Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Social Indicators Research 2/2018

24.08.2017

On the Output Orientation of the Benefit-of-the-Doubt-Model

verfasst von: Tom Van Puyenbroeck

Erschienen in: Social Indicators Research | Ausgabe 2/2018

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

While Benefit-of-the-Doubt (BoD) models, as used in the context of composite indicator construction, seek to aggregate outputs only, they are formally equivalent to an input-oriented Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) model in multiplier form. Strictly read, this introduces conceptually ambiguous results, as input adjustments have no real significance in the context at hand. At heart of this ambiguity lies a double interpretation of what is essentially a binding constraint in BoD’s underlying linear-fractional program. Moreover, there is a direct, reciprocal relation between the BoD-model and an earlier output-oriented DEA model introduced by Lovell et al. (Eur J Oper Res 87:507–518, 1995) for similar purposes. Although these models are essentially similar, I also show that there are instances (i.e. when adding additional weight restrictions) in which the results of one alternative are easier to communicate. The models surveyed in this paper are complemented with a short application on human development data for females living in Brussels municipalities.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
A log-linear aggregation yields the multiplicative BoD-model. Many other variants, e.g. including additional weight bounds, looking for a common set of BoD weights etc. are further possible but are not considered here. Also, for expositional purposes all models in this paper are presented without an explicit treatment of slacks (which e.g. accounts for a minor difference between model (4) below and the model appearing in Lovell et al. 1995).
 
2
The original Charnes et al. (1978) DEA-model accordingly builds on a deterministic axiom (any observed input–output combination is an element of the true production set), on (‘strongly’), free disposability assumptions (if any input/output combination is an element of the production set, then input/output combinations with at least as much inputs and/or at most as much outputs are also elements of that set), on convexity assumptions (given any two elements of the production set, any linear combination of these two elements also is an element of that set) and on the (‘constant returns to scale’) assumption that any input/output combination belonging to the production set can be proportionally rescaled and will in that manner still identify a feasible input/output combination. Several later variants of this seminal model can be understood as building on a different set of axioms.
 
3
That is, there are in fact an infinite number of optimal solutions to (III), as any optimal weighting vector \((u^{*} ,v^{*} )\) implies the existence of an equally optimal vector \((\alpha u^{*},\alpha v^{*}),\alpha > 0\). By choosing among those the solution for which the denominator of the objective function in (III) equals one, that denominator vanishes and one arrives at the linear program.
 
4
Unlike (6), this is a variable returns to scale model. Lovell and Pastor (1999) however demonstrate its equivalence with an output-oriented constant returns to scale model with a unitary input.
 
5
In particular, this implies \(\tilde{w}_{i0}^{*} /\tilde{w}_{k0}^{*} = w_{i0}^{*} /w_{k0}^{*} \forall i,k = 1, \ldots ,I\), i.e. equal pairwise optimal trade-offs, as well as equality of the optimal proportional shares \(\tilde{w}_{i0}^{*} Y_{i0} /\left( {\sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{I} {\tilde{w}_{i0}^{*} Y_{i0} } } \right) = w_{i0}^{*} Y_{i0} /\left( {\sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{I} {w_{i0}^{*} Y_{i0} } } \right)\forall i = 1, \ldots ,I\).
 
6
Since the denominator needs to equal 1 in the optimum to go from fractional Model (6) to its LP-counterpart (5), model (6) has a constraint ‘set’ different from the one employed in (1).
 
7
An in-depth analysis of this problem is provided by Munda and Nardo (2009), who consequently argue in favor of a different methodological framework, based on noncompensatory/nonlinear aggregation rules. See also Munda (2012).
 
8
Care should of course be taken to set the max and min-operators at the right places. In this case, if one would proceed wrongly and start from \(\mathop {\hbox{min} }\limits_{w} \left( {{{\sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{I} {w_{i0} Y_{i0} } } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{I} {w_{i0} Y_{i0} } } {\left( {\mathop {\hbox{max} }\limits_{{Y_{ij} }} \sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{I} {w_{i0} Y_{ij} } } \right)}}} \right. \kern-0pt} {\left( {\mathop {\hbox{max} }\limits_{{Y_{ij} }} \sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{I} {w_{i0} Y_{ij} } } \right)}}} \right)\), one actually is dealing with the model of Athanassoglou (2015), who combines least favorable weights with the identification of best-practices.
 
9
See statistics.brussels.
 
10
The exact procedure to find this estimated share is similar to the one used by UNDP (see their technical note, UNDP, 2016). The value of the wage gap used is 0.8 (i.e. the average gross wage gap in Belgium). Changing this value to 0.9 (the wage gap adjusted for labor time etc) leaves the municipality rankings unaltered.
 
11
For life expectancy, the maximal value was set at 86.1 years (i.e. the maximum value in the sample) and the minimum was set at 20 as is done by UNDP. The maximum (worst possible) share of pupils with significant grade retention is set at 50%, the minimum at 5%. Maximum female per capita income is 20.000 euro, the minimum is set at 300 euro.
 
12
See e.g. Qizilbash (1997) for an application of the Borda method to HDI country data.
 
13
Note that in Table 2 we exploit the intimate relation between the results of these two envelopment models as discussed in the previous section. In the table we opt to show the results of model (7), which has the convenience that all λ j -variables add up to 1 by construction, rather than those of model (6), which are the same up to a scalar transformation.
 
14
Note that opposite, but otherwise qualitatively similar results would be generated when looking for endogenous ‘worst possible’ weights, i.e. when applying model (12) to the data of Table 2. That is, the emphasis would largely be on the educational dimension, and there would be one municipality (Sint-Joost-ten-Node) that would have a major role in identifying worst practices.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Athanassoglou, S. (2015). Revisiting worst-case DEA for composite indicators. Social Indicators Research, 128, 1–14. Athanassoglou, S. (2015). Revisiting worst-case DEA for composite indicators. Social Indicators Research, 128, 1–14.
Zurück zum Zitat Charnes, A., & Cooper, W. W. (1962). Programming with linear fractional functionals. Naval Research Logistics Quarterly, 9, 181–186.CrossRef Charnes, A., & Cooper, W. W. (1962). Programming with linear fractional functionals. Naval Research Logistics Quarterly, 9, 181–186.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Charnes, A., Cooper, W. W., & Rhodes, E. (1978). Measuring the efficiency of decision making units. European Journal of Operational Research, 2, 429–444.CrossRef Charnes, A., Cooper, W. W., & Rhodes, E. (1978). Measuring the efficiency of decision making units. European Journal of Operational Research, 2, 429–444.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cherchye, L., Moesen, W., Rogge, N., & Van Puyenbroeck, T. (2007). An introduction to ‘benefit of the doubt’ composite indicators. Social Indicators Research, 82, 111–145.CrossRef Cherchye, L., Moesen, W., Rogge, N., & Van Puyenbroeck, T. (2007). An introduction to ‘benefit of the doubt’ composite indicators. Social Indicators Research, 82, 111–145.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cherchye, L., Moesen, W., & Van Puyenbroeck, T. (2004). Legitimately diverse, yet comparable: On synthesizing social inclusion performance in the EU. JCMS Journal of Common Market Studies, 42(5), 919–955.CrossRef Cherchye, L., Moesen, W., & Van Puyenbroeck, T. (2004). Legitimately diverse, yet comparable: On synthesizing social inclusion performance in the EU. JCMS Journal of Common Market Studies, 42(5), 919–955.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cooper, W. W., Seiford, L., & Tone, K. (1999). Data envelopment analysis. New York: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Cooper, W. W., Seiford, L., & Tone, K. (1999). Data envelopment analysis. New York: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Zurück zum Zitat Despotis, D. K. (2005). A reassessment of the human development index via data envelopment analysis. The Journal of the Operational Research Society, 56, 969–980.CrossRef Despotis, D. K. (2005). A reassessment of the human development index via data envelopment analysis. The Journal of the Operational Research Society, 56, 969–980.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Färe, R., & Karagiannis, G. (2014). Benefit-of-the-doubt aggregation and the diet problem. Omega, 47, 33–35.CrossRef Färe, R., & Karagiannis, G. (2014). Benefit-of-the-doubt aggregation and the diet problem. Omega, 47, 33–35.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Liu, W. B., Zhang, D. Q., Meng, W., Li, X. X., & Xu, F. (2011). A study of DEA models without explicit inputs. Omega, 39, 472–480.CrossRef Liu, W. B., Zhang, D. Q., Meng, W., Li, X. X., & Xu, F. (2011). A study of DEA models without explicit inputs. Omega, 39, 472–480.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lovell, C. A. K., & Pastor, J. T. (1999). Radial DEA models without inputs or without outputs. European Journal of Operational Research, 118, 46–51.CrossRef Lovell, C. A. K., & Pastor, J. T. (1999). Radial DEA models without inputs or without outputs. European Journal of Operational Research, 118, 46–51.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lovell, C. A. K., Pastor, J. T., & Turner, J. A. (1995). Measuring macroeconomic performance in the OECD: a comparison of European and non-European countries. European Journal of Operational Research, 87, 507–518.CrossRef Lovell, C. A. K., Pastor, J. T., & Turner, J. A. (1995). Measuring macroeconomic performance in the OECD: a comparison of European and non-European countries. European Journal of Operational Research, 87, 507–518.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mariano, E. B., Sobreiro, V. A., & do Nascimento Rebelatto, D. A. (2015). Human development and data envelopment analysis: A structured literature review. Omega, 54, 33–49.CrossRef Mariano, E. B., Sobreiro, V. A., & do Nascimento Rebelatto, D. A. (2015). Human development and data envelopment analysis: A structured literature review. Omega, 54, 33–49.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Munda, G. (2012). Choosing aggregation rules for composite indicators. Social Indicators Research, 109(3), 337–354.CrossRef Munda, G. (2012). Choosing aggregation rules for composite indicators. Social Indicators Research, 109(3), 337–354.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Munda, G., & Nardo, M. (2009). Noncompensatory/nonlinear composite indicators for ranking countries: a defensible setting. Applied Economics, 41(12), 1513–1523.CrossRef Munda, G., & Nardo, M. (2009). Noncompensatory/nonlinear composite indicators for ranking countries: a defensible setting. Applied Economics, 41(12), 1513–1523.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nardo, M., Saisana, M., Saltelli, A., Tarantola, S., Hoffman, A. and E. Giovannini (2005), Handbook on Constructing Composite Indicators: Methodology and Users Guide. Paris/Ispra. Nardo, M., Saisana, M., Saltelli, A., Tarantola, S., Hoffman, A. and E. Giovannini (2005), Handbook on Constructing Composite Indicators: Methodology and Users Guide. Paris/Ispra.
Zurück zum Zitat Podinovski, V. V. (2001). DEA models for the explicit maximization of relative efficiency. European Journal of Operational Research, 131, 572–586.CrossRef Podinovski, V. V. (2001). DEA models for the explicit maximization of relative efficiency. European Journal of Operational Research, 131, 572–586.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Qizilbash, M. (1997). Pluralism and well-being indices. World Development, 25, 2009–2026.CrossRef Qizilbash, M. (1997). Pluralism and well-being indices. World Development, 25, 2009–2026.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sarrico, C. S., & Dyson, R. G. (2004). Restricting virtual weights in data envelopment analysis. European Journal of Operational Research, 159, 17–34.CrossRef Sarrico, C. S., & Dyson, R. G. (2004). Restricting virtual weights in data envelopment analysis. European Journal of Operational Research, 159, 17–34.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Savić, G., & Martić, M. (2017). Composite Indicator Construction by Data Envelopment Analysis. In V. Jeremić et al. (Eds.), Emerging trends in the development and application of composite indicators (pp. 132–155). Hershey: IGI Global. Savić, G., & Martić, M. (2017). Composite Indicator Construction by Data Envelopment Analysis. In V. Jeremić et al. (Eds.), Emerging trends in the development and application of composite indicators (pp. 132–155). Hershey: IGI Global.
Zurück zum Zitat Wong, Y.-H. B., & Beasley, J. (1990). Restricting weight flexibility in data envelopment analysis. Journal of the Operational Research Society, 41, 829–835.CrossRef Wong, Y.-H. B., & Beasley, J. (1990). Restricting weight flexibility in data envelopment analysis. Journal of the Operational Research Society, 41, 829–835.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Zhou, P., Ang, B. W., & Poh, K. L. (2007). A mathematical programming approach to constructing composite indicators. Ecological Economics, 62(2), 291–297.CrossRef Zhou, P., Ang, B. W., & Poh, K. L. (2007). A mathematical programming approach to constructing composite indicators. Ecological Economics, 62(2), 291–297.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
On the Output Orientation of the Benefit-of-the-Doubt-Model
verfasst von
Tom Van Puyenbroeck
Publikationsdatum
24.08.2017
Verlag
Springer Netherlands
Erschienen in
Social Indicators Research / Ausgabe 2/2018
Print ISSN: 0303-8300
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-0921
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-017-1734-x

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 2/2018

Social Indicators Research 2/2018 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner