Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Public Choice 1-2/2018

26.02.2018

Youth bulges, insurrections and labor-market restrictions

verfasst von: Thomas Apolte, Lena Gerling

Erschienen in: Public Choice | Ausgabe 1-2/2018

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This paper analyzes the link between large youth cohorts and violent conflicts when labor-market restrictions are present. Such restrictions are expected to limit the youth cohort’s access to income opportunities in the formal economy, and thus lower the youth-specific opportunity cost of insurrection activities. We develop a theoretical model of insurrection markets and integrate the youth cohort’s relative size. In equilibrium, a binding labor-market constraint interacts with the youth bulge in determining the level of insurrection activities within the society. We test the implications of our model on a sample of 135 non-OECD countries in the post-Cold War period and find the effect of the youth cohort’s relative size on conflict onsets to be moderated by changes in the labor-market conditions as measured by unemployment rates. Generally, the results provide evidence that the underlying institutional setting shapes the conflict potential inherent in a given demographic structure.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
These effects already have been mentioned by Goldstone (1991, p. 139): “If real wages are above average, then ...a youthful population can be stabilizing. However, if there is a precipitous drop in real wages, then ...the youthfulness of the population can increase the mobilization potential of the population”.
 
2
There is by now a vast amount of literature following Acemoglu and Robinson (2000, 2001, 2006) that is based on the notion of collectively sustained revolution constraints (see, e.g., Dorsch and Maarek 2015; Cervellati et al. 2014). However, this literature suffers from a number of drawbacks. In general, the literature on revolutions suppresses the micro-structure of collective action, so that it provides an ex-post rationalization rather than a causal explanation of insurrection activities (Apolte 2012).
 
3
Acemoglu (2006) and Dorsch and Maarek (2015) consider the scope of tax instruments and deadweight-losses from such intervention into the economy. Since they are not critical for the point raised in this paper, we abstract from these losses.
 
4
A detailed formal analysis of the following is provided in the “Appendix”.
 
5
See the “Appendix” for the formal details.
 
6
We rule out possible situations with no labor-market restriction and, at the same time, utility from insurrection activities is less than the net effective wage rate even with full employment, so that insurrection activities are never worthwhile.
 
7
See the “Appendix” for the formal details.
 
8
In the following, we use the terms “insurrection” and “conflict” interchangeably as our (empirical) conflict measure closely resembles what we modeled as “insurrections” in the theoretical section.
 
9
We refrain from relating the youth cohort size to the total population as such a measure might seriously underestimate the extent of a youth bulge in the presence of continued high fertility rates (Urdal 2004, 2006).
 
10
Technically, we use the size of the cohort of the 0-to-9-year-old males at time t-15 [which becomes the youth cohort (aged 15–24) in t]. In the denominator, we include the size of the population aged zero to 54 in t-15 [which becomes the total working population (aged 15–69) in t].
 
11
Similar approaches are applied in studies of the relationship between youth cohorts and labor-market outcomes (Korenman and Neumark 1997) and in the literature on demography and economic growth (see, for example, Bloom and Williamson 1998).
 
12
See Angrist and Krueger (1999) for a technical discussion of this condition.
 
13
We provide an online appendix that contains additional information on the definitions and sources of all variables included in our analysis.
 
14
One concern with the included controls is that they might be endogenous to insurrections and tend to be correlated with each other (Burke et al. 2014). Therefore, we treat these controls with caution and also present results without them. Nevertheless, our results do not depend on the chosen number and definition of the control variables. Additional regression results are available from the authors.
 
15
For a country with RYCS (at birth) at the sample mean (= 0.149), the standardized value of this variable is zero. Thus, the overall effect of a one-unit increase in UE (= unemployment changes) at RYCS (at birth) = 0.149 is simply \(\hat{\gamma _2}\). For a country with RYCS (at birth) = 0.177, the standardized value is 0.848. The overall effect of a one-unit increase in UE at RYCS (at birth) = 0.177 is therefore \(\hat{\gamma _2} + \hat{\gamma _3}*0.848\). The differential effect of a one-unit increase in UE is the difference in both effects, or \(\hat{\gamma _3}*0.848 = 0.00727*0.848 = 0.00616\) (i.e., 0.616 percentage points).
 
16
One could question the extent to which the absence of regulatory constraints actually reflects functioning labor markets. While this might be true for many (though not all) developed countries, in less developed countries the absence of labor regulations could simply reflect the failure of the state to establish a regulatory framework needed for functioning markets in the first place. That is one more reason why we refrain from using these indices as our main labor-market indicators.
 
17
Since the indicator variable does not vary over time and the relative youth cohort size exhibits only little within-country variation, we refrain from including country fixed effects in our model, but instead enter regional and region-year fixed effects.
 
18
In models (3)–(6) of Table 3, we separately include dummy variables for the political system, levels of education and resource rents. For ease of exposition, we summarize the coefficients on the main effects of these variables in one line, and we do the same for the interaction with RYCS (at birth) and the three-way interaction effect, using as a placeholder the term “indicator variable”.
 
19
The results are qualitatively similar if we use the PolityIV definition and define as democratic all country-years with a Polity2 score of more than five.
 
20
The partial effects of an increase in RYCS for a given value of UE in autocracies versus democracies are computed as follows. In autocracies (i.e., when democracy = 0), the effect of RYCS is given by \(0.0647 + 0.0224\times \overline{UE}\). When democracy = 1, the effect of RYCS is \(0.0647 - 0.0660 + (0.0224 - 0.0213)\times \overline{UE} = -\,0.0013 + 0.0011\times \overline{UE}\), which clearly is smaller than the effect in autocracies for any \(\overline{UE}>0\).
 
21
The construction of the binary variables is similar to the institutional indicators in column (1) and (2) of Table 3. The only difference is that we do not construct time-invariant country averages, but use the annual observations to capture expansions in education over time. We use total years of schooling as well as years of tertiary schooling from the dataset of Barro and Lee (2013). To control for endogeneity concerns and since the data are available only for 5-year periods, we lag the variable by 5 years following Campante and Chor (2012).
 
22
Excluding all observations of ongoing conflicts produces a somewhat artificial correlation between current and lagged values of the dependent variable. Therefore, in the dynamic specifications, the dependent variable is coded one for all conflict onsets, while country-years of ongoing conflicts are coded zero, following the coding procedure of Fearon and Laitin (2003). We call this variable “any conflict onset”. In the online appendix, we provide a list of included cases for all conflict definitions.
 
23
We employ the first-difference GMM estimator instead of the system GMM estimator because it involves fewer internal instruments. As instruments, we use lagged levels of the dependent variable, unemployment (changes) and their interaction with the youth bulge, assuming exogeneity for RYCS (at birth). The results do not change when entering internal instruments for this variable as well.
 
24
In the online appendix we provide additional robustness tests to our baseline model. In particular, we show that our results are robust to alternative definitions of the dependent variable and the youth cohort, as well as to different time structures and to the inclusion of additional demographic controls.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Acemoglu, D. (2006). A simple model of inefficient institutions. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 108(4), 515–546.CrossRef Acemoglu, D. (2006). A simple model of inefficient institutions. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 108(4), 515–546.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2000). Democratization or repression? European Economic Review, 44(4), 683–693.CrossRef Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2000). Democratization or repression? European Economic Review, 44(4), 683–693.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). A theory of political transitions. American Economic Review, 91(4), 938–963.CrossRef Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). A theory of political transitions. American Economic Review, 91(4), 938–963.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2006). Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2006). Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Ai, C., & Norton, E. C. (2003). Interaction terms in logit and probit models. Economics Letters, 80(1), 123–129.CrossRef Ai, C., & Norton, E. C. (2003). Interaction terms in logit and probit models. Economics Letters, 80(1), 123–129.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Angrist, J. D., & Krueger, A. B. (1999). Empirical strategies in labor economics. In O. Ashenfelter & D. Card (Eds.), Handbook of labor economics (Vol. 3, pp. 1277–1366). Amsterdam: Elsevier Science. Angrist, J. D., & Krueger, A. B. (1999). Empirical strategies in labor economics. In O. Ashenfelter & D. Card (Eds.), Handbook of labor economics (Vol. 3, pp. 1277–1366). Amsterdam: Elsevier Science.
Zurück zum Zitat Angrist, J. D., & Pischke, J.-S. (2008). Mostly harmless econometrics: An empiricist’s companion. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Angrist, J. D., & Pischke, J.-S. (2008). Mostly harmless econometrics: An empiricist’s companion. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Apolte, T. (2012). Why is there no revolution in North Korea? Public Choice, 150(3–4), 561–578.CrossRef Apolte, T. (2012). Why is there no revolution in North Korea? Public Choice, 150(3–4), 561–578.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. The Review of Economic Studies, 58(2), 277–297.CrossRef Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. The Review of Economic Studies, 58(2), 277–297.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Austin, L. (2011). The politics of youth bulge: From Islamic activists to democratic reform in the Middle East and North Africa. SAIS Review of International Affairs, 31(2), 81–96. Austin, L. (2011). The politics of youth bulge: From Islamic activists to democratic reform in the Middle East and North Africa. SAIS Review of International Affairs, 31(2), 81–96.
Zurück zum Zitat Banks, A. S., & Wilson, K. A. (2015). Cross-national time-series data archive. Jerusalem: Databanks International. Online database, available from http://www.cntsdata.com/. Accessed 18 Nov 2015. Banks, A. S., & Wilson, K. A. (2015). Cross-national time-series data archive. Jerusalem: Databanks International. Online database, available from http://​www.​cntsdata.​com/​. Accessed 18 Nov 2015.
Zurück zum Zitat Barro, R., & Lee, J.-W. (2013). A new data set of educational attainment in the world, 1950–2010. Journal of Development Economics, 104, 184–198.CrossRef Barro, R., & Lee, J.-W. (2013). A new data set of educational attainment in the world, 1950–2010. Journal of Development Economics, 104, 184–198.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bazzi, S., & Blattman, C. (2014). Economic shocks and conflict: Evidence from commodity prices. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 6(4), 1–38. Bazzi, S., & Blattman, C. (2014). Economic shocks and conflict: Evidence from commodity prices. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 6(4), 1–38.
Zurück zum Zitat Berman, E., Callen, M., Felter, J. H., & Shapiro, J. N. (2011). Do working men rebel? Insurgency and unemployment in Afghanistan, Iraq, and the Philippines. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 55(4), 496–528.CrossRef Berman, E., Callen, M., Felter, J. H., & Shapiro, J. N. (2011). Do working men rebel? Insurgency and unemployment in Afghanistan, Iraq, and the Philippines. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 55(4), 496–528.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Blattman, C., & Miguel, E. (2010). Civil war. Journal of Economic Literature, 48(1), 3–57.CrossRef Blattman, C., & Miguel, E. (2010). Civil war. Journal of Economic Literature, 48(1), 3–57.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bloom, D. E., & Williamson, J. G. (1998). Demographic transitions and economic miracles in emerging Asia. The World Bank Economic Review, 12(3), 419–455.CrossRef Bloom, D. E., & Williamson, J. G. (1998). Demographic transitions and economic miracles in emerging Asia. The World Bank Economic Review, 12(3), 419–455.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Boix, C., & Svolik, M. W. (2013). The foundation of limited authoritarian government: Institutions, commitment, and power-sharing in dictatorships. The Journal of Politics, 75(2), 300–316.CrossRef Boix, C., & Svolik, M. W. (2013). The foundation of limited authoritarian government: Institutions, commitment, and power-sharing in dictatorships. The Journal of Politics, 75(2), 300–316.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bruno, G. S. F. (2005). Approximating the bias of the LSDV estimator for dynamic unbalanced panel data models. Economics Letters, 87(3), 361–366.CrossRef Bruno, G. S. F. (2005). Approximating the bias of the LSDV estimator for dynamic unbalanced panel data models. Economics Letters, 87(3), 361–366.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Caldwell, C. (2007). Youth and war, a deadly duo. The Financial Times, January 6. Caldwell, C. (2007). Youth and war, a deadly duo. The Financial Times, January 6.
Zurück zum Zitat Campante, F. R., & Chor, D. (2012). Why was the Arab world poised for revolution? Schooling, economic opportunities, and the Arab spring. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26, 167–187.CrossRef Campante, F. R., & Chor, D. (2012). Why was the Arab world poised for revolution? Schooling, economic opportunities, and the Arab spring. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26, 167–187.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Carter, D. B., & Signorino, C. S. (2010). Back to the future: Modeling time dependence in binary data. Political Analysis, 18(3), 271–292.CrossRef Carter, D. B., & Signorino, C. S. (2010). Back to the future: Modeling time dependence in binary data. Political Analysis, 18(3), 271–292.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cervellati, M., Fortunato, P., & Sunde, U. (2014). Violence during democratization and the quality of democratic institutions. European Economic Review, 66, 226–247.CrossRef Cervellati, M., Fortunato, P., & Sunde, U. (2014). Violence during democratization and the quality of democratic institutions. European Economic Review, 66, 226–247.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cheibub, J. A., Gandhi, J., & Vreeland, J. R. (2010). Democracy and dictatorship revisited. Public Choice, 143(1–2), 67–101.CrossRef Cheibub, J. A., Gandhi, J., & Vreeland, J. R. (2010). Democracy and dictatorship revisited. Public Choice, 143(1–2), 67–101.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Collier, P., & Hoeffler, A. (2004). Greed and grievance in civil war. Oxford Economic Papers, 56(4), 563–595.CrossRef Collier, P., & Hoeffler, A. (2004). Greed and grievance in civil war. Oxford Economic Papers, 56(4), 563–595.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Collier, P., Hoeffler, A., & Rohner, D. (2009). Beyond greed and grievance: Feasibility and civil war. Oxford Economic Papers, 61(1), 1–27.CrossRef Collier, P., Hoeffler, A., & Rohner, D. (2009). Beyond greed and grievance: Feasibility and civil war. Oxford Economic Papers, 61(1), 1–27.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Defoe, I. N., Dubas, J. S., Figner, B., & van Aken, M. A. G. (2015). A meta-analysis on age differences in risky decision making: Adolescents versus children and adults. Psychological Bulletin, 141(1), 48.CrossRef Defoe, I. N., Dubas, J. S., Figner, B., & van Aken, M. A. G. (2015). A meta-analysis on age differences in risky decision making: Adolescents versus children and adults. Psychological Bulletin, 141(1), 48.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dorsch, M. T., & Maarek, P. (2015). Inefficient predation and political transitions. European Journal of Political Economy, 37, 37–48.CrossRef Dorsch, M. T., & Maarek, P. (2015). Inefficient predation and political transitions. European Journal of Political Economy, 37, 37–48.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dreher, A., Minasyan, A., & Nunnenkamp, P. (2015). Government ideology in donor and recipient countries: Does ideological proximity matter for the effectiveness of aid? European Economic Review, 79, 80–92.CrossRef Dreher, A., Minasyan, A., & Nunnenkamp, P. (2015). Government ideology in donor and recipient countries: Does ideological proximity matter for the effectiveness of aid? European Economic Review, 79, 80–92.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Easterlin, R. A. (1987). Birth and fortune: The impact of numbers on personal welfare. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Easterlin, R. A. (1987). Birth and fortune: The impact of numbers on personal welfare. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Fearon, J. D., & Laitin, D. D. (2003). Ethnicity, insurgency, and civil war. American Political Science Review, 97(1), 75–90.CrossRef Fearon, J. D., & Laitin, D. D. (2003). Ethnicity, insurgency, and civil war. American Political Science Review, 97(1), 75–90.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fuller, G. E. (1995). The demographic backdrop to ethnic conflict: A geographic overview. In C. I. Unit (Ed.), The challenge of ethnic conflict to national and international order in the 1990s (pp. 151–154). Washington, DC: CIA. Fuller, G. E. (1995). The demographic backdrop to ethnic conflict: A geographic overview. In C. I. Unit (Ed.), The challenge of ethnic conflict to national and international order in the 1990s (pp. 151–154). Washington, DC: CIA.
Zurück zum Zitat Fuller, G. E. (2003). The youth factor: The new demographics of the Middle East and the implications for US Policy. Washington: Saban Center for Middle East Policy at the Brookings Institution. Fuller, G. E. (2003). The youth factor: The new demographics of the Middle East and the implications for US Policy. Washington: Saban Center for Middle East Policy at the Brookings Institution.
Zurück zum Zitat Furnham, A. (2015). Young people’s understanding of society. Abingdon: Routledge. Furnham, A. (2015). Young people’s understanding of society. Abingdon: Routledge.
Zurück zum Zitat Gates, S. (2002). Recruitment and allegiance: The microfoundations of rebellion. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46(1), 111–130.CrossRef Gates, S. (2002). Recruitment and allegiance: The microfoundations of rebellion. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46(1), 111–130.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gleditsch, N. P., Wallensteen, P., Eriksson, M., Sollenberg, M., & Strand, H. (2002). Armed conflict 1946–2001: A new dataset. Journal of Peace Research, 39(5), 615–637.CrossRef Gleditsch, N. P., Wallensteen, P., Eriksson, M., Sollenberg, M., & Strand, H. (2002). Armed conflict 1946–2001: A new dataset. Journal of Peace Research, 39(5), 615–637.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Goemans, H. E., Gleditsch, K. S., & Chiozza, G. (2009). Introducing Archigos: A dataset of political leaders. Journal of Peace Research, 46(2), 269–283.CrossRef Goemans, H. E., Gleditsch, K. S., & Chiozza, G. (2009). Introducing Archigos: A dataset of political leaders. Journal of Peace Research, 46(2), 269–283.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Goldstone, J. A. (1991). Revolution and rebellion in the early modern world. Berkeley: University of California Press. Goldstone, J. A. (1991). Revolution and rebellion in the early modern world. Berkeley: University of California Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Goldstone, J. A. (2002). Population and security: How demographic change can lead to violent conflict. Journal of International Affairs, 56(1), 3–21. Goldstone, J. A. (2002). Population and security: How demographic change can lead to violent conflict. Journal of International Affairs, 56(1), 3–21.
Zurück zum Zitat Grossman, H. I. (1991). A general equilibrium model of insurrections. The American Economic Review, 81, 912–921. Grossman, H. I. (1991). A general equilibrium model of insurrections. The American Economic Review, 81, 912–921.
Zurück zum Zitat Grossman, H. I. (1999). Kleptocracy and revolutions. Oxford Economic Papers, 51(2), 267–283.CrossRef Grossman, H. I. (1999). Kleptocracy and revolutions. Oxford Economic Papers, 51(2), 267–283.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Heinsohn, G. (2007). Why Gaza is fertile ground for angry young men. Financial Times, June 14. Heinsohn, G. (2007). Why Gaza is fertile ground for angry young men. Financial Times, June 14.
Zurück zum Zitat Heinsohn, G. (2009). Afghanistan’s disposable sons. The Wall Street Journal, September 17. Heinsohn, G. (2009). Afghanistan’s disposable sons. The Wall Street Journal, September 17.
Zurück zum Zitat Hillman, A. L. (2010). Expressive behavior in economics and politics. European Journal of Political Economy, 26(4), 403–418.CrossRef Hillman, A. L. (2010). Expressive behavior in economics and politics. European Journal of Political Economy, 26(4), 403–418.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kiviet, J. F. (1995). On bias, inconsistency, and efficiency of various estimators in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 68, 53–78.CrossRef Kiviet, J. F. (1995). On bias, inconsistency, and efficiency of various estimators in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 68, 53–78.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Krieger, T., & Meierrieks, D. (2011). What causes terrorism? Public Choice, 147(1–2), 3–27.CrossRef Krieger, T., & Meierrieks, D. (2011). What causes terrorism? Public Choice, 147(1–2), 3–27.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Krueger, A. B. (2008). What makes a terrorist: Economics and the roots of terrorism. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRef Krueger, A. B. (2008). What makes a terrorist: Economics and the roots of terrorism. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kuran, T. (1989). Sparks and prairie fires: A theory of unanticipated political revolution. Public Choice, 61(1), 41–74.CrossRef Kuran, T. (1989). Sparks and prairie fires: A theory of unanticipated political revolution. Public Choice, 61(1), 41–74.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kurrild-Klitgaard, P. (2003). The paradox of rebellion (pp. 728–731). Berlin: Springer. Kurrild-Klitgaard, P. (2003). The paradox of rebellion (pp. 728–731). Berlin: Springer.
Zurück zum Zitat Lichbach, M. I. (1995). The Rebel’s dilemma. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRef Lichbach, M. I. (1995). The Rebel’s dilemma. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat McGrath, L. F. (2015). Estimating onsets of binary events in panel data. Political Analysis, 23(4), 534–549.CrossRef McGrath, L. F. (2015). Estimating onsets of binary events in panel data. Political Analysis, 23(4), 534–549.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mesquida, C. G., & Wiener, N. I. (1999). Male age composition and severity of conflicts. Politics and the Life Sciences, 18(2), 181–189.CrossRef Mesquida, C. G., & Wiener, N. I. (1999). Male age composition and severity of conflicts. Politics and the Life Sciences, 18(2), 181–189.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Moller, H. (1968). Youth as a force in the modern world. Comparative Studies in Society and History, 10(03), 237–260.CrossRef Moller, H. (1968). Youth as a force in the modern world. Comparative Studies in Society and History, 10(03), 237–260.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Niang, S. R. (2010). Terrorizing ages: The effects of youth densities and the relative youth cohort size in the likelihood and pervasiveness of terrorism. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, April 2010, Chicago. Niang, S. R. (2010). Terrorizing ages: The effects of youth densities and the relative youth cohort size in the likelihood and pervasiveness of terrorism. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, April 2010, Chicago.
Zurück zum Zitat Nickell, S. (1981). Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 49(6), 1417–1426.CrossRef Nickell, S. (1981). Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 49(6), 1417–1426.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nizalova, O. Y., & Murtazashvili, I. (2016). Exogenous treatment and endogenous factors: Vanishing of omitted variable bias on the interaction term. Journal of Econometric Methods, 5(1), 71–77.CrossRef Nizalova, O. Y., & Murtazashvili, I. (2016). Exogenous treatment and endogenous factors: Vanishing of omitted variable bias on the interaction term. Journal of Econometric Methods, 5(1), 71–77.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nordås, R., & Davenport, C. (2013). Fight the youth: Youth bulges and state repression. American Journal of Political Science, 57(4), 926–940. Nordås, R., & Davenport, C. (2013). Fight the youth: Youth bulges and state repression. American Journal of Political Science, 57(4), 926–940.
Zurück zum Zitat Nunn, N., & Qian, N. (2014). US food aid and civil conflict. The American Economic Review, 104(6), 1630–1666.CrossRef Nunn, N., & Qian, N. (2014). US food aid and civil conflict. The American Economic Review, 104(6), 1630–1666.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Olson, M. (1965/1971). The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Olson, M. (1965/1971). The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Pharo, H., Sim, C., Graham, M., Gross, J., & Hayne, H. (2011). Risky business: Executive function, personality, and reckless behavior during adolescence and emerging adulthood. Behavioral Neuroscience, 125(6), 970.CrossRef Pharo, H., Sim, C., Graham, M., Gross, J., & Hayne, H. (2011). Risky business: Executive function, personality, and reckless behavior during adolescence and emerging adulthood. Behavioral Neuroscience, 125(6), 970.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sageman, M. (2004). Understanding terror networks. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.CrossRef Sageman, M. (2004). Understanding terror networks. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Samuelson, P. A. (1958). An exact consumption-loan model of interest with or without the social contrivance of money. The Journal of Political Economy, 66, 467–482.CrossRef Samuelson, P. A. (1958). An exact consumption-loan model of interest with or without the social contrivance of money. The Journal of Political Economy, 66, 467–482.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Schomaker, R. (2013). Youth bulges, poor institutional quality and missing migration opportunities—Triggers of and potential counter-measures for terrorism in MENA. Topics in Middle Eastern and North African Economies, 15(1), 116–140. Schomaker, R. (2013). Youth bulges, poor institutional quality and missing migration opportunities—Triggers of and potential counter-measures for terrorism in MENA. Topics in Middle Eastern and North African Economies, 15(1), 116–140.
Zurück zum Zitat Shadmehr, M., & Haschke, P. (2016). Youth, revolution, and repression. Economic Inquiry, 54(2), 778–793.CrossRef Shadmehr, M., & Haschke, P. (2016). Youth, revolution, and repression. Economic Inquiry, 54(2), 778–793.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stephan, M. J., & Chenoweth, E. (2008). Why civil resistance works: The strategic logic of nonviolent conflict. International Security, 33(1), 7–44.CrossRef Stephan, M. J., & Chenoweth, E. (2008). Why civil resistance works: The strategic logic of nonviolent conflict. International Security, 33(1), 7–44.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Themnér, L., & Wallensteen, P. (2013). Armed conflicts, 1946–2012. Journal of Peace Research, 50(4), 509–521.CrossRef Themnér, L., & Wallensteen, P. (2013). Armed conflicts, 1946–2012. Journal of Peace Research, 50(4), 509–521.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tullock, G. (1971). The paradox of revolution. Public Choice, 11(1), 89–99.CrossRef Tullock, G. (1971). The paradox of revolution. Public Choice, 11(1), 89–99.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tullock, G. (1974). The social dilemma: The economics of war and revolution. Blacksburg: University Publications. Tullock, G. (1974). The social dilemma: The economics of war and revolution. Blacksburg: University Publications.
Zurück zum Zitat Urdal, H. (2006). A clash of generations? Youth bulges and political violence. International Studies Quarterly, 50(3), 607–629.CrossRef Urdal, H. (2006). A clash of generations? Youth bulges and political violence. International Studies Quarterly, 50(3), 607–629.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wall, E. (2006). The terrorism labor market. Economics Department Honors Thesis, Economics, Holy Cross University Worcester, MA. Wall, E. (2006). The terrorism labor market. Economics Department Honors Thesis, Economics, Holy Cross University Worcester, MA.
Zurück zum Zitat Wintrobe, R. (2006). Extremism, suicide terror, and authoritarianism. Public Choice, 128(1–2), 169–195.CrossRef Wintrobe, R. (2006). Extremism, suicide terror, and authoritarianism. Public Choice, 128(1–2), 169–195.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Youth bulges, insurrections and labor-market restrictions
verfasst von
Thomas Apolte
Lena Gerling
Publikationsdatum
26.02.2018
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Public Choice / Ausgabe 1-2/2018
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0514-8

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 1-2/2018

Public Choice 1-2/2018 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner