Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Empirical Economics 6/2021

Open Access 18.09.2020

Is the productivity premium of internationalized firms technology-driven?

verfasst von: Michele Battisti, Filippo Belloc, Massimo Del Gatto

Erschienen in: Empirical Economics | Ausgabe 6/2021

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

We ask whether the productivity advantage of internationalized firms documented by the international trade literature can be interpreted most accurately in terms of proximity to the “technological frontier”. We answer in the affirmative using a methodology (based on mixture models) of unbundling technology and total factor productivity (TFP) by estimating “technology-specific” production function parameters. Exploiting detailed data provided by the EFIGE database (a sample of firms distributed across Austria, France, Germany, Hungary, Italy, Spain, and the UK), we find technology gaps (with respect to the frontier) more than three times larger than the TFP gaps on average. We also find sizable technology advantages for firms undertaking foreign direct investment and/or exporting to other European Union countries or to China, for importers of materials, and for firms with competitors in China and the USA. Medium and large firms feature a higher technology premium, which is even higher for firms operating in country-sectors that are more exposed to import competition from China. Younger firms use better technologies but less effectively.
Hinweise

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

1 Introduction

Productivity differentials across economic units are commonly interpreted in terms of “technological” heterogeneity, independently of being measured as labor productivity or total factor productivity (TFP). This practice is particularly pervasive in firm level studies, where making technological upgrading more accessible to the less “productive” firms seems to be the main prescription for helping them reduce their distance from the “frontier” and ultimately enhancing aggregate productivity growth.
However, productivity is a broad notion encompassing several hard-to-measure factors, which comprise all that cannot be explained by capital accumulation, in its standard TFP formulation, and even capital accumulation itself if labor productivity is used. Hence, enucleating the relative importance of the technological dimension within the wide notion of productivity is becoming increasingly important, particularly from a policy perspective.
For instance, the OECD (2015) documents labour productivity growth amounting to 3.5% at the global (manufacturing) frontier, against 0.5% for non-frontier firms, over the course of the 2000s (the gap is even more pronounced in the services sector). On the one hand, this report raises questions about the obstacles preventing laggard firms from adopting well-known frontier technologies: on the other, it mentions how, “given the difficulties in measuring technology, the globally most productive firms are also assumed to operate with the globally most advanced technologies but it should be recognized that very technologically advanced firms might not necessarily appear as the globally most productive or the most successful in terms of profits” (OECD 2015 page 33).
However, little empirical effort has been made to investigate the relative importance of the technological dimension of productivity within the general notion of productivity. As Bernard and Jones pointed out more than 20 years ago (Bernard and Jones 1996a), the usual (Solow residual) TFP measures are conceived under the hypothesis that the different economic units (country-sectors, in their case) are characterized by the same factor coefficients. Insofar as differences in factor coefficients mirror differences in technology, this rules out the possibility that different industries in different countries have access to different technologies. From the firm level perspective, this entails neglecting the armchair evidence that an array of technologies is normally available to firms operating in the same industry, with access to each technology varying across firms along several dimensions. The degree of internationalization is one of these dimensions.
In fact, the literature on firms’ international exposure has extensively highlighted the positive correlation between a firm’s export status and its productivity (called “exceptional exporter performance” by Bernard and Jensen (1999)). This paper explores whether, and to what extent, the productivity advantage of internationalized firms documented by the literature (see Sect. 2), can be understood in terms of technological advantage, rather than know-how and/or ability in using similar technologies.
The technological dimension of productivity is usually not considered explicitly because estimating technology-specific production function parameters, without ex-ante assumptions on the technology used by each firm, seems a daunting task with standard econometrics. This process entails that the potential factor parameter differences across technologies flow entirely into a Solow residual (i.e., the difference between observed and predicted output), in which the predicted output is computed on the basis of sector-specific production function parameters (i.e., estimated at the sectoral level).
Our analysis builds on the mixture regression analysis discussed in Battisti et al. (2020) to unbundle technology and TFP by estimating technology-specific production functions. We retrieve technology-specific factor parameters, avoiding any type of ex-ante assumption on the degree of technological sharing across firms and leaving the number of available technologies (i.e. technology groups) unconstrained. This procedure allows us to give a sense of magnitude concerning how much of the productivity–internationalization premium can be attributed to firms’ technological choices, on the one hand, and to an idiosyncratic TFP measure which, being net of this “technological” component, can be interpreted in terms of know-how and/or ability to exploit the given technology, on the other. We will focus on the complement (or gap) of the firm’s productivity performance over these two productivity dimensions with respect to what can be considered as the best practice: the between-technology TFP gap, defined as the output difference between what a firm could have produced had it chosen the best (output maximizing) available technology and the predicted output of the firm under its actual technology; and the within-technology TFP gap, defined as the difference between the average output of the best 5% performing firms and the actual output of the given firm, within a same technology group.
The analysis takes advantage of the EFIGE-ORBIS database, provided by Bruegel. EFIGE is a survey that reports detailed information on the international operations of almost 15,000 firms in seven European economies (Austria, France, Germany, Hungary, Italy, Spain, and the UK). This is combined with balance sheet data drawn from the ORBIS database, provided by Bureau van Dijk.
The estimation results point to a sectoral number of technologies ranging from one to three, depending on the industry. The first result concerns the average importance of the estimated between-technology and within-technology TFP gaps across firms. Although there is some cross-sector variability, the between-technology gaps are found to be more than three times larger than the within-technology gaps, on average. Interestingly, Battisti et al. (2020) find them to be twice as large. These results suggest that sample selection plays a key role in the findings. The sample used in Battisti et al. (2020) is larger and much less skewed towards central Europe than is the sample used in our study. This seems to support the idea that technological advancement goes hand in hand with international openness. Indeed, this is the key result emerging from our correlation analysis with the degree of international exposure, which indicates a non-significant correlation between international exposure and our within-technology TFP gaps. This complements the finding regarding the strong relevance of the between-technology gaps for most types of internationalization status. The technology advantage is found to be particularly important for firms undertaking foreign direct investment (FDI), for global exporters, importers of materials, and exporters.
Moreover, while the firms operating in country-sectors that are more exposed to competitive pressure from China do not seem to feature relatively higher within-technology TFP gaps, large firms operating in those country-sectors display significant technology advantages. This finding is consistent with the evidence of a positive relationship between competition and innovation provided by, among others, Bloom et al. (2016).
Firm size matters greatly for technology gaps, with larger firms producing with better technologies. Interestingly, age, which is found to significantly correlate with larger within-technology TFP, is associated with smaller technology gaps. This result suggests that technology is more easily accessible to young firms, but also that it takes time to be effectively used by the firm.
We finally address the geographical dimension of the international operations, showing that the technology advantage of being an exporter or being engaged in FDI activities is driven mainly by firms exporting to EU countries and, among the global exporters, by firms exporting to China. Moreover, the advantage is greater for firms importing from within the EU and, finally, for firms competing with the USA and other EU countries. Interestingly, having competitors located in China tends to be associated with higher between-technology technology gaps, except for large firms, which in this case also enjoy a technological advantage. From a policy perspective, the overall analysis lends support to the common interpretation of the productivity gap among less-internationalized firms in terms of distance from the technological frontier.
The rest of this paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 reviews the related literature. Section 3 briefly describes the study’s data. Our estimation steps and results are discussed in Sect. 4, while Sect. 5 analyses the productivity–internationalization relationship. Section 6 concludes the paper.
Our focus in the present analysis is on the extent to which cross-firm heterogeneity in productivity can be considered to mirror cross-firm heterogeneity in technology, paying particular attention to the productivity advantage of internationalized firms.
As mentioned, interest in the productivity advantage of internationalized firms started with the finding of a positive correlation between the export status and productivity, in the “exceptional exporter performance” highlighted by Bernard and Jensen (1999). Causality can run both ways. On the one hand, the relationship can be fostered by a process of “selection into export status”, whereby firms that already perform better have a stronger propensity to export than other firms (Tybout 2002). Indeed, exposure to trade is found to force the least productive firms to leave the market (Clerides et al. 1998; Bernard and Jensen 1999; Aw et al. 2000) and to lead to market share reallocation toward the most productive firms (Pavcnik 2002; Bernard et al. 2006). On the other hand, one might think that firm productivity grows as a consequence of a process of “learning by exporting” (Delgado et al. 2002; Van Biesebroeck 2005; Lileeva and Trefler 2010; Serti and Tomasi 2008; De Loecker 2007) or due to technology upgrading effects induced by international competitiveness shocks (i.e., Bustos 2011; Bloom et al. 2016).
Independently of the direction of causality, which is beyond the scope of our analysis, studies have produced comprehensive evidence that productivity is positively related not only to the exporting, but, more generally, to other forms of international exposure, such as importing, undertaking FDI, and international outsourcing. For instance, Helpman et al. (2004) show that only the most productive among the firms that serve foreign markets engage in FDI. From a policy perspective, Mayer and Ottaviano (2008) conclude that the overall international performance of European countries is essentially driven by a handful of high-performance firms.
In general, the literature shows that the productivity premium seems to grow along with the complexity of international activities. This is clearly shown by Altomonte and Aquilante (2012), who use the same data uses in our study to reveal that firms’ size and productivity premia are related to complex internationalization strategies such as exporting to a larger number of markets and/or to more distant countries, producing abroad through FDI, and being involved in international outsourcing. Such features seem to influence the patterns of internationalization in remarkably similar ways across countries. Consistently with these findings, the OECD (2015) highlights how “the global productivity frontier is actually comprised of firms from different countries [...] They are very much “global firms” in the sense that they operate in different countries (often part of a MNE group), and are interconnected with suppliers/customers from different countries along global value chains (GVCs).
The productivity measure preferred by most of the above studies is TFP, measured along the lines suggested by the recent literature on TFP estimation (Olley and Pakes 1996; Levinsohn and Petrin 2003; Wooldridge 2009; Ackerberg et al. 2015). While this literature has emphasized on purging the estimates from the so-called simultaneity bias, we focus on the importance of firm level technology as a determinant of productivity differences among firms, while controlling for simultaneity. The opportunity to disentangle these two dimensions has been highlighted by, among others, Bernard and Jones (1996a, (1996b), using the expression “total technological productivity”. Moreover, Collard-Wexler and De Loecker (2014) document important productivity increases in the steel industry, associated with the adoption of a particular technology (i.e., the “minimill” technology), while Doraszelski and Jaumandreu (2013) show that a firm’s TFP is stochastically affected by its investment in R&D.1
From the theoretical perspective, a growing body of literature concentrates on “technology”, in terms of both the creation of new technologies and the adoption/diffusion of available technologies, as one of the driving factors commonly included in standard TFP figures.
Studies on the relationship between technology adoption/diffusion and the diffusion of development date back to Gerschenkron (1962), and include Nelson and Phelps (1966) and Howitt (2000). Within this branch of literature, Parente and Prescott (1994) show that differences in barriers to technology adoption, which vary across countries and time, account for the great disparities in income across countries. Other works stress the spatial dimension of the process of technology adoption and diffusion. Desmet and Parente (2010) model the relationship between market size and technological upgrading. Desmet and Rossi-Hansberg (2014) propose a model in which technology diffusion affects economic development because technology diffuses spatially and firms in each location use the best technology they have access to. Comin et al. (2012) propose a theory in which technology diffuses slower to locations that are farther away from adoption leaders.2
Other studies point out the importance of the firm level dimension of productivity growth (i.e. changes in the productivity distribution). Gabler and Poschke (2013) and Da Rocha et al. (2017) introduce endogenous establishment-level productivity in their studies on the evolution of aggregate productivity. A similar approach is adopted by a number of studies, in which aggregate growth is fostered by the evolution of the firm level TFP distribution, as induced by trade integration (see Grossman and Helpman (2015) for an early review). This literature explicitly focuses on the role of technological heterogeneity. Among others, Sampson (2016) stresses the role of the technological choice of the entrant firms. Perla and Tonetti (2014) focus on the diffusion of technology from the more to the less productive firms, which allows the TFP distribution to endogenously “evolve” even without the introduction of new technologies. In Perla et al. (2015), firms choose whether to adopt a better technology or not, and trade integration fosters aggregate growth, by increasing the incentives to adopt the better technologies. In Benhabib et al. (2017), firms choose whether to keep producing with their existing technology, adopt a new technology or innovate, but only innovation fosters growth in the long run. Luttmer (2007) focuses on imitation, highlighting that the small size of entrants de facto indicates that imitation is difficult. In Alvarez et al. (2014), the flow of new ideas is the engine of growth: firms acquire new technologies by learning from those with whom they do business, so that trade fosters technology diffusion and aggregate growth by enabling more meeting opportunities.
Two order-of-innovation consequences of the fact that increased exposure to international markets entails fiercer competition are put forward by the literature. On the one hand, increased competition is likely to reduce innovation to the extent that expected profits shrink. On the other hand, import competition, especially from low-cost countries, is likely to force firms to innovate more than they would otherwise. Aghion et al. (2005) reconcile these two effects by deriving and testing a U-shaped relationship between competition and innovation. The firm level adjustment to increased competition along this line is investigated by Gorodnichenko et al. (2010) and Hashmi (2013). Garcia-Marin and Voigtlander (2019) provide evidence that the declining marginal costs at export entry that emerge once the price bias in productivity measurements induced by shrinking markups is accounted for are associated with higher plant-level investment (especially in machinery), which suggests that technology upgrading may be driven by a learning-from-exporting mechanism or by the increased potential benefits of innovation due to access to larger markets. Accordingly, they show that marginal costs drop steeply for plants that are initially less productive.

3 Data

This study’s analysis is based on a sample of manufacturing firms drawn from the EU-EFIGE/Bruegel-UniCredit dataset3 (“EFIGE” henceforth). This dataset surveys the international activities of almost 15,000 firms in seven European economies (Austria, France, Germany, Hungary, Italy, Spain, and the UK). The survey was conducted in 2010 and covers the period 2007 to 2009. The reported information is cross-sectional. Production function estimation, which requires two years in order to control for simultaneity (see Sect. 4), is carried out over the two years of 2009 and 2010.
The sample, which is representative of firms with more than 10 employees (see Altomonte and Aquilante 2012, for detailed information on the dataset and its representativeness), has been combined by the EFIGE team with balance sheet information from the ORBIS database of Bureau van Dijk (which covers 2001 to 2014).
From the EFIGE-ORBIS dataset, we draw information on the variables used in production function estimation. As well as value added and fixed assets, the survey provides us with quite detailed information on employees, allowing us to separately identify the number of workers in the three categories of: white collar, skilled blue collar and unskilled blue collar. Moreover, we are able to observe total (and thus average) wages. Value added, capital and wages are deflated using OECD-STAN country-sector-year deflators. From EFIGE-ORBIS, we also draw information on the other firm characteristics: age and size category (based on the total number of employees).
Data are trimmed at the first and last percentiles of the output per worker and capital per worker distributions. Tables 1 and 2 report the descriptive statistics at the sectoral and country levels, respectively.
Table 1
Descriptive statistics by sector
Sector
Short
VA
K
\(L_{wc}\)
\(L_{Ubc}\)
\(L_{Sbc}\)
# firms
Food products and beverages
Fd
2.565
3.767
1.443
2.411
2.113
489
Textiles
TX
2.484
3.594
1.661
2.366
2.051
131
wearing apparel
WA
1.989
2.839
1.221
2.218
1.953
71
Leather and leather products
LP
2.138
3.212
1.133
2.368
1.914
78
Wood and wood products
Wo
1.931
3.200
1.049
2.031
2.167
188
Pulp, paper and paper products; publishing and printing
Pa
2.829
3.725
1.890
2.191
2.486
74
Printing and reproduction of recorded media
Pr
2.411
3.155
1.576
1.641
2.639
137
Chemicals, chemical products
Ch
3.272
4.415
2.111
2.467
2.502
151
Rubber and plastic products
RP
2.750
3.716
1.819
2.613
2.169
274
Other non-metallic mineral products
NM
2.415
3.746
1.560
2.135
2.235
203
Basic metals
BM
3.305
4.398
2.131
2.948
2.926
107
Fabricated metal products
MP
2.419
3.242
1.357
1.953
2.398
887
Manufacture of computer, electronic and optical products
EP
3.029
3.799
2.047
2.211
2.567
69
Manufacture of electrical equipment
El
2.819
3.782
2.092
2.155
2.618
167
Machinery and equipment n.e.c.
Ma
2.845
3.804
1.920
1.934
2.628
498
Motor vehicles, trailers and semi-trailers
MV
3.089
3.988
2.098
2.728
2.861
83
Other manufacturing
Ot
2.228
3.383
1.590
2.109
2.308
282
Repair and installation of machinery and equipment
Re
2.958
3.799
2.146
1.967
2.451
72
Avg/Tot
 
2.637
3.643
1.714
2.247
2.388
3961
Table 2
Descriptive statistics by country
country
VA
K
\(L_{wc}\)
\(L_{Ubc}\)
\(L_{Sbc}\)
# firms
AUT
4.413
4.964
3.569
3.468
4.014
17
FRA
2.679
3.215
1.730
1.952
2.482
676
GER
3.879
4.458
2.954
2.642
3.542
319
HUN
2.624
3.363
2.355
3.083
3.124
65
ITA
2.540
3.852
1.720
2.275
2.041
1267
ESP
2.112
3.212
1.023
2.024
2.177
1417
UK
3.587
4.417
2.439
2.180
3.233
200
Avg/Tot
3.119
3.926
2.256
2.518
2.945
3961
The advantage of EFIGE over other firm level data is its detailed information on both labor and firms’ international activities.

4 Unbundling between-technology and within-technology TFP

We disentangle the between- and within-technology dimensions of productivity by using the two-stage estimation detailed in Battisti et al. (2020). The first stage entails estimating the correction factors to be used in the estimation of the production functions in order to tackle the simultaneity issue (Klette and Griliches 1996). In the second stage, technology-specific production function parameters are estimated, through a mixture model that includes the correction factors obtained in the first step. The estimation algorithm identifies the number of technology groups (i.e., the number of production functions) for each sector and the probability of adopting each technology for each firm. Finally, we compute between-technology and within-technology TFP gaps along the lines described below.
In its standard TFP interpretation, firm productivity encompasses output differences across firms that are not related to the choice of inputs. Hence, all else being equal, TFP differences are given by two dimensions. The first one is common among firms and is defined over the set of parameters that specify how inputs contribute to generating output. This is a technological dimension characterizing the shape (i.e., slope and intercept) of the production function. The second dimension is firm-specific and reflects the idiosyncratic ability of the firm to transform inputs into output, given the technology (e.g., Bhattacharya et al. 2013).
Before going into the details of each step, let us formalize the unbundling setup. Assume that firm i uses the bundle of inputs X to produce output Y through \(Y_i=A_{i}F(\mathbf {X}_{i})\). Following the standard approach, the idiosyncratic productivity (i.e., TFP) term \(A_{i}\) can be retrieved by estimating the log-production function \(y_i=\alpha + {\beta } \mathbf{x}_{i} + \epsilon _i\) at the sectoral level and computing TFP as the Solow residual \(a_{i}\equiv ln(A_{i})=y_i-\hat{y}_i\). In this case, TFP is expressed in relative terms with respect to the average firm in the sector. Let us consider an array of technologies available in each sector, with a number of firms using each technology. Then, the estimated TFP productivity distribution can actually be seen as the result of the overlapping of several TFP distributions, one for each (group of firms using the same) technology. We use \(m=1\) as an index of technology, with M denoting the number of available technologies. We also assume that the technology differs in terms of the production function parameters (\(\alpha ,\beta \)) and that we are able to estimate them for each technology (we will use mixture models for this). With this information, we are also able to identify the technology among all possibilities that would allow firm i to produce the maximum possible output level given the amount of capital. We refer to this technology as \(m^H\). Instead of using the average firm in the sector as a benchmark, as in the standard approach, we can now express the Solow residual in terms of the average firm among the firms using the best technology: \(\hat{a}_{i,m^{H}}=y_{i}-\hat{y}_{i,m^{H}}\), with \(\hat{y}_{i,m^{H}}\) denoting firm i’s predicted output associated with using the best technology.
Let us now turn to the technology actually used by firm i and assume, for the time being, that it is observable. Using \(m^D\) to refer to such technology, the corresponding predicted output \(\hat{y}_{i,m^{D}}\) can be used to obtain the following decomposition of \(\hat{a}_{i,m^{H}}\) into a within- and a between-technology component:
$$\begin{aligned} \hat{a}_{i,m^{H}}=\underbrace{y_{i}-\hat{y}_{i,m^{D}}}_{WITHIN} + \underbrace{\hat{y}_{i,m^{D}} -\hat{y}_{i,m^{H}}}_{BETWEEN} \end{aligned}$$
(1)
The “between” component, which is also equal to \(\hat{a}_{i,{m^D}}-\hat{a}_{i,m^{H}}\), is a measure of technology productivity expressed in terms of the distance between the predicted output associated with the firm’s actual technology and the output associated with the output-maximizing technology, given the input levels, had the firm behaved as the “average” firm in the two technology groups. As the difference between predicted outputs, this measure is driven only by technology, through the different production function parameters.
The “within” component provides us with a quantification of the difference \(\hat{a}_{i,{m^D}}\) between the observed output of the firm and the predicted output it would have obtained had it behaved as the “average” (representative) firm in its own technology group (i.e., within the group of firms using technology \(m^D\)).
Production functions estimation—stage 1 (dealing with simultaneity) The first step of our method deals with the simultaneity issue. As is well known, productivity estimation at the firm level suffers from endogeneity. The problem stems from the fact that the information incorporated in the productivity term \(a_{it}\), although unknown to the econometrician, is arguably used by the firm when the decision on the amount of inputs is made. In other words, inputs might be chosen simultaneously with output. This causes the OLS estimated error term to correlate with the amount of factors and thus biases the estimated production function coefficients (i.e., \(Cov(K_{i,t},a_{i,t})\ne 0\), \(Cov(L_{i,t},a_{i,t,})\ne 0\), with \(K_{i,t}\) and \(L_{i,t}\) being the total amount of fixed capital and labor employed by firm i at time t). Since our mixture regression framework builds on weighted least squares (see next paragraph), our estimated parameters are potentially biased. Moreover, in our case, the technology may be chosen simultaneously with the inputs. This would yield an additional source of simultaneity (i.e., \(Cov(K_{i,t},m_{i,t})\ne 0\), \(Cov(L_{i,t},m_{i,t})\ne 0\)) and make the bias even is more pervasive. However, the widely used semi-parametric solution suggested by Olley and Pakes (1996) as well as subsequent contributions (Levinsohn and Petrin 2003; Wooldridge 2009; Ackerberg et al. 2015) can hardly be applied to our mixture regression framework. Therefore, we deal with simultaneity using the following empirical approach suggested by Battisti et al. (2020). We assume that the capital and production technology in t are both decided in \(t-1\), based on one-time-lagged capital and a vector \(Z_{t}\) of external conditions (i.e., market frictions and other country characteristics such as interest rate and wage differentials). Labor is instead a freely adjustable input and its t level is decided in t on the basis of \(K_{i,t}\) and the observed productivity \(a_{i,t}\). This leaves us with the following system of equations (with the index in square brackets referring to the time period in which the decision is made):
$$\begin{aligned} \left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \ln K_{i,t}[t-1] = \rho _{0} + \rho _{1} \, \ln K_{i,t-1}[t-2] + Z_{c,t} + e_{i,t}^{K} + u_{i,t}^{K} \\ \\ \ln L_{i,t}[t] = \rho _{0} + \rho _{1} \, \ln K_{i,t}[t-1] + Z_{c,t} + e_{i,t}^{L} + u_{i,t}^{L}\end{array}\right. \end{aligned}$$
(2)
under the assumption that \(u_{i,t}^{K}\) and \(u_{i,t}^{L}\) are i.i.d. errors, \(e_{i,t}^{K}\) can be thought of as “absorbing” \(Cov(K_{i,t}[t-1],\) \(m_{i,t}[t-1])\) and \(Cov(K_{i,t}[t-1], a_{i,t-1})\), with \(e_{i,t}^{L}\) “absorbing” \(Cov(L_{i,t}[t], a_{i,t})\). As measures of the unobserved correlations, the estimated residuals, \(\hat{\Phi }_{i}=e_{i,t}^{K} + u_{i,t}^{K}\) and \(\hat{\Psi }_{i}=e_{i,t}^{L} + u_{i,t}^{L}\), can be included as additional regressors in the mixture regressions (Stage 2) to estimate potentially simultaneity-free production function parameters.
We estimate (2) sector-by-sector through three-stage least squares including country-year effects (to account for \(Z_{c,t}\)). The estimation, which requires two time periods, is carried out over the two years of 2009 and 2010, under the hypothesis that the technology to be used in 2010 is decided, together with the amount of capital, in 2009. This choice is consistent with the information on firms’ international characteristics used in Sect. 5, as this is collected as a cross section for the years before 2010 (firms were requested to report their engagement in international activities in 2008 or over the 2007–2009 period, depending on the question). At this stage, we do not disentangle across labor categories, as we are interested only in the whole residual to be used in the second step.
Production functions estimation—stage 2 To obtain technology-specific production function parameters, we estimate the following labor-intensive production function (index t is hereafter omitted) sector-by-sector:
$$\begin{aligned} y_{i}= & {} a_{i} + \alpha _{m} + \beta _{m}^{K} k_{i}^{\delta _{i,m}} + \beta _{m}^{W} w_{i}^{\delta _{i,m}} + \beta _{m}^{S} s_{i}^{\delta _{i,m}} + \beta _{m}^{U} u_{i}^{\delta _{i,m}} + \gamma _m r_i^{\delta _{i,m}}\nonumber \\&+ \varphi \hat{\Phi }_{i}^{\delta _{i,m}} + \psi \hat{\Psi }_{i}^{\delta _{i,m}} + \text {FE}_s + \eta _{i}, \end{aligned}$$
(3)
where labor (measured as number of employees) is disaggregated into three categories: white collar (\(w_{i}\)), skilled blue collar (\(s_{i}\)), unskilled blue collar (\(u_{i}\)). Moreover, \(r_i\) is the average wage paid by the firm, used to proxy for the human capital dimension left unexplained by disentangling across labor categories; technology is described by the parameter set \((\alpha _m,\beta _{m}^{K},\beta _{m}^{W},\beta _{m}^{S},\beta _{m}^{U})\), with the TFP term split into the idiosyncratic component \(a_{i}\) and the technology component \(\alpha _{m}\); \(\text {FE}_s\) are three-digit industry fixed effects; \(\eta _{i}\) is the i.i.d term.; and \(\delta _{i,m}\) are observation weights defined in (4). The probability distribution of \(y_i\) is modelled as the weighted average of the M unknown distributions, each with a proper mean (\(\mu _{m}\)) and variance (\(\sigma _{m}^2\)): \(f(Y_{i}|\mu ,\sigma ^2)=\sum ^M_{m=1}\omega _m f_m(Y_{i}|\mu _{m},\sigma _{m}^2)\). The unknown ex-ante probability of belonging to group m (i.e., \(\omega _m=\sum _{i} p_{i,m}/\sum _{m}\sum _{i} p_{i,m}\)) is dealt with by using the expectation-maximization (EM) algorithm to the weighted least squares estimation of Equation (3) (see De Sarbo and Cron 1988), where the observation weights are
$$\begin{aligned} \delta _{i,m}=\sqrt{p_{i,m}} \qquad \text {with} \quad p_{i,m} = \frac{\omega _m f_m\{y_i|\mu _m;\sigma ^2_m\}}{\sum _{m=1}^M \omega _m f_m\{y_i|\mu _m;\sigma ^2_m\}}. \end{aligned}$$
(4)
The (weighted least squares) estimation starts with random values of \(\omega _{m}\) to estimate (3) and compute posterior probabilities \(p_{i,m}\). These are used to update the weights \(\omega ^m\), and thus the regression coefficients in Eq. (3) in each step of the EM algorithm. The algorithm alternates the “M” step (production function estimation) and the “E” step (probabilities computation) until the log-likelihood converges. Under the assumption that the density functions of Eq. (4) follow a Gaussian distribution, the characterizing parameters are the weighted mean and the variance of the group regressions. We use the Bayesian Information Criterion (BIC), to ex-post determine the number M of clusters, as it helps us identify the best M in terms of avoiding a poor description of the population on the one hand and over-fitting on the other (Steele and Raftery 2010). The obtained BIC values are reported in Table 3.4
Table 3
Mixture regressions: BIC values
Sector
\(\hbox {BIC}_1\)
\(\hbox {BIC}_2\)
\(\hbox {BIC}_3\)
\(\hbox {BIC}_4\)
\(\hbox {BIC}_5\)
\(\hbox {BIC}_6\)
\(\hbox {BIC}_7\)
Fd
322.72
165.54
125.10
\(-\)19.94
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
TX
135.07
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
WA
64.20
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
LP
56.02
3.02
\(-\)62.73
\(-\)149.35
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
Wo
235.80
116.47
\(-\)25.17
\(-\)47.09
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
Pa
26.21
\(-\)1.60
\(-\)71.96
\(-\)125.53
\(-\)202.68
n.c.
n.c.
Pr
54.16
\(-\)58.78
\(-\)54.46
\(-\)151.38
\(-\)179.95
n.c.
n.c.
Ch
15.79
\(-\)88.28
\(-\)231.05
\(-\)301.93
\(-\)406.50
n.c.
n.c.
RP
58.92
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
NM
222.73
141.28
101.90
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
BM
96.11
\(-\)21.11
\(-\)93.31
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
MP
797.74
514.34
432.98
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
EP
48.00
\(-\)58.69
\(-\)77.97
\(-\)143.40
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
El
218.46
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
Ma
149.98
\(-\)28.76
\(-\)110.09
\(-\)181.30
\(-\)341.83
\(-\)453.41
n.c.
MV
55.60
4.88
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
Ot
222.71
55.38
15.41
\(-\)84.42
\(-\)268.34
n.c.
n.c.
Re
20.20
\(-\)40.59
\(-\)69.42
\(-\)146.50
n.c.
n.c.
n.c.
The estimation is carried out cross-sectionally for the year 2010 employing mixture models (McLachlan and Peel 2000) to recover a vector of production function parameters for each technology m. Mixture models allow us to avoid any ex-ante assumption on both the degree of technology sharing across firms and the number of available technologies, which are instead provided by the estimation routine. To give an intuition, the algorithm allows us to describe a production function process as being composed of several sub-processes, each of them with a set of parameters and with each firm having its own probability of belonging to one of these sets. Finally, in this framework, a “superior” technology is characterized by a parameter set \((\alpha _m,\beta _{m}^{K},\beta _{m}^{W},\beta _{m}^{S},\beta _{m}^{U})\) such that a higher output is produced at given input and TFP levels.5
Table 4 reports the estimated \(\alpha \) and \(\beta \) parameters for each technology group and sector. As the first column of this table shows, the number of technologies identified by our algorithm tends to be higher than one. Table 5 reports the total probability by technology group (computed as \(prob_m=\sum _{i} p_{i,m}\)). This gives a sense of the magnitude of each group (i.e., number of firms in a given group, with each firm accounting for a share equal to its own probability of belonging to that group). None of the groups is empty or close to it. It is worth noting that the final number of technologies is generally lower than that suggested by Table 3. This happens because, although the BIC is used in deciding the best fit in the mixture regressions, we constrain the \(\beta \) parameters to be statistically significant (while non-significant \(\alpha \) values are set to zero). For each firm, the probability of belonging to a discarded cluster is set to zero and is proportionally reallocated to the other sector clusters.
Table 4
Estimated production function parameters
sector
\(\alpha _1\)
\(\beta ^K_1\)
\(\beta ^{H}_1\)
\(\beta ^{S}_1\)
\(\beta ^{U}_1\)
\(\alpha _2\)
\(\beta ^K_2\)
\(\beta ^{H}_2\)
\(\beta ^{S}_2\)
\(\beta ^{U}_2\)
\(\alpha _3\)
\(\beta ^K_3\)
\(\beta ^{H}_3\)
\(\beta ^{S}_3\)
\(\beta ^{U}_3\)
Fd
0.855
0.301
0.134
0.308
0.309
0.455
0.330
0.242
0.220
0.167
0.432
0.499
0.285
0.161
0.217
TX
0.700
0.367
0.170
0.241
0.259
WA
0.888
0.397
0.211
0.127
0.160
LP
1.418
0.138
0.081
0.364
0.192
1.736
0.375
0.259
0.145
0.197
.
Wo
0
0.121
0.131
0.325
0.213
\(-\)0.017
0.458
0.119
0.119
0.166
Pa
0.758
0.234
0.154
0.433
0.419
0
0.318
0.193
0.343
0.092
Pr
0
0.054
0.268
0.298
0.214
0.739
0.464
0.235
0.107
0.337
Ch
0.574
0.232
0.223
0.159
0.317
0.271
0.377
0.078
0.173
0.354
RP
0.503
0.361
0.174
0.261
0.249
.
.
.
.
NM
0.762
0.323
0.169
0.336
0.320
.
.
.
.
BM
0.858
0.142
0.287
0.317
0.181
0.595
0.299
0.206
0.149
0.299
MP
0.688
0.335
0.075
0.455
0.165
0.979
0.363
0.179
0.182
0.367
EP
0.424
0.303
0.447
0.285
0.198
0
0.189
0.199
0.416
0.224
El
0.633
0.327
0.236
0.261
0.284
.
.
.
.
Ma
-0.140
0.502
0.033
0.029
0.064
0
0.472
0.062
0.112
0.193
0.840
0.293
0.209
0.172
0.333
MV
0
0.483
0.147
0.222
0.223
.
.
.
.
Ot
1.033
0.711
0.156
0.317
0.022
0.856
0.386
0.019
0.033
0.259
Re
0.574
0.193
0.268
0.181
0.331
0
0.515
0.350
0.200
0.461
0
0.412
0.103
0.012
0.287
Table 5
Mixture regressions: total probability by technology group (rounded values)
Sector
Prob 1
Prob 2
Prob 3
Fd
313
37
136
TX
131
WA
71
LP
26
52
Wo
25
161
Pa
37
32
Pr
19
44
73
Ch
36
113
RP
272
NM
201
BM
23
82
MP
257
629
EP
42
23
El
165
Ma
18
33
346
MV
83
Ot
273
Re
13
28
“Between” and “Within” TFP gaps Once the production function parameters are estimated for each technology available within each sector, they are used to predict the output levels of the firm under each technology and give the decomposition in (1) an order of magnitude. The locally optimal technology \(m^{H}\) at \(\mathbf {x}_{i}=\{k_{i}, w_{i}, s_{i}, u_{i}\}\) can be identified as the one, such that \(\hat{y}_{i,m^{H}}|\mathbf {x}_{i}>\hat{y}_{i,m}|\mathbf {x}_{i} \quad \forall m \ne m^{H}\). Moreover, since the technology actually used by firm i is unobservable, the under uncertainty equivalent \(\hat{y}_{i,m^D}\) in (1) (i.e., probabilistic predicted output), can be obtained as \(\sum _{m=1}^{m^{H}} p_{i,m} \cdot \hat{y}_{i,m}\) – that is, as a weighted average of the predicted output associated with each technology, with the weights represented by the probabilities \(p_i,m\) provided by the estimation algorithm.
Hence, we can define the “between-technology” TFP (i.e., BTFP) gap as the difference between firm i’s frontier output and firm i’s probabilistic predicted output (i.e., the weighted average of the estimated predicted output associated with each possible technology m):
$$\begin{aligned} \text {BTFP gap}_i=\hat{y}_{i,m^{H}} - \sum _{m=1}^{m^{H}} p_{i,m} \cdot \hat{y}_{i,m} \end{aligned}$$
(5)
We can define the “within-technology” TFP (i.e., WTFP) gap as the difference between firm i’s observed output and firm i’s probabilistic predicted output:
$$\begin{aligned} \text {WTFP gap}_i = \text {WTFP}^{B} - \text {WTFP}_i \qquad \text {with} \quad \text {WTFP}_i = y_i - \sum _{m=1}^{m^{H}} p_{i,m} \cdot \hat{y}_{i,m} \end{aligned}$$
(6)
where \(\text {WTFP}^{B}\) denotes the average WTFP of the best 5% of firms (in terms of WTFP) in the sector.6
Table 6 reports the sectoral estimates of both measures, in terms of average and standard deviation (columns 1 to 4).
Table 6
WTFP and BTFP gaps estimates: Sectoral averages
Sector
\(\widehat{\text {BTFP gap}}_i\)
\(\widehat{\text {WTFP gap}}_i\)
\(\widehat{\text {Ratio1}}_i\)
\(\widehat{\text {Ratio2}}_i\)
# tech
AVG
SD
AVG
SD
Fd
1.854
0.855
0.291
0.148
0.598
0.809
3
TX
0
0
0.470
0.264
0
0
1
WA
0
0
0.580
0.297
0
0
1
LP
1.679
0.961
0.354
0.196
0.482
0.745
2
Wo
1.789
0.792
0.375
0.294
0.607
0.788
2
Pa
1.544
0.883
0.280
0.129
0.500
0.763
2
Pr
2.123
0.905
0.222
0.149
0.628
0.858
3
Ch
1.871
0.925
0.395
0.177
0.590
0.763
2
RP
0
0
0.385
0.194
0
0
1
NM
0
0
0.703
0.423
0
0
1
BM
1.681
0.923
0.197
0.113
0.528
0.820
2
MP
1.747
0.813
0.378
0.184
0.587
0.766
2
EP
1.885
0.952
0.336
0.137
0.572
0.770
2
El
0
0
0.599
0.284
0
0
1
Ma
2.021
0.869
0.209
0.112
0.636
0.849
3
MV
0
0
0.417
0.193
0
0
1
Ot
1.784
0.864
0.466
0.255
0.590
0.737
3
Re
1.444
0.701
0.105
0.049
0.617
0.859
3
AVG
1.396
1.084
0.370
0.246
0.453
0.612
-
To obtain more detail about the technological dimension, we also report two additional BTFP indexes. The first one, obtained as \(\text {Ratio1}_i=\frac{\text {BTFP gap}_i}{\hat{y}_{i,m^{H}}-\hat{y}_{i,m^{L}}}\), where \(\hat{y}_{i,m^{L}}\) is firm i’s predicted output associated with using the worst technology, measures the extent to which the industry average BTFP gap is driven by sector-wide differences in the available technologies, as subsumed by the denominator (i.e., the gap based on predicted output using the best versus the worst technology). The second index gauges the relative importance of the technological dimension: \(\text {Ratio2}_i=\frac{\text {BTFP gap}_i}{\text {BTFP gap}_i+\text {WTFP gap}_i}\).
For ease of interpretation, the estimated number of technologies is reported in the last column of Table 6.
In general, the contribution of the WTFP and BTFP gaps to cross-firm output differences is quite unbalanced, with technological differences taking the lead as drivers of the output differences across firms, particularly in sectors in which three technologies are obtained (Fd, Pr, Ma, Re). This is highlighted by the high average values of Ratio2.
By widening the output differences associated with the available technologies (see Ratio1), a higher number of technologies tend to increase the BTFP gap on average (but not its dispersion).
Substantial intra-sectoral heterogeneity emerges from Figures 1 and 2, in which the sectoral distribution of the estimated BTFP and WTFP gaps is reported.
It is worth emphasizing that, in our methodology, the price-bias7 usually associated with firm level TFP estimates does not affect our BTFP gap measure (under the assumption that firms in different technology clusters do not systematically apply different prices), with all the cross-firm price (i.e., mark-up) dispersion flowing into the WTFP gap term. Moreover, as human capital heterogeneity is controlled for by disentangling across different types of workers and by including the average wage within the firm, we can safely attribute cross-firm BTFP gap heterogeneity to differences in technology in a strict sense (e.g., different machinery and software returns).
Taken together, these results suggest that the technology dimension tends to dominate. At the same time, however, there are many firms in which the output gap is determined mostly by the ability to use the adopted technology.
Next, we discuss how international activities correlate with both dimensions is discussed next.

5 Disentangling the productivity–internationalization relationship

This section examines whether the widely documented productivity advantage of international firms can be understood in terms of technological advantage, as it is usually done, or whether it is more a matter of know-how and ability to use the given technology. In the first case, we expect firms’ involvement in international activities to be correlated more with our BTFP gap measure than with WTFP gaps and vice versa, if technology is not the main driver of the productivity premium documented by the literature.
To this end, we focus on a vector of firm level measures of international exposure \(\mathbf{I}_i\) to estimate the following equation in different specifications
$$\begin{aligned} B_i=\zeta _0 + {\zeta }_I \mathbf{I}_i + {\zeta }_Z \mathbf{Z}_i + F_c + F_s + \epsilon _i \end{aligned}$$
(7)
where \(B_i\) is, in turn, standard TFP (to reproduce the standard results in the literature), \(\text {BTFP gap}_i\), and \(\text {WTFP gap}_i\); \({{Z}}_i\) is a vector of firm level controls; and \(F_c\) and \(F_s\) are country and sector fixed effects. \({\zeta }_I\) is a vector of parameters that, though not entailing causality, reflect the empirical correlation of the productivity dimension of interest with the different types of international exposure.
To measure the international exposure of firms, we exploit the detailed information collected by the EFIGE survey, which is used to classify firms along seven (non-mutually exclusive) categories: exporters, importers of services, importers of materials, FDI undertakers, passive and active outsourcers, and global exporters. A dummy for each category is created. Clearly, if a firm is not involved in any of these activities, all the related dummies are equal to zero, and the firm is considered to be non-active abroad. Firms are considered exporters/importers if they have sold/bought abroad some or all of their own products/services in 2008. With respect to FDI and international outsourcing, the survey includes a question asking whether firms were running at least part of their production activity in another country: firms replying “yes, through direct investment (i.e. foreign affiliates/controlled firms)” are considered to be undertaking FDI, while firms replying “yes, through contracts and arm’s length agreements with local firms” are considered to be pursuing an active international outsourcing strategy. Firms replying positively to a question asking whether part of their turnover is made up by sales produced according to a specific order coming from a customer (produced-to-order goods) and indicating that their main customers for the production-to-order activity are other firms located abroad are considered to be pursuing a passive outsourcing strategy. Hence, a passive outsourcer is the counterpart of an active outsourcer in an arm’s length transaction. Finally, global exporters are firms that export to countries outside the EU.
To set a benchmark, we start by considering the correlation of the seven characteristics above with a standard TFP measure computed following Wooldridge (2009), i.e., without controlling for technological heterogeneity.8 Table 7 reports the estimation output. The first column reports the coefficients estimated in separate regressions with country and sector fixed effects. The positive sign highlights the higher TFP characterizing the internationalized firms: this is the TFP premium highlighted by the literature in the field (see Altomonte and Aquilante 2012 for consistent estimates on the same data).
Table 7
International exposure and Wooldridge-estimated TFP
 
(1)*
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
Exporter
0.122***
0.042
0.023
0.037
0.042
(0.023)
(0.026)
(0.025)
(0.026)
(0.026)
Importer of services
0.165***
0.104***
0.059*
0.061**
0.061**
(0.023)
(0.023)
(0.023)
(0.024)
(0.024)
Importer of materials
0.113***
0.049*
0.015
0.018
0.021
(0.019)
(0.021)
(0.020)
(0.021)
(0.021)
FDI
0.294***
0.219***
0.130**
0.111*
0.107*
(0.048)
(0.048)
(0.049)
(0.050)
(0.049)
Passive outsourcer
0.113***
0.056*
0.048*
0.03
0.029
(0.020)
(0.022)
(0.022)
(0.022)
(0.022)
Active outsourcer
0.229***
0.167**
0.161**
0.158**
0.140**
(0.053)
(0.051)
(0.049)
(0.050)
(0.051)
Global exporter
0.089***
0.01
\(-\)0.024
\(-\)0.036
\(-\)0.04
(0.021)
(0.023)
(0.022)
(0.023)
(0.023)
Non-active abroad
\(-\)0.124***
    
(\(-\)0.025)
    
Age
  
0
0
0
  
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
Small-medium
  
0.191***
0.180***
0.042
  
(0.022)
(0.023)
(0.042)
Medium
  
0.402***
0.387***
0.151**
  
(0.030)
(0.031)
(0.052)
Large
  
0.512***
0.470***
0.281**
  
(0.055)
(0.054)
(0.089)
China
   
\(-\)0.789
\(-\)2.078***
   
(0.464)
(0.515)
Small-medium*China
    
1.212***
    
(0.313)
Medium*China
    
2.101***
    
(0.362)
Large*China
    
1.779**
    
(0.613)
Const
 
1.027***
0.680***
0.697***
0.848***
 
(0.147)
(0.155)
(0.163)
(0.168)
N
3426
3426
3417
3150
3150
adj. \(R^2\)
 
0.409
0.444
0.392
0.398
*Coefficients in Column (1) are estimated in separate regressions.
Robust standard errors are in parentheses. All variables are in logs. OLS regressions. Country and sector FE included in all regressions. Size classes defined in terms of number of employees: Small (10–19), Small-Medium (20–49), Medium (50–250), Large (>250). China: share of imports from China wrt total imports in the country-sector. Statistical significance: *\(p<0.10\), **\(p<0.05\), ***\(p<0.01\)
In columns 2–4, the seven characteristics (with the non-active-abroad firms set as the excluded category) are considered all together, in a short horse-race aimed at identifying the main markers of the productivity premium. As well as including country and sector fixed effects, we also consider firm age and size; in columns (4) and (5), we also control for how much the country-sector in which the firm operates is under pressure due to import competition (with data drawn from COMTRADE). To do this, we consider the share of imports from China in country-sector total imports. Moreover, four size categories are considered: small (10–19 employees), small-medium (20–49), medium (50–250), and large (>250). Larger firms are significantly more productive, particularly when operating in sectors featuring fiercer import competition from China. However, the exporter status loses significance when more complex specifications are used: the more productive firms seem to be those classified as active outsourcers and importers of services, as well as those involved in FDI activity.
Against the backdrop of these standard results, Tables 8 and 9 show the results on whether and how the significance in analogous regressions changes when standard TFP is replaced by our BTFP gap (see Table 8) and WTFP gap (see Table 9) measures.
Table 8
International exposure and BTFP gaps
 
(1)*
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
Exporter
\(-\)0.463***
\(-\)0.157***
\(-\)0.086**
\(-\)0.084**
\(-\)0.085**
(0.037)
(0.042)
(0.029)
(0.031)
(0.031)
Importer of services
\(-\)0.513***
\(-\)0.253***
\(-\)0.05
\(-\)0.054
\(-\)0.052
(0.045)
(0.046)
(0.030)
(0.032)
(0.032)
Importer of materials
\(-\)0.457***
\(-\)0.241***
\(-\)0.081***
\(-\)0.076**
\(-\)0.073**
(0.035)
(0.036)
(0.024)
(0.025)
(0.025)
FDI
\(-\)1.077***
\(-\)0.798***
\(-\)0.253***
\(-\)0.273***
\(-\)0.263***
(0.099)
(0.099)
(0.053)
(0.055)
(0.055)
Passive outsourcer
\(-\)0.356***
\(-\)0.07
\(-\)0.022
\(-\)0.022
\(-\)0.021
(0.038)
(0.042)
(0.027)
(0.029)
(0.029)
Active outsourcer
\(-\)0.476***
\(-\)0.199
\(-\)0.071
\(-\)0.103
\(-\)0.083
(0.117)
(0.113)
(0.061)
(0.069)
(0.068)
Global exporter
\(-\)0.530***
\(-\)0.297***
\(-\)0.117***
\(-\)0.115***
\(-\)0.113***
(0.041)
(0.043)
(0.028)
(0.030)
(0.030)
Non-active abroad
0.496***
    
(\(-\)0.039)
    
