import tariff. It is questionable whether the local currency pricing assumption (i.e. Chinese exporters denominating their prices in USD, United States exporters denominating theirs in CNY) is realistic and—if it is—whether it could be proven before an international adjudicative body, such as the WTO dispute settlement system.
 
50
Staiger and Sykes (2010), pp. 594–595.
 
51
Questions of international investment law will not be addressed here as they were subject to Sect. 4.​3 above. In this regard, see Jennings et al. (1992b), p. 916 (para. 407) (fn. 14) summarizing that states have not been found responsible for indiscriminatory currency devaluations and Kämmerer (2018), paras 11–18.
 
52
Bergsten and Gagnon (2017), pp. 130–131; Staiger and Sykes (2010), pp. 606, 612; Viterbo (2012), pp. 304–307.
 
53
PCIJ (12 July 1929) Case Concerning the Payment of Various Serbian Loans Issued in France, Judgement, Publications of the PCIJ, Series A. - No. 20/21, para. 96; Mann (1982), p. 465; Herrmann (2010b), pp. 38–40; Mercurio and Leung (2009), p. 1268; Lastra (2017a), p. 548; on the concept of monetary sovereignty in extenso Zimmermann (2013).
 
54
Herrmann (2010b), p. 39; see similarly Mercurio and Leung (2009), pp. 1269–1270.
 
55
Viterbo (2012), p. 290; Mann (1982), p. 465: “depreciate or appreciate its value”.
 
56
On other, rather quixotic attempts to construe a breach of GATT obligations via a non-violation complaint or on the basis of the national treatment provision of Art. III GATT see Staiger and Sykes (2010), p. 606 (fn. 47).
 
57
Cf. Posner and Sykes (2013), p. 321; for a discussion of a violation of the Antidumping Agreement see Viterbo (2012), pp. 313–314; Zimmermann (2011a), p. 457 (who both reject a violation).
 
58
Cf. Hufbauer et al. (2006), pp. 17–19 (also noting that the GATS holds no comparable provision); Gadbaw (2017b), p. 555.
 
59
Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures - ASCM - 1869 U.N.T.S. 14.
 
60
Adamantopoulos (2010), para. 28.
 
61
Appellate Body (16 January 2003 (adopted 27 January 2003)) United States - Continued Dumping and Subsidy Offset Act of 2000, Report of the Appellate Body, WT/DS217/AB/R, WT/DS234/AB/R, para. 269.
 
62
Cf. Tietje (2015a), para. 163.
 
63
Bhala (2013a), para. 22-007.
 
64
World Trade Organization (1995), p. 78.
 
65
Panel (26 November 2004 (adopted 19 May 2005)) Dominican Republic — Import and Sale of Cigarettes, Report of the Panel, WT/DS302/R, para. 7.114; Bhala (2013a), para. 22-008.
 
66
Panel (26 November 2004 (adopted 19 May 2005)) Dominican Republic — Import and Sale of Cigarettes, Report of the Panel, WT/DS302/R, para. 7.113 (emphasis added).
 
67
Currency undervaluation is clearly neither “an ordinary customs duty, nor a tax or duty” in the sense of Art. II:2 GATT.
 
68
World Trade Organization (1995), pp. 78–82; Bhala (2013a), para. 22-008.
 
69
Bhala (2013a), para. 22-009. On a final note, one may argue—at least in the Chinese case—that when China joined the WTO in 2001, it already entertained its (undervalued) peg to the USD so that it did not levy other duties or charges in excess of those imposed on the date of its accession to the GATT (cf. Art. II (1) (b) GATT; for the interpretation of the provision regarding subsequent member states see Jackson 1997, p. 209).
 
70
This paragraph draws on Herrmann (2010b), pp. 48–49; Zimmermann (2011a), pp. 443–455 with comprehensive references in fn. 103 and 104; Staiger and Sykes (2010), pp. 609–611; Mercurio and Leung (2009), pp. 1293–1298; Bhala (2013a), paras 7-039–7-045.
 
71
Fn. omitted.
 
72
Bhala (2013b), para. 75-033 (Table 75-1) gives an overview of the traffic light system of the ASCM.
 
73
Although not a constituent element of subsidy, see Wouters and Coppens (2009), p. 28.
 
74
Cf. Wouters and Coppens (2009), pp. 33–34. Whether this is the case depends on whether the subsidy is contingent upon export (performance); it could be argued that undervalued currency de facto benefits mainly the export sector; however, a different line of argument negates contingency upon export performance due to the fact that all holders of foreign currency (and not only exporters) benefit from the undervalued local currency, see Hufbauer et al. (2006), pp. 22–23; Mercurio and Leung (2009), pp. 1297–1298; for a different view see Viterbo (2012), p. 313. If one were to follow this latter line of argument, specificity would have to be determined (cf. fn. 76 below).
 
75
An income or price support in the sense of Art. XVI GATT will be neglected here for it is obviously not given (Mercurio and Leung 2009, p. 1294; for a full discussion see Zimmermann 2011a, pp. 448–449).
 
76
If one were to categorize undervalued currency as yellow light subsidy under Art. 5 to 6 ASCM, specificity would also stand to question (in this direction Mercurio and Leung 2009, pp. 1296–1297; against specificity Viterbo 2012, p. 313; also for red light subsidies Zimmermann 2011a, p. 447, which is probably misleading, cf. Bhala 2013a, para. 7-040 (fn. 82)).
 
77
Cf. Zimmermann (2011a), pp. 447–448; Viterbo (2012), p. 312. It is not immediately apparent to be either “a [potential] direct transfer of funds”; or “government revenue […] foregone or not collected”; or the provision of goods or services or purchase of goods by the government (Art. 1.1 (a) (1) (i) to (iii) ASCM). An argument could potentially be made that the government foregoes tariff revenue by making imports more expensive (if demand for such imports is elastic and thus declines) or that the entity engaging in currency market intervention (to devalue the currency) directly transfers funds (cf. Staiger and Sykes 2010, p. 610). Although neither of these potential benefits are directed at the exporters, this does not seem to be of import for finding a “financial contribution”, which—in contrast to the benefit, which looks at the recipient side—takes into its view only the government side (Wouters and Coppens 2009, p. 26). Arguing against a financial contribution in this sense are Zimmermann (2011a), pp. 448–449 and Mercurio and Leung (2009), pp. 1294–1295; arguing against Zimmermann is Bhala (2013a), paras 7-040–7-041.
 
78
Wouters and Coppens (2009), p. 15; Adamantopoulos (2008), para. 11; Panel (29 June 2001 (adopted 23 August 2001)) United States — Measures Treating Export Restraints as Subsidies, Report of the Panel, WT/DS194/R, para. 8.69 (unappealed); cf. Zimmermann (2011a), p. 447 (fn. 112) with further references.
 
79
Wouters and Coppens (2009), pp. 25–26; cf. Appellate Body (2 August 1999 (adopted 20 August 1999)) Canada — Measures Affecting the Export of Civilian Aircraft, Report of the Appellate Body, WT/DS70/AB/R, para. 158.
 
80
Appellate Body (2 August 1999 (adopted 20 August 1999)) Canada — Measures Affecting the Export of Civilian Aircraft, Report of the Appellate Body, WT/DS70/AB/R, para. 157 (emphasis added).
 
81
Staiger and Sykes (2010), p. 611; in opposition to a benefit also: Viterbo (2012), p. 312.
 
82
Zimmermann (2011a), p. 450; Mercurio and Leung (2009), p. 1296; Bhala (2013a), para. 7-41.
 
83
Hufbauer et al. (2006), p. 21; Bhala (2013a), para. 7-42; Mercurio and Leung (2009), p. 1296.
 
84
Zimmermann (2011a), pp. 450–451.
 
85
Herrmann (2010b), p. 49; see also Bown and Hillman (2019), pp. 569–570.
 
86
In accordance with Art. 1 (1) DSU, cf. Ciobanasu and Denters (2008), p. 65; van den Bossche and Zdouc (2017), p. 170. For an overview of possible multilateral and unilateral consequences see Staiger and Sykes (2010), pp. 606–616.
 
87
Art. 23 (1) DSU; Steinmann (2006), para. 6; van den Bossche and Zdouc (2017), p. 169; Hahn (1996), p. 283; also on GATT 1947 see Mavroidis (2008), pp. 404, 398–402.
 
88
Cf. Ciobanasu and Denters (2008), p. 65. For a discussion of antidumping duties see Staiger and Sykes (2010), pp. 614–616.
 
89
Cf. Bhala (2013a), para. 7-30.
 
90
Ad Article XV (following the asterisk) provides (emphasis added, also in the main quote): “The word ‘frustrate’ is intended to indicate, for example, that infringements of the letter of any Article of this Agreement by exchange action shall not be regarded as a violation of that Article if, in practice, there is no appreciable departure from the intent of the Article. Thus, a contracting party which, as part of its exchange control operated in accordance with the Articles of Agreement of the International Monetary Fund, requires payment to be received for its exports in its own currency or in the currency of one or more members of the International Monetary Fund will not thereby be deemed to contravene Article XI or Article XIII. Another example would be that of a contracting party which specifies on an import licence the country from which the goods may be imported, for the purpose not of introducing any additional element of discrimination in its import licensing system but of enforcing permissible exchange controls”.
 
91
For a discussion of other legal issues and ambiguities relating to Art. XV GATT see Zimmermann (2011a), pp. 460–472; Gadbaw (2017b), pp. 555–556; Viterbo (2012), pp. 308–314.
 
92
Herrmann (2010b), pp. 46–47; for a different view see Mercurio and Leung (2009), pp. 1285–1286. In addition, the drafters assumed the original Bretton Woods exchange rate system and IMF jurisdiction over exchange rates, both of which are no longer in place, cf. Lastra (2015), para. 14.202 (fn. 262). Gadbaw (2017b), p. 555 and Viterbo (2012), p. 309 submit that Art. XV:9 GATT would also have to be considered.
 
93
Bhala (2013a), para. 7-32. It should be noted that some authors argue—based on the wording of its Ad Article—that Art. XV (4) GATT demands a specific GATT provision to be frustrated (and not the GATT’s general purpose), see Hufbauer et al. (2006), p. 19.
 
94
GATT Preamble para. 2; Mercurio and Leung (2009), pp. 1288–1290; similarly Hufbauer et al. (2006), p. 18.
 
95
Ciobanasu and Denters (2008), p. 67.
 
96
Mercurio and Leung (2009), p. 1287.
 
97
Bhala (2013a), para. 7-31; Staiger and Sykes (2010), pp. 607–608 find the reading most probable under which “frustration” requires a violation of the IMF Statute.
 
98
Viterbo (2012), p. 310.
 
99
Mercurio and Leung (2009), p. 1290; Staiger and Sykes (2010), p. 608; Lastra (2015), para. 14.202 (fn. 262); Gadbaw (2017b), p. 556; Herrmann (2010b), p. 48; inconclusive Ciobanasu and Denters (2008), pp. 68, 70.
 
100
Lastra (2015), para. 13.05.
 
101
Funk (2018), pp. 265–266; Herrmann (2010b), p. 41.
 
102
Cf. Zimmermann (2011a), p. 428; Posner and Sykes (2013), p. 314.
 
103
Art. IV, Sec. 1 (iii) IMF Statute (emphasis added).
 
104
Staiger and Sykes (2010), p. 589; Herrmann (2010b), p. 41.
 
105
International Monetary Fund Executive Board (2007), Annex, Art. IV, Sec. 1 (iii) and Principle A, para. 1. On the history of this decision Herrmann (2010b), pp. 42–43; Zimmermann (2011a), pp. 430–437.
 
106
Zimmermann (2011a), p. 430.
 
107
International Monetary Fund Executive Board (2007), Annex, Art. IV, Sec. 1 (iii) and Principle A, para. 2 (emphasis added).
 
108
International Monetary Fund (2007b); in detail Zimmermann (2011a), pp. 435–436.
 
109
Goldstein and Lardy (2008), pp. 17–18; Staiger and Sykes (2010), p. 614 and Zimmermann (2011a), p. 440 (in the context of export subsidies). On the differing opinions Hufbauer et al. (2006), p. 25 and Viterbo (2012), p. 296 (fn. 22).
 
110
International Monetary Fund Executive Board (2007), Annex, Art. IV, Sec. 1 (iii) and Principle A, para. 3.
 
111
International Monetary Fund Executive Board (2007), Annex, Art. IV, Sec. 1 (iii) and Principle A, para. 3: “Any representation made by the member regarding the purpose of its policies will be given the benefit of any reasonable doubt.” See also Viterbo (2012), pp. 296–297.
 
112
Cf. Mussa (2008), pp. 292–295; for comprehensive references cf. Goldstein and Lardy (2008), p. 39; for a different view Bergsten and Gagnon (2017), p. 138.
 
113
In detail Blustein (2019), pp. 89–110; see also Bhala (2013a), para. 7-19; Hufbauer et al. (2006), p. 26.
 
114
This paragraph draws on Herrmann (2010b), pp. 44–45; Viterbo (2012), pp. 299–301; and Staiger and Sykes (2010), pp. 592–593.
 
115
Zimmermann (2011a), p. 433; Bhala (2013a), paras 7-028–7-029.
 
116
Chwieroth (2010), pp. 241–242.
 
117
On the IMF’s practice Mussa (2008), pp. 287–292; on bilateral surveillance in general Mercurio and Leung (2009), pp. 1274–1275. Quite telling is Gadbaw’s remark (Gadbaw 2017a, p. 554 (emphasis added)): “In practice, the [IMF] has treated these guidelines less as rules than as topics of conversation […]”.
 
118
Zimmermann (2011a), p. 426.
 
119
Zimmermann (2011a), pp. 432–433; Bhala (2013a), para. 7-29.
 
120
Mattoo and Subramanian (2008), pp. 6–9; Gadbaw (2017a), p. 554; Bergsten and Gagnon (2017), pp. 138–139; Zimmermann (2011a), p. 437; Herrmann (2010b), pp. 44–45; Staiger and Sykes (2010), p. 593; Ciobanasu and Denters (2008), p. 58; Viterbo (2012), p. 315; Blustein (2019), pp. 101, 110; Bhala (2013a), paras 7-028–7-029; for the difficulties in determining even an undervaluation cf. Goldstein and Lardy (2008), pp. 18–19. Affirming manipulation by China are Mercurio and Leung (2009), p. 1278 (see, however, p. 1283 on intent).
 
121
Especially the legislative organs of the United States considered their options, see Viterbo (2012), pp. 304–307 (also with reference to the bills introduced, some of which drew on the security exception in Art. XXI GATT) and the references in fn. 52 above. In context of the 2019 weakening of the CNY vis-à-vis the USD (fn. 39 above), the United States administration called upon the (independent) Federal Reserve, the state’s central bank, to react (The Economist 2019b, p. 55).
 
122
See Schachter (1991), p. 184.
 
123
Shaw (2017), p. 589 with further references in fn. 1.
 
124
Peters (2016), pp. 373–374 (paras 33–37); Malanczuk (1997), pp. 270–271.
 
125
Schröder (2016), pp. 546–547 (para. 7) (the Draft Articles also contain provisions not reflecting customary international law); Hahn (1996), p. 47 (with further references in fn. 110).
 
126
PCIJ (13 September 1928) Case Concerning The Factory at Chorzów (Claim for Indemnity), Merits, Publications of the PCIJ, Series A. - No. 17, p. 29.
 
127
Crawford (2013), pp. 598 et seqq.
 
128
Zoller (1984), pp. 75, 137 places them “within reparation and outside punishment” (critical of this placing is Noortmann 2005, p. 36); see also Peters (2016), p. 375 (para. 39); Crawford (2013), pp. 675 et seqq.; Cassese (2005), p. 302.
 
129
Crawford (2013), pp. 684–686.
 
130
Schachter (1991), p. 185; Crawford (2013), p. 675; Giegerich (2018c), para. 5.
 
131
Cf. Joyner (2016), pp. 200–201.
 
132
Peters (2016), p. 376 (para. 43); Schachter (1991), p. 185; Kißler (1984), pp. 90, 92.
 
133
Cf. Blustein (2019), p. 95.
 
134
Overview: International Law Commission (2001), Introduction to Chapter II of Part III, para. 6; Doehring (1994), p. 236.
 
135
Ronzitti (2016b), pp. 30–31.
 
136
Ronzitti (2016b), pp. 26–28; Paddeu (2018), pp. 10, 19–22. Dispute settlement provisions and obligations to safeguard diplomatic and consular inviolability may not be deviated from (Art. 50 (2) Draft Articles), see comprehensively Crawford (2013), pp. 688–697; Cassese (2005), pp. 303–306.
 
137
White and Abass (2014), p. 545; Paddeu (2018), paras 23–25 (who rightly points out that measures also have to be necessary; a criterion not further elaborated here).
 
138
O’Connell (2002), p. 76; taking a different view is Schachter (1991), p. 193: “[R]easonable judgements are not difficult to make in most cases.”
 
139
Franck (2008), p. 763.
 
140
Crawford (2013), pp. 697–698; slightly unclear Culot (2017), p. 345.
 
141
Art. 51 Draft Articles: “Countermeasures must be commensurate with the injury suffered, taking into account the gravity of the internationally wrongful act and the rights in question”.
 
142
Cassese (2005), pp. 305–306; White and Abass (2014), p. 546.
 
143
Crawford (2013), p. 687; Cassese (2005), p. 305; Kißler (1984), p. 92; Paddeu (2018), paras 41–42.
 
144
Kißler (1984), pp. 93–99; Schachter (1991), pp. 196–198.
 
145
Elagab (1988), pp. 215, 218–219; Hahn (1996), p. 158; see generally Noortmann (2005), pp. 131 et seqq. On the controversial notion of self-contained regimes see International Law Commission (2006), paras 123 et seqq.
 
146
Simma and Pulkowski (2006), pp. 512–529; Hahn (1996), pp. 159, 279; Bothe (2016a), p. 36; White and Abass (2014), p. 547; Crawford (2013), pp. 104–105 (also on the question on how to deal with international agreements that are “silent” on the end of the exhaustiveness of its remedies. See also Bowett (1972), pp. 10–11.
 
147
Noortmann (2005), p. 130.
 
148
Cf. Schachter (1991), pp. 188–190. Paddeu (2018), para. 37 sets up the following three cumulative conditions for an exclusion of countermeasures by pending dispute settlement procedures: “(i) the wrongful act has ceased; (ii) the dispute is pending before a court or tribunal with power to issue binding decisions on the parties, including on provisional measures; and (iii) the responsible State’s subjection of the dispute to dispute settlement is in good faith”.
 
149
Dupont (2012), pp. 332–334 and Dupont (2016), pp. 61–63 with further references.
 
150
Dupont (2012), pp. 324–325; Dupont (2016), pp. 54–55.
 
151
Cassese (2005), pp. 302–303.
 
152
Paddeu (2018), paras 29–30 (also on the exceptions in urgent cases).
 
153
For the avoidance of doubt, these are no procedural but material requirements.
 
154
Cf. White and Abass (2014), p. 546.
 
155
Tomuschat (1973), p. 184; Malanczuk (1985), p. 301; Schachter (1991), p. 185; Crawford (2013), pp. 676–677.
 
156
International Law Commission (2001), Introduction to Chapter II of Part III, para. 3: “Acts of retorsion[,] [w]hatever their motivation, so long as such acts are not incompatible with the international obligations of the States taking them towards the target State, they do not involve countermeasures and they fall outside the scope of the present articles.” See also Crawford (2002), pp. 281–282; Dupont (2012), p. 312; Noortmann (2005), p. 42; White and Abass (2014), pp. 543–544.
 
157
White and Abass (2014), p. 544.
 
158
Peters (2016), p. 376 (para. 43); Cassese (2005), p. 310; Zoller (1984), p. 135 (assuming that her concept of countermeasures also includes retorsions); unclear Tomuschat (1973), p. 183, who observes that state practice is often proportionate in the use of retorsions.
 
159
International Law Commission (2001), Introduction to Chapter II of Part III, para. 3. Cf. Malanczuk (1997), p. 271; White and Abass (2014), pp. 540, 543.
 
160
Schachter (1991), pp. 198–199; Garçon (1997), p. 211; Giegerich (2018c), para. 14; Malanczuk (1985), p. 302.
 
161
Cf. Schachter (1991), p. 186.
 
162
Noortmann (2005), pp. 44–45.
 
163
The view taken here could integrate Schachter’s argument for declaring retorsions illegal when they are taken in pursuit of “improper” or “illegal” objectives (without the dismal prospects of finding a measure for impropriety or illegality), cf. Schachter (1991), p. 199 (originally as Schachter 1982, pp. 167–187), who is supported by Noortmann (2005), pp. 43–44. Kißler (1984), p. 100 entertains similar notions regarding reprisals. Finding such standards has already proven extremely difficult (if not vain) in context of the principle of non-intervention (above Sect. 3.​4.​2.​2).
 
164
Giegerich (2018c), paras 15–27, who adds that in exceptional circumstances, the obligation of states to settle disputes peacefully (Art. 2 (3) UN Charter) may restrict retorsions; but no general subsidiarity to dispute settlement mechanisms is in force; Cassese (2005), pp. 303–305.
 
165
Noortmann (2005), p. 43 (referring to measures of self-help in general).
 
166
Cf. Ronzitti (2016b), pp. 31–32.
 
167
Joyner (2016), pp. 193–194.
 
168
Schachter (1991), p. 186 notes: “The paucity of case-law and the obscurity of State practice have contributed to the uncertainty of the law on several key issues”.
 
169
A meaningful byproduct from the currency war example in terms of strictures on economic warfare in general is the observation that, once more, a very specific measure of economic warfare—in this case subsidies—is regulated (by Art. VI GATT in conjunction with the ASCM). This coincides with the findings regarding tariffs, quantitative restrictions, and antidumping measures (above Sect. 3.​4.​4.​1).
 
170
This paradox is captured in the following quote (Elagab 1988, p. 44): “States are permitted as a form of redress to take measures that are in themselves a threat to order”.
 
171
Malanczuk (1985), p. 293.
 
172
Cf. Paddeu (2018), para. 43.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Adamantopoulos K (2008) Art. 1 SCMA. In: Wolfrum R, Stoll P-T, Koebele M (eds) WTO - trade remedies. Brill, Leiden, pp 423–452 Adamantopoulos K (2008) Art. 1 SCMA. In: Wolfrum R, Stoll P-T, Koebele M (eds) WTO - trade remedies. Brill, Leiden, pp 423–452
Zurück zum Zitat Adamantopoulos K (2010) Art. VI GATT. In: Stoll P-T, Wolfrum R, Hestermeyer H (eds) WTO - trade in goods. Brill, Leiden, pp 195–216 Adamantopoulos K (2010) Art. VI GATT. In: Stoll P-T, Wolfrum R, Hestermeyer H (eds) WTO - trade in goods. Brill, Leiden, pp 195–216
Zurück zum Zitat Bergsten CF, Gagnon JE (2017) Currency conflict and trade policy. Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington D.C. Bergsten CF, Gagnon JE (2017) Currency conflict and trade policy. Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington D.C.
Zurück zum Zitat Bhala R (2013a) Modern GATT law (vol. I): a treatise on the law and political economy of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade and other World Trade Organisation agreements, 2nd edn., I. Sweet & Maxwell, London Bhala R (2013a) Modern GATT law (vol. I): a treatise on the law and political economy of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade and other World Trade Organisation agreements, 2nd edn., I. Sweet & Maxwell, London
Zurück zum Zitat Bhala R (2013b) Modern GATT law (vol. II): a treatise on the law and political economy of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade and other World Trade Organisation agreements, 2nd edn., II. Sweet & Maxwell, London Bhala R (2013b) Modern GATT law (vol. II): a treatise on the law and political economy of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade and other World Trade Organisation agreements, 2nd edn., II. Sweet & Maxwell, London
Zurück zum Zitat Blustein P (2019) Schism: China, America and the fracturing of the global trading system. CIGI Press, WaterlooCrossRef Blustein P (2019) Schism: China, America and the fracturing of the global trading system. CIGI Press, WaterlooCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bothe M (2016a) Compatibility and legitimacy of sanctions regimes. In: Ronzitti N (ed) Coercive diplomacy, sanctions and international law. Brill, Nijhoff, Leiden, pp 33–42 Bothe M (2016a) Compatibility and legitimacy of sanctions regimes. In: Ronzitti N (ed) Coercive diplomacy, sanctions and international law. Brill, Nijhoff, Leiden, pp 33–42
Zurück zum Zitat Boughton JM (2000) Northwest of Suez: The 1956 Crisis and the IMF. IMF Working Papers, Working Paper No. 00/192. International Monetary Fund, Washington D.C Boughton JM (2000) Northwest of Suez: The 1956 Crisis and the IMF. IMF Working Papers, Working Paper No. 00/192. International Monetary Fund, Washington D.C
Zurück zum Zitat Bowett DW (1972) Economic coercion and reprisals by states. Va J Int Law 13:1–12 Bowett DW (1972) Economic coercion and reprisals by states. Va J Int Law 13:1–12
Zurück zum Zitat Cassese A (2005) International law, 2nd edn. Oxford University Press, Oxford Cassese A (2005) International law, 2nd edn. Oxford University Press, Oxford
Zurück zum Zitat Chwieroth JM (2010) Capital ideas: the IMF and the rise of financial liberalization. Princeton University Press, Princeton, Woodstock Chwieroth JM (2010) Capital ideas: the IMF and the rise of financial liberalization. Princeton University Press, Princeton, Woodstock
Zurück zum Zitat Ciobanasu IC, Denters E (2008) Manipulation of the Chinese Yuan - may WTO members respond? Griffin’s View on Int Comp Law 9:55–70 Ciobanasu IC, Denters E (2008) Manipulation of the Chinese Yuan - may WTO members respond? Griffin’s View on Int Comp Law 9:55–70
Zurück zum Zitat Crawford J (2002) The International Law Commission’s articles on state responsibility: introduction, text and commentaries. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge Crawford J (2002) The International Law Commission’s articles on state responsibility: introduction, text and commentaries. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
Zurück zum Zitat Crawford J (2013) State responsibility: the general part. Cambridge studies in international and comparative law, vol 100. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRef Crawford J (2013) State responsibility: the general part. Cambridge studies in international and comparative law, vol 100. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Culot H (2017) Unilateral sanctions in international economic law. In: Cottier T, Nadakavukaren Schefer K (eds) Elgar encyclopedia of international economic law. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, Northampton, pp 343–345 Culot H (2017) Unilateral sanctions in international economic law. In: Cottier T, Nadakavukaren Schefer K (eds) Elgar encyclopedia of international economic law. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, Northampton, pp 343–345
Zurück zum Zitat Doehring K (1994) The unilateral enforcement of international law by exercising reprisals. In: St. Macdonald RJ (ed) Essays in honour of Wang Tieya. Nijhoff, Dordrecht, pp 235–242 Doehring K (1994) The unilateral enforcement of international law by exercising reprisals. In: St. Macdonald RJ (ed) Essays in honour of Wang Tieya. Nijhoff, Dordrecht, pp 235–242
Zurück zum Zitat Dupont P-E (2016) Unilateral European sanctions as countermeasures: the case of the EU measures against Iran. In: Happold M, Eden P (eds) Economic sanctions and international law: law and practice. Hart Publishing, Oxford, Portland, Oregon, pp 37–66 Dupont P-E (2016) Unilateral European sanctions as countermeasures: the case of the EU measures against Iran. In: Happold M, Eden P (eds) Economic sanctions and international law: law and practice. Hart Publishing, Oxford, Portland, Oregon, pp 37–66
Zurück zum Zitat Elagab OY (1988) The legality of non-forcible counter measures in international law. Clarendon Press, Oxford Elagab OY (1988) The legality of non-forcible counter measures in international law. Clarendon Press, Oxford
Zurück zum Zitat Ferguson N (2009) The ascent of money. Penguin, London Ferguson N (2009) The ascent of money. Penguin, London
Zurück zum Zitat Funk JB (2018) Der Internationale Währungsfonds: Status, Funktion, Legitimation. Rechtsfragen der Globalisierung, Band 21. Duncker & Humblot, Berlin Funk JB (2018) Der Internationale Währungsfonds: Status, Funktion, Legitimation. Rechtsfragen der Globalisierung, Band 21. Duncker & Humblot, Berlin
Zurück zum Zitat Gadbaw MR (2017a) The role of the International Monetary Fund. In: Cottier T, Nadakavukaren Schefer K (eds) Elgar encyclopedia of international economic law. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, Northampton, pp 553–554 Gadbaw MR (2017a) The role of the International Monetary Fund. In: Cottier T, Nadakavukaren Schefer K (eds) Elgar encyclopedia of international economic law. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, Northampton, pp 553–554
Zurück zum Zitat Gadbaw MR (2017b) The role of the World Trade Organization in monetary affairs. In: Cottier T, Nadakavukaren Schefer K (eds) Elgar encyclopedia of international economic law. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, Northampton, pp 554–556 Gadbaw MR (2017b) The role of the World Trade Organization in monetary affairs. In: Cottier T, Nadakavukaren Schefer K (eds) Elgar encyclopedia of international economic law. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, Northampton, pp 554–556
Zurück zum Zitat Garçon G (1997) Handelsembargen der Europäischen Union auf dem Gebiet des Warenverkehrs gegenüber Drittländern: Im Lichte der Änderungen durch den Maastrichter Vertrag und des Völkerrechts. Zugl.: Saarbrücken, Univ., Diss., 1997. Saarbrücker Studien zum internationalen Recht, vol 8. Nomos, Baden-Baden Garçon G (1997) Handelsembargen der Europäischen Union auf dem Gebiet des Warenverkehrs gegenüber Drittländern: Im Lichte der Änderungen durch den Maastrichter Vertrag und des Völkerrechts. Zugl.: Saarbrücken, Univ., Diss., 1997. Saarbrücker Studien zum internationalen Recht, vol 8. Nomos, Baden-Baden
Zurück zum Zitat Giegerich T (2018c) Retorsion. In: Wolfrum R (ed) Max Planck encyclopedia of public international law (online edition). Oxford University Press, Oxford Giegerich T (2018c) Retorsion. In: Wolfrum R (ed) Max Planck encyclopedia of public international law (online edition). Oxford University Press, Oxford
Zurück zum Zitat Goldstein M, Lardy NR (2008) China’s exchange rate policy: an overview of some key issues. In: Goldstein M, Lardy NR (eds) Debating China’s exchange rate policy. Institute for International Economics, Washington D.C., London, pp 1–75 Goldstein M, Lardy NR (2008) China’s exchange rate policy: an overview of some key issues. In: Goldstein M, Lardy NR (eds) Debating China’s exchange rate policy. Institute for International Economics, Washington D.C., London, pp 1–75
Zurück zum Zitat Hahn MJ (1996) Die einseitige Aussetzung von GATT-Verpflichtungen als Repressalie. Zugl.: Heidelberg, Univ., Diss., 1994. Beiträge zum ausländischen öffentlichen Recht und Völkerrecht, vol 122. Springer, Berlin et al. Hahn MJ (1996) Die einseitige Aussetzung von GATT-Verpflichtungen als Repressalie. Zugl.: Heidelberg, Univ., Diss., 1994. Beiträge zum ausländischen öffentlichen Recht und Völkerrecht, vol 122. Springer, Berlin et al.
Zurück zum Zitat Herdegen M (2016) Principles of international economic law, 2nd edn. Oxford University Press, OxfordCrossRef Herdegen M (2016) Principles of international economic law, 2nd edn. Oxford University Press, OxfordCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Herrmann C (2010b) Don Yuan: China’s “Selfish” exchange rate policy and international economic law. Eur Yearb Int Econ Law 1:31–51 Herrmann C (2010b) Don Yuan: China’s “Selfish” exchange rate policy and international economic law. Eur Yearb Int Econ Law 1:31–51
Zurück zum Zitat Hufbauer GC, Wong Y, Sheth K (2006) US-China trade disputes: rising tide, rising stakes. Policy analyses in international economics, vol 78. Institute for International Economics, Washington D.C. Hufbauer GC, Wong Y, Sheth K (2006) US-China trade disputes: rising tide, rising stakes. Policy analyses in international economics, vol 78. Institute for International Economics, Washington D.C.
Zurück zum Zitat International Monetary Fund (1978) The Second Amendment of the Fund’s Articles of Agreement. Pamphlet Series. International Monetary Fund, Washington D.C. International Monetary Fund (1978) The Second Amendment of the Fund’s Articles of Agreement. Pamphlet Series. International Monetary Fund, Washington D.C.
Zurück zum Zitat International Monetary Fund (2005) Balance of payments manual, 5th edn. Books. International Monetary Fund, Washington D.C. International Monetary Fund (2005) Balance of payments manual, 5th edn. Books. International Monetary Fund, Washington D.C.
Zurück zum Zitat International Monetary Fund (2019) Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions 2018, Washington D.C. International Monetary Fund (2019) Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions 2018, Washington D.C.
Zurück zum Zitat Jackson JH (1997) The world trading system: law and policy of international economic relations, 2nd edn. MIT Press, Cambridge, London Jackson JH (1997) The world trading system: law and policy of international economic relations, 2nd edn. MIT Press, Cambridge, London
Zurück zum Zitat Jennings R, Watts A, Oppenheim LFL (1992b) Oppenheim’s international law: vol. I: peace, Parts 2 to 4, 9th edn. Longman, Harlow Jennings R, Watts A, Oppenheim LFL (1992b) Oppenheim’s international law: vol. I: peace, Parts 2 to 4, 9th edn. Longman, Harlow
Zurück zum Zitat Joyner DH (2016) International legal limits on the ability of states to lawfully impose international economic/financial sanctions. In: Ronzitti N (ed) Coercive diplomacy, sanctions and international law. Brill, Nijhoff, Leiden, pp 190–206 Joyner DH (2016) International legal limits on the ability of states to lawfully impose international economic/financial sanctions. In: Ronzitti N (ed) Coercive diplomacy, sanctions and international law. Brill, Nijhoff, Leiden, pp 190–206
Zurück zum Zitat Kämmerer JA (2018) Argentine debt crisis. In: Wolfrum R (ed) Max Planck encyclopedia of public international law (online edition). Oxford University Press, Oxford Kämmerer JA (2018) Argentine debt crisis. In: Wolfrum R (ed) Max Planck encyclopedia of public international law (online edition). Oxford University Press, Oxford
Zurück zum Zitat Katz DJ (2013) Waging financial war. US Army War Coll Q Parameters 43:77–85 Katz DJ (2013) Waging financial war. US Army War Coll Q Parameters 43:77–85
Zurück zum Zitat Kirshner J (1995) Currency and coercion: the political economy of international monetary power. Princeton University Press, Princeton, Chichester Kirshner J (1995) Currency and coercion: the political economy of international monetary power. Princeton University Press, Princeton, Chichester
Zurück zum Zitat Kißler K-P (1984) Die Zulässigkeit von Wirtschaftssanktionen der Europäischen Gemeinschaft gegenüber Drittstaaten. Schriften zum Staats- und Völkerrecht, Bd. 16. Peter Lang, Frankfurt am Main, New York Kißler K-P (1984) Die Zulässigkeit von Wirtschaftssanktionen der Europäischen Gemeinschaft gegenüber Drittstaaten. Schriften zum Staats- und Völkerrecht, Bd. 16. Peter Lang, Frankfurt am Main, New York
Zurück zum Zitat Krugman PR, Obstfeld M (2016) International economics: theory and policy, 10th edn. Pearson, New York Krugman PR, Obstfeld M (2016) International economics: theory and policy, 10th edn. Pearson, New York
Zurück zum Zitat Lastra RM (2015) International financial and monetary law, 2nd edn. Oxford University Press, Oxford Lastra RM (2015) International financial and monetary law, 2nd edn. Oxford University Press, Oxford
Zurück zum Zitat Lastra RM (2017a) Allocation of powers and jurisdiction in monetary law. In: Cottier T, Nadakavukaren Schefer K (eds) Elgar encyclopedia of international economic law. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, Northampton, pp 548–549 Lastra RM (2017a) Allocation of powers and jurisdiction in monetary law. In: Cottier T, Nadakavukaren Schefer K (eds) Elgar encyclopedia of international economic law. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, Northampton, pp 548–549
Zurück zum Zitat Lastra RM (2017b) The role of law in monetary policies. In: Cottier T, Nadakavukaren Schefer K (eds) Elgar encyclopedia of international economic law. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, Northampton, pp 549–551 Lastra RM (2017b) The role of law in monetary policies. In: Cottier T, Nadakavukaren Schefer K (eds) Elgar encyclopedia of international economic law. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, Northampton, pp 549–551
Zurück zum Zitat Malanczuk P (1985) Zur Repressalle im Entwurf der International Law Commission zur Staatenverantwortlichkeit. Zeitschrift für ausländisches öffentliches Recht und Völkerrecht 45:293–323 Malanczuk P (1985) Zur Repressalle im Entwurf der International Law Commission zur Staatenverantwortlichkeit. Zeitschrift für ausländisches öffentliches Recht und Völkerrecht 45:293–323
Zurück zum Zitat Malanczuk P (1997) Akehurst’s modern introduction to international law, 7th edn. Routledge, London, New York Malanczuk P (1997) Akehurst’s modern introduction to international law, 7th edn. Routledge, London, New York
Zurück zum Zitat Mann FA (1982) The legal aspect of money: with special reference to comparative private and public international law, 4th edn. Clarendon, Oxford Mann FA (1982) The legal aspect of money: with special reference to comparative private and public international law, 4th edn. Clarendon, Oxford
Zurück zum Zitat Mavroidis PC (2008) Trade in goods: the GATT and the other agreements regulating trade in goods agreements. Oxford University Press, OxfordCrossRef Mavroidis PC (2008) Trade in goods: the GATT and the other agreements regulating trade in goods agreements. Oxford University Press, OxfordCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat McDougal MS, Feliciano FP (1958) International coercion and world public order: the general principles of the law of war. Yale Law J 67:771–845 McDougal MS, Feliciano FP (1958) International coercion and world public order: the general principles of the law of war. Yale Law J 67:771–845
Zurück zum Zitat Mercurio B, Leung CSN (2009) Is China a currency manipulator: the legitimacy of China’s exchange regime under the current international legal framework. Int Lawyer 43:1257–1300 Mercurio B, Leung CSN (2009) Is China a currency manipulator: the legitimacy of China’s exchange regime under the current international legal framework. Int Lawyer 43:1257–1300
Zurück zum Zitat Mussa M (2008) IMF surveillance over China’s exchange rate policy. In: Goldstein M, Lardy NR (eds) Debating China’s exchange rate policy. Institute for International Economics, Washington D.C., London, pp 279–339 Mussa M (2008) IMF surveillance over China’s exchange rate policy. In: Goldstein M, Lardy NR (eds) Debating China’s exchange rate policy. Institute for International Economics, Washington D.C., London, pp 279–339
Zurück zum Zitat Noortmann M (2005) Enforcing international law: from self-help to self-contained regimes. Ashgate, Aldershot, Hants Noortmann M (2005) Enforcing international law: from self-help to self-contained regimes. Ashgate, Aldershot, Hants
Zurück zum Zitat Paddeu FI (2018) Countermeasures. In: Wolfrum R (ed) Max Planck encyclopedia of public international law (online edition). Oxford University Press, Oxford Paddeu FI (2018) Countermeasures. In: Wolfrum R (ed) Max Planck encyclopedia of public international law (online edition). Oxford University Press, Oxford
Zurück zum Zitat Peters A (2016) Völkerrecht: Allgemeiner Teil, 4th edn. litera B. Schulthess, Zürich, Basel, Genf Peters A (2016) Völkerrecht: Allgemeiner Teil, 4th edn. litera B. Schulthess, Zürich, Basel, Genf
Zurück zum Zitat Posner EA, Sykes AO (2013) Economic foundations of international law. Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, Cambridge Posner EA, Sykes AO (2013) Economic foundations of international law. Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, Cambridge
Zurück zum Zitat Rickards J (2011) Currency wars: the making of the next global crisis. Portfolio; Penguin, New York Rickards J (2011) Currency wars: the making of the next global crisis. Portfolio; Penguin, New York
Zurück zum Zitat Ronzitti N (ed) (2016b) Coercive diplomacy, sanctions and international law. Brill, Nijhoff, Leiden Ronzitti N (ed) (2016b) Coercive diplomacy, sanctions and international law. Brill, Nijhoff, Leiden
Zurück zum Zitat Schachter O (1982) International law in theory and practice: general course in public international law. RdC 178:9–396 Schachter O (1982) International law in theory and practice: general course in public international law. RdC 178:9–396
Zurück zum Zitat Schachter O (1991) International law in theory and practice. Developments in international law. Nijhoff, Dordrecht et al. Schachter O (1991) International law in theory and practice. Developments in international law. Nijhoff, Dordrecht et al.
Zurück zum Zitat Schröder M (2016) Verantwortlichkeit, Völkerstrafrecht, Streitbeilegung und Sanktionen. In: Vitzthum W, Proelß A (eds) Völkerrecht, 7th edn. de Gruyter, Berlin, Boston, pp 539–590 Schröder M (2016) Verantwortlichkeit, Völkerstrafrecht, Streitbeilegung und Sanktionen. In: Vitzthum W, Proelß A (eds) Völkerrecht, 7th edn. de Gruyter, Berlin, Boston, pp 539–590
Zurück zum Zitat Shaw MN (2017) International law, 8th edn. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, New York Shaw MN (2017) International law, 8th edn. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, New York
Zurück zum Zitat Steinmann A (2006) Art. 23 DSU. In: WTO - institutions and dispute settlement. Brill, Leiden, pp 557–562 Steinmann A (2006) Art. 23 DSU. In: WTO - institutions and dispute settlement. Brill, Leiden, pp 557–562
Zurück zum Zitat The CORE Team (2017) The economy. Oxford University Press, Oxford The CORE Team (2017) The economy. Oxford University Press, Oxford
Zurück zum Zitat The Economist (2018v, 19 May) Disappearing trick, p 59 The Economist (2018v, 19 May) Disappearing trick, p 59
Zurück zum Zitat The Economist (2018w, 20 January) Playing ketchup with the dollar, p 14 The Economist (2018w, 20 January) Playing ketchup with the dollar, p 14
Zurück zum Zitat The Economist (2019a, 10 August) Dangerous miscalculations, p 10 The Economist (2019a, 10 August) Dangerous miscalculations, p 10
Zurück zum Zitat The Economist (2019b, 10 August) The guns of August, pp 53–55 The Economist (2019b, 10 August) The guns of August, pp 53–55
Zurück zum Zitat Tietje C (2015a) § 3. WTO und Recht des Weltwarenhandels. In: Tietje C (ed) Internationales Wirtschaftsrecht, 2nd edn. de Gruyter, Berlin et al., pp 158–236 Tietje C (2015a) § 3. WTO und Recht des Weltwarenhandels. In: Tietje C (ed) Internationales Wirtschaftsrecht, 2nd edn. de Gruyter, Berlin et al., pp 158–236
Zurück zum Zitat Tomuschat C (1973) Repressalie und Retorsion, zu einigen Aspekten ihrer innerstaatlichen Durchführung. Zeitschrift für ausländisches öffentliches Recht und Völkerrecht 33:179–222 Tomuschat C (1973) Repressalie und Retorsion, zu einigen Aspekten ihrer innerstaatlichen Durchführung. Zeitschrift für ausländisches öffentliches Recht und Völkerrecht 33:179–222
Zurück zum Zitat van den Bossche P, Zdouc W (2017) The law and policy of the World Trade Organization: text, cases and materials, 4th edn. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRef van den Bossche P, Zdouc W (2017) The law and policy of the World Trade Organization: text, cases and materials, 4th edn. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Viterbo A (2012) International economic law and monetary measures: limitations to states’ sovereignty and dispute settlement. Edward Elgar, CheltenhamCrossRef Viterbo A (2012) International economic law and monetary measures: limitations to states’ sovereignty and dispute settlement. Edward Elgar, CheltenhamCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat White ND, Abass A (2014) Countermeasures and sanctions. In: Evans MD (ed) International law, 4th edn. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 537–562CrossRef White ND, Abass A (2014) Countermeasures and sanctions. In: Evans MD (ed) International law, 4th edn. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 537–562CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat World Trade Organization (1995) Guide to GATT law and practice: analytical index. WTO, Geneva World Trade Organization (1995) Guide to GATT law and practice: analytical index. WTO, Geneva
Zurück zum Zitat Wouters J, Coppens D (2009) An overview of the agreement on subsidies and countervailing measures – including a discussion of the agreement on agriculture. In: Bagwell KW, Bermann GA, Mavroidis PC (eds) Law and economics of contingent protection in international trade. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 7–84CrossRef Wouters J, Coppens D (2009) An overview of the agreement on subsidies and countervailing measures – including a discussion of the agreement on agriculture. In: Bagwell KW, Bermann GA, Mavroidis PC (eds) Law and economics of contingent protection in international trade. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 7–84CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Zarate JC (2013a) Treasury’s war: the unleashing of a new era of financial warfare. Public Affairs, New York Zarate JC (2013a) Treasury’s war: the unleashing of a new era of financial warfare. Public Affairs, New York
Zurück zum Zitat Zarate JC (2013b) The coming financial wars. US Army War Coll Q Parameters 43:87–97 Zarate JC (2013b) The coming financial wars. US Army War Coll Q Parameters 43:87–97
Zurück zum Zitat Zimmermann CD (2011a) Exchange rate misalignment and international law. AJIL 105:423–476CrossRef Zimmermann CD (2011a) Exchange rate misalignment and international law. AJIL 105:423–476CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Zimmermann CD (2013) A contemporary concept of monetary sovereignty. Oxford monographs in international law. Oxford University Press, Oxford, United KingdomCrossRef Zimmermann CD (2013) A contemporary concept of monetary sovereignty. Oxford monographs in international law. Oxford University Press, Oxford, United KingdomCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Zoller E (1984) Peacetime unilateral remedies: an analysis of countermeasures. Transnational; Epping, Dobbs Ferry Zoller E (1984) Peacetime unilateral remedies: an analysis of countermeasures. Transnational; Epping, Dobbs Ferry
Metadaten
Titel
Currency War
verfasst von
Teoman M. Hagemeyer-Witzleb
Copyright-Jahr
2021
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-72846-5_5

Premium Partner