Skip to main content

2016 | OriginalPaper | Buchkapitel

3. Hyperbolic Discounting and Self-Destructive Behaviors

verfasst von : Shinsuke Ikeda

Erschienen in: The Economics of Self-Destructive Choices

Verlag: Springer Japan

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

In the previous chapter, I explained that people’s degrees of impatience are affected by various choice conditions and frames, all of which cause a variety of anomalous phenomena in their intertemporal choices and behaviors that traditional economics cannot explain. In this chapter, I shall deal with hyperbolic discounting or present bias. As explained in Chap. 1, under hyperbolic discounting, more immediate gratifications are discounted at higher discount rates, and people are less patient in waiting for less delayed rewards.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
For two alternative rewards A and B with different magnitudes R A , R B and different delays T A , T B , a simple version of the matching law describes relative preferences for A over B, V A /V B , as \( {V}_A/{V}_B=K{R}_A\ {T}_B/\left({R}_B\ {T}_A\right) \), where K is a positive constant.
 
2
The issue of psychological or subjective time has been attracting the attention of economists. For example, Samuelson (1976) proposed axiomatic conditions for the existence of subjective time. Uzawa (1968) constructed consumers’ subjective time from the personal discount rate. Sato and Ramachandran (2014, Chap. 8) and Sato (2015) explained a downward trend of Japan’s income-wealth ratio after World War II by hypothesizing that the subjective time of the Japanese people expanded during the period.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Ainslie, G. W. (1974). Impulse control in pigeons. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 21(3), 485–489.CrossRef Ainslie, G. W. (1974). Impulse control in pigeons. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 21(3), 485–489.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Figner, B., Knoch, D., Johnson, E. J., Krosch, A. R., Lisanby, S. H., Fehr, E., & Weber, E. U. (2010). Lateral prefrontal cortex and self-control in intertemporal choice. Nature Neuroscience, 13, 538–539.CrossRef Figner, B., Knoch, D., Johnson, E. J., Krosch, A. R., Lisanby, S. H., Fehr, E., & Weber, E. U. (2010). Lateral prefrontal cortex and self-control in intertemporal choice. Nature Neuroscience, 13, 538–539.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Frederick, S. G., Loewenstein, G., & O’Donoghue, T. (2002). Time discounting and time preference: A critical review. Journal of Economic Literature, 40(2), 351–401.CrossRef Frederick, S. G., Loewenstein, G., & O’Donoghue, T. (2002). Time discounting and time preference: A critical review. Journal of Economic Literature, 40(2), 351–401.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Glimcher, P. W., Kable, J., & Louie, K. (2007). Neuroeconomic studies of impulsivity: Now or just as soon as possible? American Economic Review, 97(2), 142–147.CrossRef Glimcher, P. W., Kable, J., & Louie, K. (2007). Neuroeconomic studies of impulsivity: Now or just as soon as possible? American Economic Review, 97(2), 142–147.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hariri, A. R., Brown, S. M., Williamson, D. E., Flory, J. D., de Wit, H., & Manuck, S. B. (2006). Preference for immediate over delayed rewards is associated with magnitude of ventral striatal activity. Journal of Neuroscience, 26(51), 13213–13217.CrossRef Hariri, A. R., Brown, S. M., Williamson, D. E., Flory, J. D., de Wit, H., & Manuck, S. B. (2006). Preference for immediate over delayed rewards is associated with magnitude of ventral striatal activity. Journal of Neuroscience, 26(51), 13213–13217.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Herrnstein, R. J. (1961). Relative and absolute strengths of response as a function of frequency of reinforcement. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 4(3), 267–272.CrossRef Herrnstein, R. J. (1961). Relative and absolute strengths of response as a function of frequency of reinforcement. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 4(3), 267–272.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ikeda, I., Ohtake, F., & Tsutsui, Y. (2005). Time-discount rates: Investigation based on economic experiments and questionnaire survey (Osaka University ISER Discussion Paper No. 638). (in Japanese). Ikeda, I., Ohtake, F., & Tsutsui, Y. (2005). Time-discount rates: Investigation based on economic experiments and questionnaire survey (Osaka University ISER Discussion Paper No. 638). (in Japanese).
Zurück zum Zitat Kable, J. W., & Glimcher, P. W. (2007). The neural correlates of subjective value during intertemporal choice. Nature Neuroscience, 10(12), 1625–1633.CrossRef Kable, J. W., & Glimcher, P. W. (2007). The neural correlates of subjective value during intertemporal choice. Nature Neuroscience, 10(12), 1625–1633.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kable, J. W., & Glimcher, P. W. (2010). An “as soon as possible” effect in human intertemporal decision making: Behavioral evidence and neural mechanisms. Journal of Neurophysiology, 103(5), 2513–2531.CrossRef Kable, J. W., & Glimcher, P. W. (2010). An “as soon as possible” effect in human intertemporal decision making: Behavioral evidence and neural mechanisms. Journal of Neurophysiology, 103(5), 2513–2531.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Keren, G., & Roelofsma, P. (1995). Immediacy and certainty in intertemporal choice. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 63(3), 287–297.CrossRef Keren, G., & Roelofsma, P. (1995). Immediacy and certainty in intertemporal choice. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 63(3), 287–297.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kim, B. K., & Zauberman, G. (2009). Perception of anticipatory time in temporal discounting. Journal of Neuroscience, Psychology, and Economics, 2(2), 91–101.CrossRef Kim, B. K., & Zauberman, G. (2009). Perception of anticipatory time in temporal discounting. Journal of Neuroscience, Psychology, and Economics, 2(2), 91–101.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Loewenstein, G., & Prelec, D. (1992). Anomalies in intertemporal choice: Evidence and an interpretation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(2), 573–597.CrossRef Loewenstein, G., & Prelec, D. (1992). Anomalies in intertemporal choice: Evidence and an interpretation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(2), 573–597.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Loewenstein, G., Rick, S., & Cohen, J. D. (2008). Neuroeconomics. Annual Review of Psychology, 59, 647–672.CrossRef Loewenstein, G., Rick, S., & Cohen, J. D. (2008). Neuroeconomics. Annual Review of Psychology, 59, 647–672.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Matthews, L. R., & Temple, W. (1979). Concurrent schedule assessment of food preference in cows. Journal of the Experimental Analysis and Behavior, 32(2), 245–254.CrossRef Matthews, L. R., & Temple, W. (1979). Concurrent schedule assessment of food preference in cows. Journal of the Experimental Analysis and Behavior, 32(2), 245–254.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mazur, J. E. (1987). An adjusting procedure for studying delayed reinforcement. In M. L. Commons, J. E. Mazur, J. A. Navin, & H. Rachlin (Eds.), Quantitative analyses of behavior: The effect of delay and of intervening events on reinforcement value (Vol. 5, pp. 55–73). Hillsdale: Erlbaum. Mazur, J. E. (1987). An adjusting procedure for studying delayed reinforcement. In M. L. Commons, J. E. Mazur, J. A. Navin, & H. Rachlin (Eds.), Quantitative analyses of behavior: The effect of delay and of intervening events on reinforcement value (Vol. 5, pp. 55–73). Hillsdale: Erlbaum.
Zurück zum Zitat McClure, S. M., Laibson, D. I., Loewenstein, G., & Cohen, J. D. (2004). Separate neural systems value immediate and delayed monetary rewards. Science, 306(5695), 503–507.CrossRef McClure, S. M., Laibson, D. I., Loewenstein, G., & Cohen, J. D. (2004). Separate neural systems value immediate and delayed monetary rewards. Science, 306(5695), 503–507.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat McClure, S. M., Ericson, K. M., Laibson, D. I., Loewenstein, G., & Cohen, J. D. (2007). Time discounting for primary rewards. Journal of Neurosceince, 27(21), 5796–5804.CrossRef McClure, S. M., Ericson, K. M., Laibson, D. I., Loewenstein, G., & Cohen, J. D. (2007). Time discounting for primary rewards. Journal of Neurosceince, 27(21), 5796–5804.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ozdenoren, E., Salant, S. W., & Silverman, D. (2012). Willpower and the optimal control of visceral urges. Journal of the European Economic Association, 10(2), 342–368.CrossRef Ozdenoren, E., Salant, S. W., & Silverman, D. (2012). Willpower and the optimal control of visceral urges. Journal of the European Economic Association, 10(2), 342–368.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Peters, J. (2011). The role of the medical orbitofrontal cortex in intertemporal choice: Prospection or valuation? Journal of Neuroscience, 31(16), 5889–5890.CrossRef Peters, J. (2011). The role of the medical orbitofrontal cortex in intertemporal choice: Prospection or valuation? Journal of Neuroscience, 31(16), 5889–5890.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Roelofsma, P. H. M. P. (1996). Modelling intertemporal choices: An anomaly approach. Acta Psychologica, 93(1), 5–22.CrossRef Roelofsma, P. H. M. P. (1996). Modelling intertemporal choices: An anomaly approach. Acta Psychologica, 93(1), 5–22.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Samuelson, P. A. (1976). Speeding up of time with age in recognition of life as fleeting. In A. M. Tang, F. M. Westfield, & J. S. Worley (Eds.), Evolution, welfare, and time in economics: Essays in honor of Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen. Lexington: Lexington Books. Samuelson, P. A. (1976). Speeding up of time with age in recognition of life as fleeting. In A. M. Tang, F. M. Westfield, & J. S. Worley (Eds.), Evolution, welfare, and time in economics: Essays in honor of Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen. Lexington: Lexington Books.
Zurück zum Zitat Sato, R. (2015). Dynamic analysis and subjective time. Mimeo. Sato, R. (2015). Dynamic analysis and subjective time. Mimeo.
Zurück zum Zitat Sato, R., & Ramachandran, R. V. (2014). Symmetry and economic invariance (2nd Enhanced edition). Tokyo: Springer Japan. Sato, R., & Ramachandran, R. V. (2014). Symmetry and economic invariance (2nd Enhanced edition). Tokyo: Springer Japan.
Zurück zum Zitat Sellitto, M., Ciaramelli, E., & di Pellegrino, G. (2010). Myopic discounting of future rewards after medial orbitofrontal damage in humans. Journal of Neuroscience, 30(49), 16429–16436.CrossRef Sellitto, M., Ciaramelli, E., & di Pellegrino, G. (2010). Myopic discounting of future rewards after medial orbitofrontal damage in humans. Journal of Neuroscience, 30(49), 16429–16436.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Takahashi, T. (2005). Loss of self-control in intertemporal choice may be attributable to logarithmic time-perception. Medical Hypotheses, 65(4), 691–693.CrossRef Takahashi, T. (2005). Loss of self-control in intertemporal choice may be attributable to logarithmic time-perception. Medical Hypotheses, 65(4), 691–693.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tanaka, S. C., Doya, K., Okada, G., Ueda, K., Okamoto, Y., & Yamazaki, S. (2004). Prediction of immediate and future rewards differentially recruits cortico-basal ganglia loops. Nature Neuroscience, 7(8), 887–893.CrossRef Tanaka, S. C., Doya, K., Okada, G., Ueda, K., Okamoto, Y., & Yamazaki, S. (2004). Prediction of immediate and future rewards differentially recruits cortico-basal ganglia loops. Nature Neuroscience, 7(8), 887–893.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Uzawa, H. (1968). Time preference, the consumption function and optimum asset holdings. In J. N. Wolfe (Ed.), Value capital and growth: Papers in honour of Sir John Hicks (pp. 485–504). Chicago: Aldine. Uzawa, H. (1968). Time preference, the consumption function and optimum asset holdings. In J. N. Wolfe (Ed.), Value capital and growth: Papers in honour of Sir John Hicks (pp. 485–504). Chicago: Aldine.
Zurück zum Zitat Woolverton, W. L., & Alling, K. (1999). Choice under concurrent VI schedules: Comparison of behavior maintained by cocaine or food. Psychopharmacology, 141(1), 47–56.CrossRef Woolverton, W. L., & Alling, K. (1999). Choice under concurrent VI schedules: Comparison of behavior maintained by cocaine or food. Psychopharmacology, 141(1), 47–56.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Zauberman, G., Kim, B. K., Malkoc, S., & Bettman, J. R. (2009). Discounting time and time discounting: Subjective time perception and intertemporal preferences. Journal of Marketing Research, 46(4), 543–556.CrossRef Zauberman, G., Kim, B. K., Malkoc, S., & Bettman, J. R. (2009). Discounting time and time discounting: Subjective time perception and intertemporal preferences. Journal of Marketing Research, 46(4), 543–556.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Hyperbolic Discounting and Self-Destructive Behaviors
verfasst von
Shinsuke Ikeda
Copyright-Jahr
2016
Verlag
Springer Japan
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-4-431-55793-7_3

Premium Partner