Age
  
\(-\)0.002**
\(-\)0.002**
\(-\)0.002**
  
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
Small-medium
  
\(-\)0.680***
\(-\)0.683***
\(-\)0.688***
  
(0.024)
(0.025)
(0.047)
Medium
  
\(-\)1.772***
\(-\)1.803***
\(-\)1.723***
  
(0.037)
(0.038)
(0.062)
Large
  
\(-\)2.594***
\(-\)2.619***
\(-\)2.402***
  
(0.049)
(0.051)
(0.076)
China
   
1.05
1.376*
   
(0.591)
(0.636)
Small-medium*China
    
0.031
    
(0.359)
Medium*China
    
\(-\)0.729
    
(0.443)
Large*China
    
\(-\)2.323***
    
(0.574)
Const
\(-\)
\(-\)1.291***
0.328
0.557***
0.470***
\(-\)
(0.175)
(0.203)
(0.132)
(0.132)
N
2646
2646
2641
2367
2367
Adj. \(R^2\)
\(-\)
0.322
0.704
0.709
0.71
* Coefficients in Column (1) are estimated in separate regressions.
Robust standard errors are in parentheses. All variables are in logs. OLS regressions. Country and sector FE included in all regressions. Size classes defined in terms of number of employees: Small (10-19), Small-Medium (20-49), Medium (50-250), Large (>250). China: share of imports from China wrt total imports in the country-sector. Statistical significance: *\(p<0.10\), **\(p<0.05\), ***\(p<0.01\)
Table 9
International exposure and WTFP gaps
 
(1)*
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
Exporter
\(-\)0.021
\(-\)0.026
\(-\)0.035
\(-\)0.037
\(-\)0.04
(0.037)
(0.044)
(0.044)
(0.046)
(0.046)
Importer of services
0.033
0.033
0.026
0.021
0.021
(0.040)
(0.043)
(0.043)
(0.044)
(0.044)
Importer of materials
0.018
0.019
0.008
0.034
0.033
(0.034)
(0.037)
(0.038)
(0.039)
(0.039)
FDI
0.032
0.025
\(-\)0.001
\(-\)0.068
\(-\)0.068
(0.079)
(0.081)
(0.083)
(0.087)
(0.087)
Passive outsourcer
0.001
0.017
0.017
0.005
0.007
(0.035)
(0.041)
(0.041)
(0.042)
(0.042)
Active outsourcer
0.123
0.12
0.111
0.116
0.122
(0.099)
(0.099)
(0.098)
(0.107)
(0.107)
Global exporter
\(-\)0.044
\(-\)0.056
\(-\)0.059
\(-\)0.054
\(-\)0.051
(0.038)
(0.042)
(0.042)
(0.044)
(0.044)
Non-active abroad
0.012
    
(\(-\)0.042)
    
Age
  
0.002**
0.002**
0.002**
  
(0.001)
(0.001)
(0.001)
Small-medium
  
0.072
0.033
0.099
  
(0.040)
(0.041)
(0.078)
Medium
  
0.051
0.029
0.161
  
(0.053)
(0.055)
(0.094)
Large
  
0.109
0.085
0.121
  
(0.094)
(0.095)
(0.145)
China
   
0.378
1.027
   
(0.784)
(0.910)
Small-medium*China
    
\(-\)0.587
    
(0.572)
Medium*China
    
\(-\)1.178
    
(0.673)
hLarge*China
    
\(-\)0.284
    
(1.125)
Const
\(-\)
\(-\)0.217
\(-\)0.354
\(-\)0.392
\(-\)0.457*
\(-\)
(0.193)
(0.203)
(0.208)
(0.213)
N
3480
3480
3471
3197
3197
Adj. \(R^2\)
\(-\)
0.069
0.071
0.076
0.076
*Coefficients in Column (1) are estimated in separate regressions.
Robust standard errors are in parentheses. All variables are in logs. OLS regressions. Country and sector FE included in all regressions. Size classes defined in terms of number of employees: Small (10–19), Small-medium (20–49), medium (50–250), large (>250). China: share of imports from China wrt total imports in the country-sector. Statistical significance: *\(p<0.10\), **\(p<0.05\), ***\(p<0.01\)
Comparing Tables 8 and 9 with Table 7 clearly shows that, while the explanatory power of the country-sector controls is broadly unaffected, the significance of all the internationalization dummies vanishes when WTFP gaps are considered, while the correlation is even stronger with the BTFP gaps. In particular, the technology advantage is found to be particularly important for the firms undertaking FDI, for global exporters, importers of materials and, finally, for exporters.
Firms operating in country-sectors relatively more exposed to competitive pressure from China are not significantly less productive. At the same time, large firms operating in those country-sectors display significant technology advantages, consistent with the evidence provided by Bloom et al. (2016). As for the BTFP gaps, size strongly matters in all specifications, with larger firms found to produce with better technologies. Interestingly, firm age appears to be non-significant in the standard TFP regressions because it acts in opposite directions in terms of between-technology and within-technology productivity dimensions, with younger firms characterized by lower BTFP gaps and higher WTFP gaps. This suggests that technology is more accessible to young firms but also that they need time to accumulate experience in using it.
We next focus on the geographical articulation of the between-technology premiums premium. The results are reported in Tables from 10, 11, 12, 1314. The significance of the technology advantage associated with being an exporter is driven by firms exporting to EU countries and, among the global exporters, by firms exporting to China. The same is true for FDI. Regarding importer status, the technology gaps are significantly lower in firms importing from within the EU and from China, and for the importers of services. Finally, in Table 14, we disentangle the China competition effect by exploiting information on the countries in which the firm has competitors. The more technologically advanced firms seem to be those operating in competition with the USA and other EU countries. Interestingly, having competitors located in China tends to be associated with higher technology gaps. This effect persists also when the interaction with size is controlled for (see the last column of Table 14). However, the technology gap is significantly lower when having competitors in China is coupled with a larger size (consistently with the results in column 4).
Table 10
BTFP gaps: geography of exports
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
Exporter EU
\(-\)0.389***
\(-\)0.121***
\(-\)0.127***
\(-\)0.127***
(0.05)
(0.03)
(0.03)
(0.03)
Exporter Europe not EU
\(-\)0.047
\(-\)0.012
0.003
0.003
(0.06)
(0.04)
(0.04)
(0.04)
Exporter CHN
\(-\)0.164**
\(-\)0.106**
\(-\)0.092**
\(-\)0.085*
(0.07)
(0.04)
(0.05)
(0.05)
Exporter US
\(-\)0.239***
\(-\)0.114***
\(-\)0.108**
\(-\)0.095**
(0.08)
(0.04)
(0.05)
(0.05)
Age
 
\(-\)0.002**
\(-\)0.002**
\(-\)0.002***
 
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
Small-medium
 
\(-\)0.711***
\(-\)0.711***
\(-\)0.720***
 
(0.02)
(0.02)
(0.05)
Medium
 
\(-\)1.854***
\(-\)1.881***
\(-\)1.781***
 
(0.04)
(0.04)
(0.06)
Large
 
\(-\)2.734***
\(-\)2.761***
\(-\)2.515***
 
(0.05)
(0.05)
(0.08)
China
  
1.066*
1.464**
  
(0.61)
(0.66)
Small-medium*China
   
0.066
   
(0.37)
Medium*China
   
\(-\)0.886*
   
(0.46)
Large*China
   
\(-\)2.579***
   
(0.58)
Const
\(-\)1.579***
0.305
0.537***
0.439***
(0.20)
(0.22)
(0.16)
(0.16)
N
2646.000
2641.000
2367.000
2367.000
Adj. \(R^2\)
0.227
0.695
0.700
0.701
Standard errors in parentheses
*\(p<0.10\), **\(p<0.05\), ***\(p<0.01\)
Dependent variable: BTFP. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. All variables are in logs. OLS regressions. Country and sector FE included in all regressions. Size classes defined in terms of number of employees: Small (10–19), Small-Medium (20–49), Medium (50–250), Large (>250). China: share of imports from China wrt total imports in the country-sector. Statistical significance: *\(p<0.10\), **\(p<0.05\), ***\(p<0.01\)
Table 11
BTFP gaps: geography of FDI
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
FDI EU
\(-\)0.819***
\(-\)0.280***
\(-\)0.276***
\(-\)0.259***
(0.14)
(0.07)
(0.07)
(0.08)
FDI Europe not EU
\(-\)0.158
0.112
0.100
0.067
(0.25)
(0.12)
(0.15)
(0.14)
FDI CHN
\(-\)0.450***
\(-\)0.097
\(-\)0.054
\(-\)0.036
(0.17)
(0.09)
(0.11)
(0.11)
FDI US
\(-\)0.673***
\(-\)0.248**
\(-\)0.293***
\(-\)0.310***
(0.22)
(0.11)
(0.08)
(0.08)
Age
 
\(-\)0.002**
\(-\)0.002**
\(-\)0.002***
 
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
Small-medium
 
\(-\)0.719***
\(-\)0.718***
\(-\)0.730***
 
(0.02)
(0.02)
(0.05)
Medium
 
\(-\)1.868***
\(-\)1.899***
\(-\)1.789***
 
(0.04)
(0.04)
(0.06)
Large
 
\(-\)2.705***
\(-\)2.729***
\(-\)2.485***
 
(0.05)
(0.05)
(0.08)
China
  
1.030*
1.445**
  
(0.60)
(0.65)
Small-medium*China
   
0.088
   
(0.36)
Medium*China
   
\(-\)0.978**
   
(0.46)
Large*China
   
\(-\)2.554***
   
(0.58)
Const
\(-\)1.811***
0.220
0.443***
0.345**
(0.16)
(0.21)
(0.15)
(0.15)
N
2646.000
2641.000
2367.000
2367.000
Adj. \(R^2\)
0.229
0.694
0.698
0.700
Standard errors in parentheses
*\(p<0.10\), **\(p<0.05\), ***\(p<0.01\)
Dependent variable: BTFP. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. All variables are in logs. OLS regressions. Country and sector FE included in all regressions. Size classes defined in terms of number of employees: Small (10–19), small-medium (20–49), medium (50–250), large (>250). China: share of imports from China wrt total imports in the country-sector. Statistical significance: *\(p<0.10\), **\(p<0.05\), ***\(p<0.01\)
Table 12
BTFP gaps: geography of imports of services
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
Importer services EU
\(-\)0.611***
\(-\)0.096*
\(-\)0.099*
\(-\)0.095*
(0.08)
(0.05)
(0.05)
(0.05)
Importer services Europe not EU
\(-\)0.072
\(-\)0.201*
\(-\)0.231**
\(-\)0.235**
(0.22)
(0.10)
(0.12)
(0.12)
Importer services CHN
\(-\)0.233
\(-\)0.234**
\(-\)0.250**
\(-\)0.211*
(0.19)
(0.09)
(0.11)
(0.11)
Importer services US
0.011
0.054
0.073
0.076
(0.22)
(0.11)
(0.12)
(0.12)
Age
 
\(-\)0.002**
\(-\)0.002**
\(-\)0.002***
 
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
Small-medium
 
\(-\)0.715***
\(-\)0.715***
\(-\)0.732***
 
(0.02)
(0.02)
(0.05)
Medium
 
\(-\)1.871***
\(-\)1.899***
\(-\)1.800***
 
(0.04)
(0.04)
(0.06)
Large
 
\(-\)2.734***
\(-\)2.761***
\(-\)2.532***
 
(0.05)
(0.05)
(0.08)
China
  
1.161*
1.504**
  
(0.60)
(0.65)
Small-medium*China
   
0.139
   
(0.37)
Medium*China
   
\(-\)0.880*
   
(0.46)
Large*China
   
\(-\)2.422***
   
(0.59)
Const
\(-\)1.561***
0.280
0.510***
0.416***
(0.16)
(0.21)
(0.15)
(0.15)
N
2646.000
2641.000
2367.000
2367.000
Adj. \(R^2\)
0.222
0.693
0.698
0.699
Standard errors in parentheses
*\(p<0.10\), **\(p<0.05\), ***\(p<0.01\)
Dependent variable: BTFP. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. All variables are in logs. OLS regressions. Country and sector FE included in all regressions. Size classes defined in terms of number of employees: Small (10–19), small-medium (20–49), medium (50–250), large (>250). China: share of imports from China wrt total imports in the country-sector. Statistical significance: *\(p<0.10\), **\(p<0.05\), ***\(p<0.01\)
Table 13
BTFP gaps: geography of imports of materials
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
Importer materials EU
\(-\)0.331***
\(-\)0.124***
\(-\)0.128***
\(-\)0.128***
(0.04)
(0.02)
(0.03)
(0.03)
Importer materials Europe not EU
\(-\)0.297***
\(-\)0.069
\(-\)0.098*
\(-\)0.096*
(0.09)
(0.05)
(0.06)
(0.06)
Importer materials CHN
\(-\)0.291***
\(-\)0.084**
\(-\)0.062
\(-\)0.042
(0.06)
(0.04)
(0.04)
(0.04)
Importer materials US
\(-\)0.183*
\(-\)0.060
\(-\)0.058
\(-\)0.055
(0.10)
(0.05)
(0.05)
(0.05)
Age
 
\(-\)0.002**
\(-\)0.002**
\(-\)0.002***
 
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
Small-medium
 
\(-\)0.703***
\(-\)0.703***
\(-\)0.709***
 
(0.02)
(0.02)
(0.05)
Medium
 
\(-\)1.833***
\(-\)1.862***
\(-\)1.770***
 
(0.04)
(0.04)
(0.06)
Large
 
\(-\)2.694***
\(-\)2.720***
\(-\)2.484***
 
(0.05)
(0.05)
(0.08)
China
  
1.211**
1.583**
  
(0.60)
(0.65)
Small-medium*China
   
0.039
   
(0.37)
Medium*China
   
\(-\)0.838*
   
(0.46)
Large*China
   
\(-\)2.509***
   
(0.59)
Const
\(-\)1.685***
0.254
0.486***
0.391**
(0.18)
(0.21)
(0.16)
(0.15)
N
2646.000
2641.000
2367.000
2367.000
Adj. \(R^2\)
0.252
0.697
0.702
0.703
Standard errors in parentheses
*\(p<0.10\), **\(p<0.05\), ***\(p<0.01\)
Dependent variable: BTFP. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. All variables are in logs. OLS regressions. Country and sector FE included in all regressions. Size classes defined in terms of number of employees: Small (10–19), small-medium (20–49), medium (50–250), Large (>250). China: share of imports from China wrt total imports in the country-sector. Statistical significance: *\(p<0.10\), **\(p<0.05\), ***\(p<0.01\)
Table 14
BTFP gaps: geography of competitors
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
Competitors EU
0.010
\(-\)0.079
\(-\)0.055
\(-\)0.049
\(-\)0.082
(0.10)
(0.06)
(0.06)
(0.06)
(0.06)
Competitors Europe not EU
\(-\)0.088
\(-\)0.001
0.009
0.003
0.002
(0.07)
(0.04)
(0.04)
(0.04)
(0.04)
Competitors CHN
0.051
0.057**
0.059**
0.060**
0.125***
(0.05)
(0.03)
(0.03)
(0.03)
(0.04)
Competitors US
\(-\)0.298***
\(-\)0.136***
\(-\)0.151***
\(-\)0.139***
\(-\)0.130***
(0.07)
(0.04)
(0.04)
(0.04)
(0.04)
Age
 
\(-\)0.002**
\(-\)0.002**
\(-\)0.002***
\(-\)0.002**
 
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
(0.00)
Small-Medium
 
\(-\)0.722***
\(-\)0.722***
\(-\)0.741***
\(-\)0.705***
 
(0.02)
(0.02)
(0.05)
(0.03)
Medium
 
\(-\)1.879***
\(-\)1.908***
\(-\)1.816***
\(-\)1.855***
 
(0.04)
(0.04)
(0.06)
(0.04)
Large
 
\(-\)2.764***
\(-\)2.788***
\(-\)2.542***
\(-\)2.716***
 
(0.04)
(0.05)
(0.08)
(0.05)
China
  
1.107*
1.429**
 
  
(0.61)
(0.66)
 
Small-medium*China
   
0.160
 
   
(0.37)
 
Medium*China
   
\(-\)0.821*
 
   
(0.46)
 
Large*China
   
\(-\)2.571***
 
   
(0.57)
 
Small-medium*Competitors CHN
    
\(-\)0.081
    
(0.06)
Medium*Competitors CHN
    
\(-\)0.104
    
(0.07)
Large*Competitors CHN
    
\(-\)0.198**
    
(0.09)
Const
\(-\)1.776***
0.341
0.540***
0.441***
0.343
(0.20)
(0.22)
(0.17)
(0.17)
(0.22)
N
2646.000
2641.000
2367.000
2367.000
2641.000
Adj. \(R^2\)
0.202
0.693
0.697
0.699
0.693
Standard errors in parentheses
*\(p<0.10\), **\(p<0.05\), ***\(p<0.01\)
Dependent variable: BTFP. Robust standard errors are in parentheses. All variables are in logs. OLS regressions. Country and sector FE included in all regressions. Size classes defined in terms of number of employees: Small (10-19), Small-Medium (20-49), Medium (50-250), Large (>250). China: share of imports from China wrt total imports in the country-sector. Statistical significance: *\(p<0.10\), **\(p<0.05\), ***\(p<0.01\)

6 Conclusions

In the standard TFP concept, the notion of productivity includes several hard-to-measure factors—namely, all the differences in output not explained by different input choices. Studying the role played by the technological dimension, within this general notion of productivity is gaining increasing interest, particularly from a policy perspective. Cross-firm productivity heterogeneity is commonly understood in terms of “technological” heterogeneity but lacks a clear interpretation. One of the fields in which this issue is particularly pervasive is international economics, where the firms exposed to international markets are usually found to be more productive than domestic firms. Regardless of the direction of causality, this productivity premium is commonly attributed to a superior technology level, although “it should be recognized that very technologically advanced firms might not necessarily appear as the globally most productive or the most successful in terms of profits” (OECD 2015, p. 33). The literature on the technological dimension of productivity is sparse, chiefly because estimating technology-specific production function parameters is a daunting task with standard econometrics, without an ex-ante assumption on the technology used by each firm. In standard estimates (producing sector-specific estimates), the factor parameter differences not accounted for in the estimation flow entirely into the Solow residual.
This study has built on the mixture regression analysis discussed in Battisti et al. (2020) to unbundle between-technology and within-technology TFP by estimating technology-specific production functions and to disentangle technological and within-technology productivity gaps across firms. Technology gaps are measures of the output loss associated with not using the best technology, given the level of inputs, while within-technology TFP gaps can be considered measures of the ability to use the given technology. Our analysis takes advantage of detailed information on labor types (which is key to controlling for human capital) and on firms’ international operations (which is exploited to study the productivity–internationalization relationship) provided by the EFIGE database.
The estimation points to a sectoral number of technologies ranging from one to three, depending on the sector. We also find, although with some cross-sector variability, that technology gaps are more than three times larger than within-technology TFP gaps on average. A non-significant relationship between international exposure and within-technology TFP gaps is found, while the relationship with the between-technology gaps is strongly significant. In particular, the technology advantage is significant for firms undertaking FDI, for global exporters, importers of materials and exporters. The significance of the technology advantage is driven mainly by operations with other EU countries and, among global exporters, by exporting to China. The most technologically advanced firms generally seem to be those operating in competition with the USA and other EU countries. Interestingly, while the firms operating in country-sectors relatively more exposed to competitive pressure from China do not seem to feature relatively higher within-technology productivity gaps, large firms operating in those country-sectors display significant technology advantages. Size strongly matters in technology adoption process, with larger firms producing with better technologies. Interestingly, age displays the opposite correlations, with younger firms using better technologies but less effectively. This result suggests that technology is more accessible to young firms but that they need time to accumulate experience in using it.
From a policy perspective, the overall picture produced by our estimates supports the common interpretation of the productivity gap among less internationalized firms in terms of distance from the technological frontier. In addition, our analysis allows for more granular policy implications than previous studies do because it allows us to disentangle the specific correlation between given firm characteristics on the one hand and both the technology choices and the ability to use the adopted technology on the other hand. Our results suggest that helping young firms learn to use new technologies more quickly is more important than improving the technology adoption process. Furthermore, as larger firms are found to react more positively to external competition than their smaller counterparts, policy initiatives may consider creating instruments designed specifically to encourage the technological upgrade of smaller internationalized firms (e.g., institutional incentives for technological sharing in firm networks, technological partnerships, shared patent portfolios). While a policy oriented discussion of our findings is outside the scope of this study, its implications are suggestive and should stimulate further empirical and methodological investigation into the empirical relationships between technology driven TFP and within-technology productivity.

Acknowledgements

Open access funding provided by Università degli Studi G. D’Annunzio Chieti Pescara within the CRUI-CARE Agreement.

Compliance with ethical standards

Conflict of interest

Author Michele Battisti declares that he has no conflict of interest. Author Filippo Belloc declares that he has no conflict of interest. Author Massimo Del Gatto declares that he has no conflict of interest.

Ethical approval

This article does not contain any studies with human participants or animals performed by any of the authors.
Open AccessThis article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Anhänge

Appendix: Relationship with the Wooldridge estimation

Among the issues highlighted by the literature on estimating production functions, recent works have focused on simultaneity bias. The source of simultaneity bias is the fact that information on actual productivity, although unknown to the econometrician, is known to the firm when it decides on the amount of inputs. This biases the production function parameters obtained through the least squares estimates because of the potential correlation between the regressors and error term.
A successful stratagem suggested by the literature for addressing this issue consists of recovering the \(a_i\) component from the traces it leaves in the observed behavior of the firm. Key studies examining this approach, which is commonly referred to as the proxy variable method, include the semi-parametric approach put forward by Olley and Pakes (1996), Levinsohn and Petrin (2003), and Ackerberg et al. (2006) as well as the GMM estimation adopted by Wooldridge (2009) used in the analysis as a benchmark estimation under the assumption of no heterogeneity in terms of production function parameters9. The basic idea of this methodology consists of identifying a (proxy) variable that reacts to the changes in TFP observed by a firm and is thus a function of these changes. Insofar as this function is invertible, its inverse may be calculated and plugged into the production function-estimating equation. Olley and Pakes (1996) suggest resorting to investment as a proxy, whereas Levinsohn and Petrin (2003) use intermediates. Doraszelski and Jaumandreu (2012), who extend Olley and Pakes (1996), show that a firm’s TFP is stochastically affected by its investment in knowledge (considered in terms of R&D).10
The implementation of such a semi-parametric approach within our mixture model framework raises identification problems. In particular, the way in which the proxy variable (either investment or materials) reacts to changes in technology and TFP should be specified separately because firms’ input choices may be differently correlated with the technology parameters and firms’ TFP. Our model of technology adoption developed in Sect. 4 is meant to deal with these two sources of simultaneity separately, without the need to rely on a specific proxy variable.
Similarly to the semi-parametric strategy, our approach to simultaneity entails a two-step estimation. However, instead of trying to include the whole productivity term (as proxied by the inverted investment or intermediates demand function) in the production function, our strategy seeks to take its effect (on the capital and labor choice) into account by controlling for its covariance with labor and capital. We exploit the fact that the correlations between capital and technology as well as between either capital or labor and TFP flow into the residuals of the system of equations in Eq. (2), consisting of the K policy function and static condition for L. Once estimated, these residuals allow us to control for simultaneity in the mixture analysis. As well as controlling for the simultaneity caused by idiosyncratic TFP, this strategy can control for any other factor affecting the input choice through the relationships in Eq. (2). This aspect is particularly relevant in light of the results provided by Gandhi et al. (2018) on the identification problems characterizing the semi-parametric approach. Such problems stem from the circumstance that even when the invertibility conditions (for the proxy variable demand function) identified by the literature are satisfied, it is still possible to construct a continuum of observationally equivalent production functions that cannot be distinguished from the true production function in the data.11 By not resorting to any proxy variable, our approach is in principle immune to this order of problems.
Second, our timing of input choice is strictly in line with Olley and Pakes (1996), with labor dealt with as a “perfectly variable” input decided at the time of production. While this is also true in Levinsohn and Petrin (2003), Ackerberg et al. (2015) highlight the collinearity problems associated with such decision timing and suggest a slightly different specification in which labor is a “less variable” input than intermediates chosen one “subperiod” before productivity is observed. This implies that differently from Olley and Pakes (1996) and Levinsohn and Petrin (2003), in which the labor and capital coefficients are identified in the first and second steps respectively, the first step is only used to net the output function of the idiosyncratic productivity (and in our case also technology) shock, with both the capital and the labor coefficients retrieved in the second stage.12 Although we use the same timing of input choice as Olley and Pakes (1996) and Levinsohn and Petrin (2003), our approach is not subject to the Ackerberg et al. (2015) critique, as both coefficients are estimated in the second stage in our case.

First-stage estimation

In this Section we report the output of the first-stage of our estimation algorithm. According to (2), the output consists of the coefficients of the two regressors \(\ln K_{i,t-1}[t-2]\) and \(\ln K_{i,t}[t-1]\). The estimation is carried out (sector-by-sector) through three-stage least squares (including country-year effects): the endogenous explanatory variable \(\ln K_{i,t}[t-1]\) in the second equation is simultaneously estimated as the dependent variable from the first equation. Figures are reported, together with standard errors, in Table 15.
Table 15
First-stage estimation output
Sector
\(\ln K_{i,t-1}[t-2]\)
\(\ln K_{i,t}[t-1]\)
Coef
SE
Coef
SE
Fd
0.480
0.024
0.997
0.006
TX
0.478
0.040
1.003
0.016
WA
0.179
0.075
1.023
0.026
LP
0.365
0.053
0.964
0.017
Wo
0.599
0.041
0.967
0.014
Pa
0.502
0.053
0.995
0.013
Pr
0.483
0.050
1.018
0.017
Ch
0.604
0.039
1.024
0.012
RP
0.617
0.032
0.996
0.010
NM
0.529
0.029
0.986
0.010
BM
0.607
0.051
0.890
0.044
MP
0.581
0.017
0.976
0.007
EP
0.536
0.076
0.964
0.031
El
0.663
0.042
0.988
0.018
Ma
0.659
0.021
0.991
0.008
MV
0.792
0.039
1.012
0.015
Ot
0.542
0.030
0.991
0.011
Re
0.499
0.062
1.022
0.022
We also report in Fig. 3 the overall distribution of the estimated \(\hat{\Phi }_{i}\) and \(\hat{\Psi }_{i}\), which are then used in the second stage in order to control for simultaneity.
Fußnoten
1
Doraszelski and Jaumandreu (2013) assume that firm productivity evolves according to a Markov process, which is “shifted” (either positively or negatively) by R&D expenditure. Following Olley and Pakes (1996), including the R&D choice entails taking an additional policy function (besides the policy function for investment in physical capital) into account. Under the crucial assumption that the error in t is uncorrelated with the innovation choice in \(t-1\), R&D can be exploited in the production function estimation to purge the estimates from the part of the error correlated with the input choice. Loosely speaking, this approach enables us to estimate firms’ TFP while controlling for simultaneity and the effect of innovation choices at the same time.
 
2
Another line of research investigates technology diffusion in more detail using data on specific technologies. In particular, it is worth citing the Cross-country Historical Adoption of Technology (CHAT) dataset, described in Comin and Hobijn (2009), which includes long-run information on the extensive (whether a specific technology is present or not in a given country at a particular time) and intensive (the intensity with which producers or consumers employ a technology, at a given moment in time, scaled by the size of the economy) margins of technology adoption at the country-level on a number of technologies (e.g. tractors, fertilizer, portable cell phones). The CHAT dataset enables, among others, Comin and Hobijn (2010) to explain the very different speeds at which countries recovered after wars, Cervellati et al. (2014) to study the effect of trade liberalization and democratization on technology adoption, and Comin and Mestieri (2018) to explore the general patterns characterizing the diffusion of technologies, how they changed over time, and the key drivers of technology.
 
4
In our specification, similar (conditional) covariances among the dependent variable and regressors yield a high probability of belonging to the same cluster, for any two firms. An alternative strategy might be modeling probabilities according to some form of similarity (e.g., in firm size, as in Dayton and Mc Ready 1988). Recent studies have also used the similarity among regressors to obtain a pre-partition of sample firms in order to “help” the clusterization algorithm (e.g., Shahbaba and Neal 2009). However, these methods impose a priori choices that we wish to avoid.
 
5
It is worth noting how our BTFP-WTFP dichotomy might be not unique in the presence of residual differences in biased, input-augmenting, technological change across firms that are not captured by the clustering algorithm.
 
6
It is worth noting that WTFP, as defined in Equation (6), would be centered on zero at the sectoral level. Using gaps can be seen as a normalization in order to work only with positive values.
 
7
The price bias stems from the price dispersion across firms characterizing imperfectly competitive markets. Productivity is usually estimated on revenues or value added, instead of using produced quantities, as information on the latter (or individual prices to be used as deflators) is usually not available. Hence, the obtained productivity measures, which are biased by cross-firm heterogeneity in terms of markups.
 
8
It is worth noting how, as the mixture regression is carried out through weighted least squares, we might see the OLS-estimated coefficients as a weighted average of the M technology-specific coefficients, with weights (i.e., \(\Theta _{m}\)) given by the ratio of the number of firms in the m-technology group to the total number of firms in the sector—namely, \(\hat{\beta }=\sum _{m=1}^{M}\hat{\beta }_{m} \frac{\Theta _{m}}{\sum _{m=1}^{M} \Theta _{m}}\).
 
9
Being the mixture regression carried out through weighted least squares, we might see the OLS-estimated coefficients as a weighted average of the M technology-specific coefficients, with weights (i.e., \(\Theta _{m}\)) given by the ratio of the number of firms in the m-technology group to the total number of firms in the sector, namely, \(\hat{\beta }=\sum _{m=1}^{M}\hat{\beta }_{m} \frac{\Theta _{m}}{\sum _{m=1}^{M} \Theta _{m}}\). The same reasoning applies to \(\alpha \).
 
10
Firms’ productivity is assumed to evolve according to a Markov process, which is “shifted” (either positively or negatively) by R&D expenditure. The R&D choice gives rise to an additional policy function (besides the policy function for investment in physical capital) that, under the crucial assumption that the error in t is uncorrelated with the innovation choice in \(t-1\), may be exploited in the production function estimation to purge the estimates from the part of the error correlated with the input choice. Loosely speaking, this approach allows us to estimate firms’ TFP while controlling for simultaneity and the effect of innovation choices at the same time.
 
11
The reason why is shown to be the assumption of flexible elasticity for the input used as a proxy.
 
12
The most obvious hypothesis concerning the data-generating process for labor demand is for it to be a function of capital and productivity. Thus, labor demand is only a function of capital plus the variable chosen as proxy (i.e., investment in Olley and Pakes (1996) and intermediates in Levinsohn and Petrin (2003)); hence, the labor coefficient cannot be identified in the first stage, as one cannot simultaneously estimate a fully non-parametric function of two variables along with a coefficient of a variable (labor) that is only a function of those same variables.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Ackerberg D, Caves K, Frazer G. Identification properties of recent production function estimators. Econometrica. 2015;83(6):2411–51.CrossRef Ackerberg D, Caves K, Frazer G. Identification properties of recent production function estimators. Econometrica. 2015;83(6):2411–51.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Aghion P, Bloom N, Blundell R, Griffith R, Howitt P. Competition and innovation: an inverted U relationship. Quart J Econ. 2005;120(2):701–28. Aghion P, Bloom N, Blundell R, Griffith R, Howitt P. Competition and innovation: an inverted U relationship. Quart J Econ. 2005;120(2):701–28.
Zurück zum Zitat Altomonte C, Aquilante T. The EU-EFIGE/Bruegel-Unicredit dataset. WP Bruegel. 2012;2012–10. Altomonte C, Aquilante T. The EU-EFIGE/Bruegel-Unicredit dataset. WP Bruegel. 2012;2012–10.
Zurück zum Zitat Alvarez F, Buera FJ, Lucas REJr. Idea Flows, Economic Growth, and Trade, Unpublished, 2014. Alvarez F, Buera FJ, Lucas REJr. Idea Flows, Economic Growth, and Trade, Unpublished, 2014.
Zurück zum Zitat Aw BY, Chung S, Roberts M. Productivity and turnover in the export market: micro-level evidence from the Republic of Korea and Taiwan (China). World Bank Econ Rev. 2000;14(1):65–90.CrossRef Aw BY, Chung S, Roberts M. Productivity and turnover in the export market: micro-level evidence from the Republic of Korea and Taiwan (China). World Bank Econ Rev. 2000;14(1):65–90.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bartelsman E, Haltiwanger J, Scarpetta S. Cross-country differences in productivity: the role of allocation and selection. Am Econ Rev. 2013;103(1):305–34.CrossRef Bartelsman E, Haltiwanger J, Scarpetta S. Cross-country differences in productivity: the role of allocation and selection. Am Econ Rev. 2013;103(1):305–34.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Battisti M, Belloc F, Del Gatto M. Unbundling technology adoption and TFP effects: do firms intangibles matter? J Econ Manag Strat. 2015;24(2):386–410.CrossRef Battisti M, Belloc F, Del Gatto M. Unbundling technology adoption and TFP effects: do firms intangibles matter? J Econ Manag Strat. 2015;24(2):386–410.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Battisti M, Belloc F, Del Gatto M. Labor productivity and firm-level TFP with technology-specific production functions. Rev Econ Dyn. 2020;35:283–300.CrossRef Battisti M, Belloc F, Del Gatto M. Labor productivity and firm-level TFP with technology-specific production functions. Rev Econ Dyn. 2020;35:283–300.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Battisti M, Del Gatto M, Parmeter CF. Labor productivity growth: disentangling technology and capital accumulation. J Econ Growth. 2018;23(1):111–43.CrossRef Battisti M, Del Gatto M, Parmeter CF. Labor productivity growth: disentangling technology and capital accumulation. J Econ Growth. 2018;23(1):111–43.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Benhabib J, Perla J, Tonetti C. Reconciling models of diffusion and innovation: a theory of the productivity distribution and technology frontier. NBER Working Papers, 2017;23095. Benhabib J, Perla J, Tonetti C. Reconciling models of diffusion and innovation: a theory of the productivity distribution and technology frontier. NBER Working Papers, 2017;23095.
Zurück zum Zitat Bernard AB, Jones CI. Comparing apples to oranges: productivity convergence and measurement across industries and countries. Am Econ Rev. 1996a;86(5):1216–38. Bernard AB, Jones CI. Comparing apples to oranges: productivity convergence and measurement across industries and countries. Am Econ Rev. 1996a;86(5):1216–38.
Zurück zum Zitat Bernard AB, Jones CI. Technology and convergence. Econ J. 1996b;106(437):1037–44.CrossRef Bernard AB, Jones CI. Technology and convergence. Econ J. 1996b;106(437):1037–44.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bernard AB, Jensen JB. Exceptional exporter performance: cause, effect, or both? J Int Econ. 1999;47:1–25.CrossRef Bernard AB, Jensen JB. Exceptional exporter performance: cause, effect, or both? J Int Econ. 1999;47:1–25.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bernard AB, Jensen JB, Schott P. Trade costs, firms and productivity. J Monet Econ. 2006;53:917–37.CrossRef Bernard AB, Jensen JB, Schott P. Trade costs, firms and productivity. J Monet Econ. 2006;53:917–37.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bhattacharya D, Guner N, Ventura G. Distortions, endogenous managerial skills and productivity differences. Rev Econ Dyn. 2013;16:11–25.CrossRef Bhattacharya D, Guner N, Ventura G. Distortions, endogenous managerial skills and productivity differences. Rev Econ Dyn. 2013;16:11–25.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bloom N, Draca M, Van Reenen J. Trade induced technical change? The impact of Chinese imports on innovation, IT and productivity. Rev Econ Stud. 2016;83(1):87–117.CrossRef Bloom N, Draca M, Van Reenen J. Trade induced technical change? The impact of Chinese imports on innovation, IT and productivity. Rev Econ Stud. 2016;83(1):87–117.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bustos P. Trade liberalization, exports, and technology upgrading: evidence on the impact of MERCOSUR on Argentinian Firms. Am Econ Rev. 2011;101(1):304–40.CrossRef Bustos P. Trade liberalization, exports, and technology upgrading: evidence on the impact of MERCOSUR on Argentinian Firms. Am Econ Rev. 2011;101(1):304–40.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Clerides S, Lach S, Tybout JR. Is learning by exporting important? Micro-dynamic evidence from Colombia, Mexico, and Morocco. Q J Econ. 1998;113(3):903–47.CrossRef Clerides S, Lach S, Tybout JR. Is learning by exporting important? Micro-dynamic evidence from Colombia, Mexico, and Morocco. Q J Econ. 1998;113(3):903–47.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cervellati M, Naghavi A, Toubal F. Trade liberalization, democratization and technology adoption. CEPII Working Papers, 2014;2014-08. Cervellati M, Naghavi A, Toubal F. Trade liberalization, democratization and technology adoption. CEPII Working Papers, 2014;2014-08.
Zurück zum Zitat Collard-Wexler A, De Loecker J. Reallocation and technology: evidence from the US steel industry. Am Econ Rev. 2014;105(1):131–71.CrossRef Collard-Wexler A, De Loecker J. Reallocation and technology: evidence from the US steel industry. Am Econ Rev. 2014;105(1):131–71.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Comin DA, Dmitriev M, Rossi-Hansberg E. The spatial diffusion of technology. NBER Working Papers, 2012;18534. Comin DA, Dmitriev M, Rossi-Hansberg E. The spatial diffusion of technology. NBER Working Papers, 2012;18534.
Zurück zum Zitat Comin DA, Hobijn B. The CHAT dataset. NBER Working Papers, 2009;15319. Comin DA, Hobijn B. The CHAT dataset. NBER Working Papers, 2009;15319.
Zurück zum Zitat Comin DA, Hobijn B. An exploration of technology diffusion. Am Econ Rev. 2010;100(5):2031–59.CrossRef Comin DA, Hobijn B. An exploration of technology diffusion. Am Econ Rev. 2010;100(5):2031–59.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Comin DA, Mestieri M. If technology has arrived everywhere, why has income diverged? Am Econ J: Macroecon. 2018;10(3):137–78. Comin DA, Mestieri M. If technology has arrived everywhere, why has income diverged? Am Econ J: Macroecon. 2018;10(3):137–78.
Zurück zum Zitat Da Rocha JM, Mendes Tavares M, Restuccia D. Policy distortions and aggregate productivity with endogenous establishment-level productivity. NBER Working Paper, 2017;23339. Da Rocha JM, Mendes Tavares M, Restuccia D. Policy distortions and aggregate productivity with endogenous establishment-level productivity. NBER Working Paper, 2017;23339.
Zurück zum Zitat De Loecker J. Do exports generate higher productivity? Evidence from Slovenia. J Int Econ. 2007;73(1):69–98.CrossRef De Loecker J. Do exports generate higher productivity? Evidence from Slovenia. J Int Econ. 2007;73(1):69–98.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat De Sarbo WS, Cron WL. A maximum likelihood methodology for clusterwise linear regression. J Classif. 1988;5:249–82.CrossRef De Sarbo WS, Cron WL. A maximum likelihood methodology for clusterwise linear regression. J Classif. 1988;5:249–82.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Delgado M, Farinas JC, Ruano S. Firm productivity and export markets: a non-parametric approach. J Int Econ. 2002;57(2):397–422.CrossRef Delgado M, Farinas JC, Ruano S. Firm productivity and export markets: a non-parametric approach. J Int Econ. 2002;57(2):397–422.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Del Gatto M, Di Liberto A, Petraglia C. Measuring productivity. J Econ Surv. 2011;25(5):952–1008.CrossRef Del Gatto M, Di Liberto A, Petraglia C. Measuring productivity. J Econ Surv. 2011;25(5):952–1008.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Desmet K, Parente SL. Bigger is better: market size, demand elasticity, and innovation. Int Econ Rev. 2010;51(2):319–33.CrossRef Desmet K, Parente SL. Bigger is better: market size, demand elasticity, and innovation. Int Econ Rev. 2010;51(2):319–33.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Desmet K, Rossi-Hansberg E. Spatial development. Am Econ Rev. 2014;104(4):1211–43.CrossRef Desmet K, Rossi-Hansberg E. Spatial development. Am Econ Rev. 2014;104(4):1211–43.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Doraszelski U, Jaumandreu J. R&D and productivity: estimating endogenous productivity. Rev Econ Stud. 2013;80(4):1338–83.CrossRef Doraszelski U, Jaumandreu J. R&D and productivity: estimating endogenous productivity. Rev Econ Stud. 2013;80(4):1338–83.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gabler A, Poschke M. Experimentation by firms, distortions, and aggregate productivity. Rev Econ Dyn. 2013;16(1):26–38.CrossRef Gabler A, Poschke M. Experimentation by firms, distortions, and aggregate productivity. Rev Econ Dyn. 2013;16(1):26–38.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gandhi A, Navarro S, Rivers D. On the identification of gross output production functions. J Polit Econ. 2018 (forthcoming). Gandhi A, Navarro S, Rivers D. On the identification of gross output production functions. J Polit Econ. 2018 (forthcoming).
Zurück zum Zitat Garcia-Marin A, Voigtlander N. Exporting and plant-level efficiency gains: it’s in the measure. J Polit Econ. 2019;127(4):1777–825.CrossRef Garcia-Marin A, Voigtlander N. Exporting and plant-level efficiency gains: it’s in the measure. J Polit Econ. 2019;127(4):1777–825.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gerschenkron A. Economic backwardness in historical perspective: a book of essays. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press; 1962. p. G381. Gerschenkron A. Economic backwardness in historical perspective: a book of essays. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press; 1962. p. G381.
Zurück zum Zitat Gorodnichenko Y, Svejnar J, Terrell K. Globalization and innovation in emerging markets. Am Econ J-Macroecon. 2010;2:194–226.CrossRef Gorodnichenko Y, Svejnar J, Terrell K. Globalization and innovation in emerging markets. Am Econ J-Macroecon. 2010;2:194–226.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Grossman GM, Helpman H. Globalization and growth. Am Econ Rev: Pap Proc. 2015;105(5):100–4.CrossRef Grossman GM, Helpman H. Globalization and growth. Am Econ Rev: Pap Proc. 2015;105(5):100–4.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Grun B, Leisch F. FlexMix version 2: finite mixtures with concomitant variables and varying and constant parameters. J Stat Softw. 2008;28(4):1–35.CrossRef Grun B, Leisch F. FlexMix version 2: finite mixtures with concomitant variables and varying and constant parameters. J Stat Softw. 2008;28(4):1–35.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hashmi A. Competition and innovation: the inverted-U relationship revisited. Rev Econ Stat. 2013;95(5):1653–68.CrossRef Hashmi A. Competition and innovation: the inverted-U relationship revisited. Rev Econ Stat. 2013;95(5):1653–68.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Helpman E, Melitz MJ, Yeaple SR. Export versus FDI with heterogeneous firms. Am Econ Rev. 2004;94(1):300–16.CrossRef Helpman E, Melitz MJ, Yeaple SR. Export versus FDI with heterogeneous firms. Am Econ Rev. 2004;94(1):300–16.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Howitt P. Endogenous growth and cross-country income differences. Am Econ Rev. 2000;829–46. Howitt P. Endogenous growth and cross-country income differences. Am Econ Rev. 2000;829–46.
Zurück zum Zitat Klette TJ, Griliches Z. The inconsistency of common scale estimators when output prices are unobserved and endogenous. J Appl Econom. 1996;11(4):343–61.CrossRef Klette TJ, Griliches Z. The inconsistency of common scale estimators when output prices are unobserved and endogenous. J Appl Econom. 1996;11(4):343–61.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Levinsohn J, Petrin A. Estimating production functions using inputs to control for unobservables. Rev Econ Stud. 2003;70:317–42.CrossRef Levinsohn J, Petrin A. Estimating production functions using inputs to control for unobservables. Rev Econ Stud. 2003;70:317–42.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lileeva A, Trefler D. Improved access to foreign markets raises plant-level productivity... for some plants. Q J Econ. 2010;125(3):1051–99.CrossRef Lileeva A, Trefler D. Improved access to foreign markets raises plant-level productivity... for some plants. Q J Econ. 2010;125(3):1051–99.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Luttmer EG. Selection, growth, and the size distribution of firms. Q J Econ. 2007;122(3):1103–44.CrossRef Luttmer EG. Selection, growth, and the size distribution of firms. Q J Econ. 2007;122(3):1103–44.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mayer T, Ottaviano G. The happy few: the internationalisation of European firms. Intereconomics. 2008;43:135–48.CrossRef Mayer T, Ottaviano G. The happy few: the internationalisation of European firms. Intereconomics. 2008;43:135–48.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nelson RR, Phelps ES. Investment in humans, technological diffusion, and economic growth. Am Econ Rev. 1966;56(1/2):69–75. Nelson RR, Phelps ES. Investment in humans, technological diffusion, and economic growth. Am Econ Rev. 1966;56(1/2):69–75.
Zurück zum Zitat Olley S, Pakes A. The dynamics of productivity in the telecommunications equipment industry. Econometrica. 1996;64:1263–97.CrossRef Olley S, Pakes A. The dynamics of productivity in the telecommunications equipment industry. Econometrica. 1996;64:1263–97.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pavcnik N. Trade liberalization, exit, and productivity improvements: evidence from chilean plants. Rev Econ Stud. 2002;69(1):245–76.CrossRef Pavcnik N. Trade liberalization, exit, and productivity improvements: evidence from chilean plants. Rev Econ Stud. 2002;69(1):245–76.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Parente SL, Prescott EC. Barriers to technology adoption and development. J Polit Econ. 1994;102(2):298–321.CrossRef Parente SL, Prescott EC. Barriers to technology adoption and development. J Polit Econ. 1994;102(2):298–321.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Perla J, Tonetti C. Equilibrium imitation and growth. J Polit Econ. 2014;122(1):52–76.CrossRef Perla J, Tonetti C. Equilibrium imitation and growth. J Polit Econ. 2014;122(1):52–76.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Perla J, Tonetti C, Waugh ME. Equilibrium technology diffusion, trade, and growth. NBER Working Paper, National Bureau of Economic Research, 2015;20881. Perla J, Tonetti C, Waugh ME. Equilibrium technology diffusion, trade, and growth. NBER Working Paper, National Bureau of Economic Research, 2015;20881.
Zurück zum Zitat Sampson T. Dynamic selection: an idea flows theory of entry, trade and growth. Q J Econ. 2016;131(1):315–80.CrossRef Sampson T. Dynamic selection: an idea flows theory of entry, trade and growth. Q J Econ. 2016;131(1):315–80.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Serti F, Tomasi C. Self-Selection and post-entry effects of exports: evidence from Italian Manufacturing Firms. Rev World Econ. 2008;144:660–94.CrossRef Serti F, Tomasi C. Self-Selection and post-entry effects of exports: evidence from Italian Manufacturing Firms. Rev World Econ. 2008;144:660–94.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Shahbaba B, Neal RM. Nonlinear models using Dirichlet process mixtures. J Mach Learn Res. 2009;10:1829–50. Shahbaba B, Neal RM. Nonlinear models using Dirichlet process mixtures. J Mach Learn Res. 2009;10:1829–50.
Zurück zum Zitat Steele RJ, Raftery AE. Performance of bayesian model selection criteria for gaussian mixture models. In: Chen M-H, et al., editors. Frontiers of statistical decision making and bayesian analysis. New York: Springer; 2010. p. 113–30. Steele RJ, Raftery AE. Performance of bayesian model selection criteria for gaussian mixture models. In: Chen M-H, et al., editors. Frontiers of statistical decision making and bayesian analysis. New York: Springer; 2010. p. 113–30.
Zurück zum Zitat Tybout JR. Plant-and firm-level evidence on new trade theories, in handbook of international economics. Oxford: Basil Blackwell; 2002. Tybout JR. Plant-and firm-level evidence on new trade theories, in handbook of international economics. Oxford: Basil Blackwell; 2002.
Zurück zum Zitat Van Biesebroeck J. Exporting raises productivity in sub-Saharan African manufacturing firms. J Int Econ. 2005;67:373–91.CrossRef Van Biesebroeck J. Exporting raises productivity in sub-Saharan African manufacturing firms. J Int Econ. 2005;67:373–91.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat van Dijk Bureau. Orbis Database. Amsterdam, 2018. van Dijk Bureau. Orbis Database. Amsterdam, 2018.
Zurück zum Zitat Wooldridge J. On estimating firm-level production functions using proxy variables to control for unobservables. Econ Lett. 2009;104(3):112–4.CrossRef Wooldridge J. On estimating firm-level production functions using proxy variables to control for unobservables. Econ Lett. 2009;104(3):112–4.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Is the productivity premium of internationalized firms technology-driven?
verfasst von
Michele Battisti
Filippo Belloc
Massimo Del Gatto
Publikationsdatum
18.09.2020
Verlag
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Erschienen in
Empirical Economics / Ausgabe 6/2021
Print ISSN: 0377-7332
Elektronische ISSN: 1435-8921
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-020-01936-x

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 6/2021

Empirical Economics 6/2021 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner